View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

The Role of Finance in the Investment Bust of 2001
Annual Southwestern Finance Association Meeting
Adams Mark Hotel
St. Louis, Missouri
March 8, 2002

A

recurring topic of debate among
economists and finance experts is
the role of financial markets in cycles
of boom and bust in the real economy.
This discussion has flared up once again in the
wake of the recession of 2001. The performance
of the U.S economy in the 1990s was remarkable,
and so was the performance of the stock market.
Starting in spring of 2000, both the stock market
and real economic activity weakened considerably. In the real economy, we observed a sharp
drop-off in private business fixed investment.
In the financial sector, we witnessed the stock
market delivering disappointing returns for two
consecutive years. The number of initial public
offerings (IPOs) fell dramatically, and the market
for venture capital dried up. In fact, given that
the financial indicators turned ahead of real
investment, there is a prima facie case that financial stringency contributed to the decline in
physical investment spending. Of course, the
financial environment does not come out of the
blue; weakening prospects of the tech companies
had a lot to do with the financial stringency they
faced starting in early 2000.
Real private nonresidential investment fell
by 9.2 percent from its peak level in 2000 Q4 to
2001 Q4. To put this decline in perspective, from
the quarter in which investment peaked to the
quarter in which it hit bottom, the decline connected to the 1991-92 recession was 7.3 percent.
However, the recessions of 1948-49, 1957-58,
1973-75 and 1981-82 all saw declines of 12 percent or more. Thus the investment bust of 2001
was not extreme in the context of U.S. business
cycle experience.

Before proceeding, I want to emphasize that
the views I express here are mine and do not
necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal
Reserve System. I thank my colleagues at the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, especially
Frank Schmid, for their comments, but I retain
full responsibility for errors.
The link between the financial sector and the
real economy is currently most visible in the
telecommunications industry. From December
1990 through March 2000, the Nasdaq Telecommunications Index increased by more than 816
percent, compared with an increase of 317 percent
in the Wilshire 5000 Stock Market Index. Then,
in April 2000, the Nasdaq Telecommunications
Index began a steep decline in which it shed
about 75 percent by the end of January 2002. By
comparison, the Wilshire 5000 Price Index lost a
much smaller 26 percent of its value over the
same time period.
The boom in telecommunications stock prices
reflected optimistic judgments about the industry,
and helped to finance its expansion. Between
1990 and 2000, private fixed investment in
communications equipment as a share of GDP
increased by 52 percent, or 41 basis points. In
comparison, during the prior 30 years the share
of investment in telecom equipment in GDP grew
by only 33 basis points.
Judgments about telecom turned out to be
excessively optimistic. During the last 12 months,
eight major telecommunications services providers
went bankrupt; as a measure of the scale of these
bankruptcies, observe that the total pre-bankruptcy
book value of assets of these companies amounted
to about $55 billion. It is noteworthy that all eight
1

FINANCIAL MARKETS

of these corporations went public between 1990
and 2000, a time when the telecom sector enjoyed
spectacular growth rates.
As the telecom industry expanded in the
1990s, the stocks of telecom services providers
and equipment makers were in high demand.
The parallel performance of the telecom industry
in the real economy and in the stock market raises
a couple of questions about the interaction between
financial markets and the real sector. To what
extent were the financial markets driving the boom
and subsequent bust in the telecom industry?
What does the interaction between the financial
markets and the real economy imply for the efficiency of resource allocation?
I’ll begin by reviewing what seems, at least
in retrospect, to be excessive variance in stock
market values. Then, I’ll discuss the link between
stock market valuation, corporate finance, and
resource allocation. I’ll make a few general comments on the relevance of stock price volatility
for monetary policy. Finally, I’ll finish with my
thoughts on the outlook for business fixed investment spending.

MARKET SENTIMENT
The history of banking and financial markets
is cluttered with bouts of investor optimism that
have led to extraordinary and temporary appreciation of financial and real assets. Famous asset
price bubbles are the Dutch “tulipmania” of the
1630s, the first British railway boom of the mid1840s, and the bubble in Argentine loans in the
1880s, to name but a few. We can also find, of
course, cases in which strong performance of
individual stocks did turn out to be justified.
We call the asset price run-ups that end badly
“bubbles.”
Asset price bubbles start with good news and
substantial profits for some investors early in the
boom. For instance, the 17th-century tulipmania
had its origin in a mosaic virus, which generated
interesting-looking tulips that fetched high prices
among tulip growers. Because the virus-infected
tulip bulbs were difficult to reproduce, they
2

