View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Improving Productivity in Higher Education
Webster University
St. Louis, Missouri
April 7, 2005

T

he subject of productivity in higher
education is one that has long interested
me. I do not pretend to be an education productivity expert, but rather an
observer of the scene who cannot help applying
the economist’s view of the world to the provision of education services.
I’ll start with a story reflecting an early experience after finishing my graduate work at Chicago.
When I arrived at my first regular teaching position, I put together reading lists for my courses
and sent them to the library so that books and
articles could be placed on library reserve for
students to read. After a couple of classes, my
students complained that the reserve items were
not available. I checked with the library and was
informed that faculty members had to go into the
stacks and pull the items to be placed on reserve,
something I had not been told. I complained: why
should faculty members, even lowly new assistant
professors, do such work when students paid substantially less could do the work? Did it make
sense to use employees with Ph.D.s to pull books
off library shelves?
Over the years I’ve observed many other examples of inefficient use of faculty time. Historically,
universities have simply not paid much attention
to productivity. In fact, I know of no other large
U.S. industry where productivity enhancement is
such a low priority. That said, one of my delights
from serving on the Webster board is that this
university is so well structured to deliver education services efficiently. My lecture is not primarily about Webster, although perhaps I can
encourage an active discussion among faculty
1

and administration about opportunities for productivity enhancements at this university. In fact,
I believe that in today’s world every firm needs a
culture that includes a continuing search for better
and more efficient ways to conduct business, and
that the culture should involve every employee.
Before proceeding, I want to emphasize that
the views I express here are mine and do not
necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal
Reserve System. I thank my colleagues at the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis for their comments. Tom Garrett, senior economist in the
Research Division, provided special assistance.
However, I retain full responsibility for errors.

RECENT TRENDS IN HIGHER
EDUCATION COSTS
College tuition has increased dramatically
over the past decade.1 Between 1990 and 2000,
tuition increases averaged 5.9 percent per year at
public institutions and 5.5 percent at private
institutions. These increases may be compared
to the average annual rate of CPI inflation of 2.7
percent. Tuition increases are driven largely by
increases in labor costs. Total education employment—education at all levels—has risen from
about 8½ percent of total national employment
in 1990 to over 10 percent today. The increase in
tuition and fees has outpaced the growth of disposable personal income. Tuition increases are
straining family budgets, a trend that certainly
cannot continue indefinitely. For many families,
the outlay for children’s education is the second

Tuition data are from the National Center for Education Statistics, various years.

1

ECONOMIC EDUCATION

largest family expense, exceeded only by housing
expense.
Economists and educators have cited several
reasons for the rapid increase in college tuition
seen across the country.2 One reason is an increase
in university costs. Total inflation-adjusted
expenses at public universities increased 28 percent between 1990 and 2000, whereas full-time
enrollment at public institutions increased 9.4
percent over this same period.
The lack of cost-saving incentives faced by
public universities compared to private sector
enterprises may explain the rise in tuitions. Weak
incentives to improve efficiency can result in the
continued existence of excessive staff and underutilized academic programs or research centers,
all possibly coming at the expense of student
instruction. Data from the National Center for
Education Statistics support this view.
Instructional expenditures as a percent of total
expenditures at public institutions have decreased
from 39 percent in 1977 to 34 percent in 2001. In
addition, administration expenditures increased
from 30 percent of instructional expenditures in
1976 to 50 percent in 2001. More alarming is the
fact that total instructional expenditures per student dropped 14 percent between 1990 and 2001
while administrative expenditures per student
increased 14 percent over the same period.3
Some of the increase in administrative
expense arises from growing federal and state
requirements. Public universities, especially,
should document the cost of these requirements
so that state legislatures can decide whether the
benefits are worth the costs. If not, state mandates
should be scaled back. More generally, we need
a better understanding of the costs and benefits
of regulatory provisions that have propelled
growth in administrative expenses.