appreciated sharply, generating a windfall profit
among those who happened to own them. The
initial capital gains created optimistic expectations about the profitability of growing and trading these strains of tulip bulbs. There are reports
of extensive trading in derivative contracts written
on tulip bulbs. Eventually, the interesting-looking
tulips lost their appeal and the price of the erstwhile highly valued bulbs fell, ending the speculative bubble. Peter M. Garber, who has investigated
the tulipmania more thoroughly than anyone else,
is not convinced that the pricing of the rare tulips
was irrational; still, whatever the correct facts of
this case may be, the stylized story is helpful in
understanding the concept of an asset price
bubble.
The British railroad boom was caused by a
major technological advance. There was not only
excitement about the new means of transportation, but the British also welcomed the economic
stimulus of the railroad boom because it marked
the end of a period of economic depression. In
those days, each railroad project had to be approved
by a parliamentary bill. As a consequence of this
official blessing, investors misperceived the risk
of railroad investments. Also, as is often the case
in periods of rapidly rising stock prices, questionable business activities were tolerated—activities
that would have received greater scrutiny in normal times. A striking example was the dubious
accounting practices of George Hudson, who at
one time was chairman of four railroads. Hudson,
who may not even have realized exactly what he
was doing, made dividend payments out of capital,
a practice that was legal at the time and has since
been prohibited. Perhaps because Charles Ponzi
knew that his 1920 scheme was fraudulent, we
now call an arrangement in which earlier investors
are paid high returns out of capital contributed
by later investors a Ponzi scheme rather than a
Hudson scheme.
The bubble in Argentine loans in the 1880s
began with increased demand in the world market
for Argentine agricultural products. Rising world
demand led to an economic boom in Argentina,
which gave the Argentine government easy
access to the world debt market. Argentina also

The Role of Finance in the Investment Bust of 2001

raised equity capital through initial public offerings of companies that specialized in developing
land. When one of these IPOs failed in 1888, the
Baring Brothers helped out with credit. Two years
later, the Argentine government failed to meet
these debt obligations because of falling prices of
raw materials in the world markets. This default
led to the famous Baring crises, which gave rise
to an early example of the central bank—the Bank
of England in this case—serving as a lender of
last resort.
All three bubbles—and history has recorded
many more—started with good news that created
high hopes but eventually ended in tears. In general, bubbles are driven by positive market sentiment—that is, widespread investor optimism.
Positive market sentiment gives rise to a sharp
appreciation of asset prices, which eventually
regress to their fundamental values. Regression
to the fundamental value is often followed by
unwarranted asset depreciation as market sentiment turns overly negative. Hence, market sentiment causes both asset mispricing and excessive
volatility. The problem for the economist trying
to study these issues is that mispricing and excessive volatility are always easy to identify ex post,
but rarely so ex ante. However, even when cases
are identified ex ante investors may or may not be
able to profit from trading against the mispricing.
The consequences of asset mispricing and
excessive volatility are not confined to financial
markets, but can affect fixed investment and production. Financial markets are critical for directing scarce resources to their most productive use.
The efficiency by which financial markets achieve
this goal depends on the accuracy of the prices
that financial markets signal to the investors.
The price signals of the stock market allow corporations to calculate the cost of equity capital
and evaluate the profitability of potential projects. Although the focus of my attention in this
lecture is on the role of the stock market in the
recent investment bust, it is also clear that bond
market mispricing can affect business investment.
In a 1981 study, Yale economist Robert Shiller
showed that the valuation of the U.S. stock market exhibits pronounced fluctuations around its

fundamental value. Multi-year periods of stock
market overvaluation alternate with equally
extended periods of stock market undervaluation.
An example of a period of bearish market sentiment was the early 1970s, when the four-quarter
trailing price-to-earnings ratio of the S&P 500
stock price index was as low as 7; indeed, the
stock market remained low until a sustained
market rise began in mid 1982. During the late
1990s, on the other hand, the trailing P/E ratio
climbed well above 30, even before earnings
dropped as the economy started slowing in 2001.
Such an elevated stock market valuation might
be viewed as excessively optimistic, given that
the median value of the postwar P/E ratio in the
S&P 500 runs at around 15.
The recognition of market sentiment as a
potent force in financial markets warrants the
question as to why arbitrageurs don’t bet against
it. This question needs to be answered before one
accepts the possibility of stock market overvaluation (or undervaluation, for that matter) and its
implication for the allocation of resources.
Using the word “arbitrage” here is potentially
misleading, and so let me explain what is meant
in the context of this discussion. Economists
think of a classic arbitrage as a risk-free set of
transactions, such as simultaneously buying
wheat in Kansas City and selling it in Chicago
for a higher price. The arbitrageur then ships the
wheat from Kansas City to Chicago to deliver on
his Chicago contract. Knowing the transportation
costs, the simultaneous purchase in one city and
sale in the other is risk free.
By extension, other types of arbitrage transactions are based on the assumption that some
relationship will return to normal. For example,
if the spread between the yield on an 11-year
Treasury bond and a 10-year Treasury bond
becomes unusually large, purchase of one issue
and sale of the other promises an arbitrage profit.
However, this case differs from the classic arbitrage, in which the good purchased in the cheap
market can be delivered against the sale contract
in the dear market. Nothing guarantees that the
arbitrage transaction between two Treasury issues
will be profitable, because the spread could widen
3

FINANCIAL MARKETS

and stay that way indefinitely. In the futures
markets literature, the variable relationship
between the price of one asset and another held
as a hedge causes what is known as basis risk.
The issue at hand, then, is the economic
forces that tend to return price relationships to
some concept of “normal”; when we define normal
by the historic mean, we are relying on a statistical
regularity that could in fact be changing for good
economic reasons.
In a seminal treatment on the role of the stock
market for investment and growth, John Maynard
Keynes in the General Theory of Employment,
Interest, and Money discusses several factors that
bear on the accuracy of the stock market’s price
signals. In brief, Keynes hypothesizes that market
sentiment is carried into financial markets by
uninformed investors, causing mispricing and
excessive volatility. Although it appears that mispricing and the ensuing excessive volatility offer
arbitrage opportunities for informed investors,
arbitrageurs are unable to exploit these opportunities due to liquidity constraints.
Keynes attributes the persistence of asset
mispricing and excessive volatility to a lack of
liquidity, which is another way of saying that there
is a dearth of trades that lean against the prevailing
market sentiment. Why do arbitrageurs—hedge
funds, for instance—not put on aggressive trades
that push the market back to its fundamental
value? Certainly, it is not for an initial lack of
funds, because arbitrage trades are self-financing,
at least to some extent. For instance, an investor
who goes long on off-the-run Treasury securities
and short on on-the-run Treasuries can use the
long position as collateral. However, as observed
in the near collapse of Long Term Capital Management in 1998, when the positions are large relative
to the firm’s capital a spread may widen rather
than narrow to such an extent that capital is
wiped out. Only a pure arbitrage where the good
held in a long position can be delivered against
the short position is completely self-financing.
There are two answers to the question of
why arbitrageurs do not bet aggressively against
market sentiment. First, arbitrageurs have limited
wealth and limited time horizons. Asset prices
4

might take a long time—possibly years—to regress
to their fundamental value. Worse yet, asset mispricing might deepen along the way. In the meantime, arbitrageurs that invest their own money may
develop liquidity needs for other reasons. An individual, for example, might need to draw on his
capital as he nears retirement; hedge funds might
be faced with withdrawals as investors become
impatient. As Keynes stated, “Markets may stay
irrational longer than you remain solvent.”
Another reason why informed investors might
not bet aggressively against the prevailing market
sentiment is uncertainty about the assets’ fundamental values. Some apparently overpriced ventures turn out well, and betting against them
would turn out badly. Even the most sophisticated
investor cannot rule out the possibility that the
way he looks at financial markets is inadequate.
The fact that the world in which we live is not
well-charted leads informed investors to tread
cautiously when putting on their trades.

THE RECENT SPELL OF BULLISH
MARKET SENTIMENT
A compelling object of study for the interaction between financial markets and the real economy is the market for initial public offerings. In
countries with sophisticated financial markets,
periods of excessively optimistic market sentiment tend to be accompanied by extraordinarily
strong activity in the market for initial public
equity offerings. During these so-called “hot issue”
markets, the vast majority of companies going
public have just recently been established and
operate in the very industries that are exciting
the exuberant investors.
Hot issue markets are characterized by high
volume, unusually high returns on the first trading day—known as “initial returns”—and, typically, poor long-run performance in the secondary
market. Empirical evidence for long-run underperformance of initial public offerings in the
wake of hot issue markets has been provided in a
seminal study published in 1991 by Jay Ritter.
Given the date of this study, the poor performance

The Role of Finance in the Investment Bust of 2001

of IPOs in the secondary market was public knowledge long before the frantic IPO activity in the
U.S. stock market in the late 1990s. Consistent
with Ritter’s findings, the IPOs with the highest
initial returns during the hot issue market of the
late 1990s were among the worst performing
stocks in the secondary market. From 1998 to
early 2000, the top ten IPOs—ranked by initial
return—climbed between roughly 400 to 700
percent on the first day of trading. As of August
2001, nine of these 10 stocks had depreciated by
at least 80 percent from their offering price; one
stock was delisted after a competitor acquired
the company.
The recurrence of hot issue markets leads to
the question of why history repeats itself in such
an obvious manner. To bet against overvalued
stocks, the investor would have had to sell the
issues short, maintain the short positions in the
face of further price increases for these stocks
and be willing and financially able to wait for
some time, several years in some of these cases.
The short positions could be partially hedged, by
going long on an S&P 500 Index fund, for example;
but in the late 1990s and on other occasions the
spread between the two positions would have
increased for quite some time, and that risk could
not be diversified away.
Whatever the mechanism or mechanisms
creating the mispricing, it is simply not easy for
arbitrageurs to take positions the other way. Moreover, informed investors who understand this
process may find it more profitable to trade with
rather than against the mispriced stocks. This way,
market sentiment creates its own space, obtaining
the capacity to distort asset prices in a sustained
manner.
A valuable gauge of market sentiment in the
stock market is the P/E ratio. In March 2000, the
Nasdaq 100—which accounted for more than 10
percent of the U.S. stock market—traded at a P/E
ratio of about 100. Certainly, there has always been
a handful of stocks that trade at elevated levels.
However, when 10 percent of the entire market
trades at such a lofty level, some questions might
be in order. A group of finance scholars who
studied the earnings growth of U.S. corporations

drew up the following examples. Assume the
P/E ratio of a company takes ten years to revert
from 100 to 20, which is still a somewhat generous level given that historically the P/E ratio of
the S&P 500 has averaged about 15. If we assume
that the annualized return on this stock over the
next ten years is zero, then the company’s earnings have to grow at an annual rate of 17.5 percent
to bring its P/E ratio back to 20. Alternatively, if
the investor demands a 10 percent annual return
on the stock over the next ten years, the earnings
of this company have to grow by an average 29.2
percent per year.
These simple calculations raise warning flags.
Unless the earnings of a company, or a group of
companies such as those in the Nasdaq 100 index,
are abnormally depressed for reasons that can be
investigated and understood, a P/E ratio of 100
seems unlikely to be justified, because future
earnings growth high enough to provide a reasonable rate of return are unlikely. But I do think it
important that we look behind the numbers and
not rely on the P/E ratio or any other simple number in reaching these judgments. Investors are
willing to hold stocks with high P/E ratios if they
expect these companies to grow at an aboveaverage rate. Given that investors disagree about
which companies will be the fast-growing ones,
many companies may trade at elevated prices at
the same time. This brings us to the question of
how predictable earnings growth at the company
level really is. In a recent academic study, it has
been shown that there is virtually no predictability, based on publicly available information, in
earnings growth rates at the company level at
the five- and ten-year horizons. Thus, unless an
investor has some special talent or inside information, he is no more likely to pick the next IBM
or the next Microsoft from the population of fastgrowing companies through rational deliberation
than by chance.
The unpredictability of earnings growth had
been known long before the Nasdaq 100 traded at
a P/E ratio of 100. Keynes, in the General Theory,
said, “The outstanding fact is the extreme precariousness of the basis of knowledge on which
our estimates of prospective yield have to be
5

FINANCIAL MARKETS

made. Our knowledge of the factors which will
govern the yield of an investment some years
hence is usually very slight and often negligible.
If we speak frankly, we have to admit that our
basis of knowledge for estimating the yield ten
years hence of a railway, a copper mine, a textile
factory, the goodwill of a patent medicine, an
Atlantic liner, a building in the city of London
amounts to little and sometimes to nothing; or
even five years hence.” Given that there is no
predictability in earnings growth beyond the very
short horizon, it is not surprising that stocks
with high P/E ratios tend to underperform the
market, as academic studies have shown.

STOCK MARKET VALUATION,
INVESTMENT, AND GROWTH
The median ratio of stock market valuation
to nominal GNP in the period 1920 to 2000 runs
at 48 percent. In 1990, the ratio was at about its
long-term median level, but by the first quarter
of 2000 had increased to an unprecedented 186
percent. By comparison, in the third quarter of
1929, the ratio of stock market valuation to GNP
amounted to only 68 percent. The historic peak
before the run-up of the 1990s was recorded in
the fourth quarter of 1972 at a value of 78 percent.
It appears, certainly, that the high stock market
valuation in the late 1990s left its mark on the
real economy. By reducing the cost of capital, the
stock market appreciation of the 1990s fueled
the longest investment boom in postwar history.
From a trough in the first quarter of 1990, the fraction of fixed private nonresidential investment
in GDP increased from 9.7 percent to a peak value
of 13.2 percent in the third quarter of 2000. This
peak was just a bit below the previous peak of
13.9 percent in the fourth quarter of 1981. By
comparison, the median postwar value was 10.5
percent.
As a result of the investment boom of the
1990s, the real capital stock of the economy
expanded sharply. The rate of increase in real
capital stock climbed steadily from a trough in
1992 at 1.5 percent to 4.2 percent in 2000. When
the economy slowed, it became evident that a
6

capital overhang had developed, at least in some
sectors. As I noted earlier, by the fourth quarter
of last year real private nonresidential fixed
investment had declined by 9.2 percent. Real
investment in information processing equipment
and software was hit particularly hard, with an
annual rate of decline of 19.5 percent in the second quarter, 10.4 percent in the third quarter and
2.8 percent in the fourth quarter. As estimated
by the Council of Economic Advisors, in 2001
the reduced rate of investment meant that the
growth rate of the real capital stock dropped to
2.6 percent.
Like other investment booms in history, the
rapid expansion of the capital stock in the 1990s
followed on the heels of a major technological
advance—the digital revolution. In the early stages
of the boom in computers and communications,
there were extraordinary corporate success stories
as epitomized by the rise of Microsoft and IBM in
an earlier era. On the financial side, these admirable corporate achievements were reflected in
equally impressive capital gains in the stock
market. In recent years, the new technology, which
gave rise to new, fast-growing corporations, created expectations about a “new era” in the real
economy and high returns in the stock market.
During a boom, investors rarely remember
Schumpeter’s dictum of creative destruction.
Eventually, the benefits of technological advances
are passed on to the consumer. Busts are the
inevitable consequence of the erosion of corporate profits through competition and meanreverting rates of growth.
Clearly, no company can indefinitely offer an
earnings growth rate that exceeds the sum of the
dividend yield and the growth rate of potential
GDP. Inevitably, earnings growth rates of individual companies must revert to means reflective
of the aggregate economy’s rate of growth. Against
this background, a P/E ratio of 100 in the Nasdaq
100 is difficult to explain without some kind of
new era thinking. The risk in new-era thinking is
that it is an attempt to rationalize high stock
market valuation. Although the productivity
growth of the U.S. economy has been impressive
over the last couple of years, including the most

The Role of Finance in the Investment Bust of 2001

recent period of recession, bursts of productivity
growth have happened before. More importantly,
even a permanently higher level of productivity
growth in the neighborhood of the rate enjoyed
from 1995 to 2000 does not justify outsized P/E
ratios. Past technological innovations had no
lasting impact on the growth rates of corporate
earnings, which inevitably converge to the growth
rate of the overall economy.
Over the last couple of years, the decline in
corporate profits has been accompanied by a rise
in corporate leverage. The ratio of credit market
debt to net worth for nonfarm nonfinancial corporations rose from a trough of 47.4 percent in the
third quarter of 1997 to a postwar high of 59.1
percent in the third quarter of 2001—the latest
number available. By comparison, the median
postwar value is only 34.2 percent. Note that the
current number might underestimate the actual
rise of debt obligations at the company level
because of the increased use of leasing and the
proliferation of special financing vehicles. The
rise of corporate debt is in part a consequence of
the soaring stock market of the 1990s. As the
equity capital of corporations appreciated, their
borrowing capacity increased. Corporations that
dipped deeply into their borrowing capacity in
the days of the boom found themselves highly
leveraged after their equity depreciated in the
stock market. Excessive use of debt, along with
overcapacity, contributes significantly to the
current wave of bankruptcies—in particular in
the telecom sector. Another implication of the
rise of high leverage is the increased share of
interest payments out of current income. At a
time of tightening lending standards and debt
downgrades in the bond market, high debt obligations might put a drag on capital spending as
corporations find it difficult to finance investment
projects out of current cash flow.

MONETARY POLICY
IMPLICATIONS
Since the beginning of the 19th century, academic experts and policymakers have been dis-

cussing the role of money and credit in financial
bubbles. The debate has been rekindled by events
in Japan, where an asset price bubble in the late
1980s has been followed by more than a decade
of sub-par growth and declining asset prices. It
has been argued that the Bank of Japan could have
prevented—or at least tempered—the bubble
through aggressive monetary tightening in the
second half of the 1980s. We will never know
whether such policy action would indeed have
alleviated the consequences of the bubble on the
real economy in Japan. We can say with some
confidence, though, that such aggressive monetary
tightening was not warranted at the time based
on standard inflation gauges. In fact, in 1987,
Japan’s rate of consumer price inflation was close
to nil.
Returning to the United States, a pertinent
question might be to what degree has monetary
policy contributed to excessive valuation in the
U.S. stock market and the ensuing misallocation
of resources. Is it possible that there was excess
money growth that made its way into asset prices,
rather than the prices of goods and services?
Paradoxically, it seems that the more successful
a central bank is in keeping the rate of inflation
low and stable, the more likely monetary overhang will lead to appreciation of assets. When
expectations about low and stable rates of inflation
are deeply ingrained, asset prices might serve as
a vent for excess money growth.
How can we tell whether a stock market boom
is internal to the stock market—a market bubble—
or a consequence of excessive money growth?
Excessive money growth should spill over to
assets in general, and not just to one class of
assets. In the United States in the late 1990s, we
did not see outsized increases in residential and
commercial real estate values, or in bond prices,
or in prices of foreign exchange. Indeed, the dollar was strong rather than weak in the foreign
exchange markets. The fact that the stock market
boom was somewhat concentrated in particular
segments—especially high tech—and was not
echoed in other asset markets suggests to me that
the stock market boom was not primarily a monetary phenomenon.
7

FINANCIAL MARKETS

When the behavior of asset prices, along
with other information, suggests that monetary
policy is excessively easy or tight, then obviously
it makes sense for policymakers to change course.
But it does not make good sense, I am convinced,
for a central bank to take a position on the appropriate level of the stock market and attempt to
guide the market to the “right” level. A central
bank has only one independent policy instrument,
which you can think of in terms of money growth
or the interest rate depending on your preference.
Attempting to use that instrument for multiple
purposes muddies the policy direction and risks
losing control over the rate of inflation. Compromising on the goal of low and stable inflation
is a recipe for trouble—sustained inflation or
deflation creates problems far greater that those
likely to arise from mispricing in an asset market.

THE OUTLOOK FOR BUSINESS
FIXED INVESTMENT
The current recession is the most persuasive
example in the last 50 years of an economic contraction that originated from a business investment bust rather than consumer retrenchment.
Recessions typically exhibit major declines in
housing construction and consumer durables.
This time, the recession was led by a decline in
business investment spending and accompanied
by a sharp drop in factory orders for capital goods,
both new and unfilled. The latest numbers,
released two days ago, for new orders of nondefense capital goods, excluding the volatile aircraft orders component, show an increase of 1.5
percent in January; shipments of capital goods,
excluding aircraft, rose by 2.5 percent. These
data suggest that the capital spending part of the
economy is on the mend.

8

Business investment last year was driven by
a reassessment of long-run prospects in certain
sectors, especially telecom, and by adjustment to
excess capacity resulting from the prior exuberant
investment boom. That adjustment is now well
along. Assuming final consumption demand continues to grow, excess capacity will be absorbed
over the next few years. It is important to remember that much of the information technology
capital stock has a relatively short life, due to the
rapid rate of technical change in this area. Desktop
computers and servers are replaced every few
years, which means that replacement demand
places a high floor under total investment.
It appears that the rate of return from investment to enhance efficiency is still high. Thus we
can expect to see continued capital deepening in
firms that have not yet taken full advantage of the
new technologies. As prospects for final demand
growth become clearer and the recession in corporate profits comes to an end, we can expect to
see firms once again resume heavy investment in
information technology. In short, there is every
reason to believe that we have ahead of us a
healthy revival of investment and the continued
productivity gains such investment will bring.
This outlook is predicated on my belief that
the Fed will be successful in adjusting policy in
timely fashion to maintain a climate of low and
steady inflation. Price stability is a prerequisite
for sustained economic growth; if inflation
expectations break out on the high side, all bets
are off as we would then see a classic period of
unsustainable exuberance followed by the usual
inflation hangover. That is not the future I see,
but the Fed will have to stay alert and on the job.