Another reason for tuition increases is the
recent recession and ensuing state budget crises.
Fourteen states reduced state appropriations for
higher education between fiscal years 2002 and
2003.4 Missouri experienced the second largest
decrease in the nation with a 10 percent cut in
higher education funding. In response to state
budget cuts for higher education, colleges and
universities increased tuition by an average of 10
percent nationally between 2002 and 2003. This
average 2002-2003 tuition increase was nearly
double the average annual increase over the past
decade. Webster University fared relatively better,
increasing tuition only 6.4 percent in 2003.5 The
average tuition increases in Missouri, Iowa, and
Texas were the second highest in the nation at
20 percent, behind only Massachusetts where
tuition increased nearly 24 percent. Some, but
only some, of these increases have been offset by
increases in financial aid.
Perhaps paradoxically, the availability of
financial aid may be a reason for tuition increases.
Discussion of the affordability of higher education
has focused attention of both governments and
donors on the need for financial aid to the almost
complete exclusion of attention on productivity
enhancements that might constrain tuition
increases.
The percentage of students at four-year universities who received some financial aid increased
from 60 percent in 1990 to 74 percent in 2000. At
Webster University, the number of undergraduates
receiving some form of financial aid increased
18 percent between 1999 and 2003.6 Nationwide,
financial aid is now covering a larger percentage
of tuition expenses. For example, financial aid
covered 47 percent of tuition at four-year universities in 1990 compared with 54 percent in 2000.
The increase in the use of financial aid reflects
the great importance society places on education

2

Vedder (1999, 2004a).

3

Expenditure data are from the National Center for Education Statistics, various years.

4

Trombley (2003).

5

Webster University (2004, p. 89).

6

Webster University (2004, p. 90).

2

Improving Productivity in Higher Education

and its general belief that education should be
available to all. I am certainly not opposed to
financial aid but believe that constraining gross
tuition levels deserves equal emphasis.
Another way to view financial aid is that it
reflects what economists call “price discrimination.” Price discrimination simply means that
firms charge different prices for the same product
or service. Many firms engage in price discrimination, such as the movie theater that gives a
discount to senior citizens. For the economist,
the word “discrimination” in this context does
not carry negative connotations; the practice is
sensibly related to profit or revenue maximization
in many contexts. Universities increasingly charge
different tuition to different students, depending
on ability to pay and university efforts to recruit
students with special academic or athletic skills.
The growth of financial aid suggests that universities are increasingly using sophisticated pricing
policies.
Nevertheless, even net of financial aid tuition
increases have been substantial. Thus, in an
increasingly global and technology-driven marketplace, enhancing productivity in higher education
should be of great concern to parents, students,
educators, and the citizenry. In the wake of rising
costs and increasing competition from growing forprofit and on-line education such as the University
of Phoenix, universities must develop strategies
to reverse the downward trend in productivity.
Note that I have said “downward trend in
productivity.” We are using more real resources—
especially, more university employees—to educate
each graduating student and it is hard to claim
that the quality of the graduate is improving commensurately with the increase in educational
resources expended. Thus, productivity in higher
education is falling—more inputs per unit of
output. Declining productivity in higher education is a distressing state of affairs.
7

Vedder (2004a).

8

Gates and Stone (1997).

PRODUCTIVITY IN HIGHER
EDUCATION
Economists define productivity, in the simplest terms, as a measure of output per unit of
input. Productivity in education can be measured
in terms of units, such as average class size, or it
can be measured in terms of dollars, such as the
quality or value to students relative to the cost of
educating students. These definitions allow one
to evaluate how a change in costs, quality, or
quantities influences productivity. Productivity
will increase if student quality increases more
than the cost of educating students. By “student
quality” I mean the skills a graduating student
has. Similarly, a reduction in costs while student
quality remains the same or rises will also increase
productivity. This latter possibility reflects the
basic idea of doing more with less. Higher education, unfortunately, has seen a decrease in productivity over the past decade. Total inflationadjusted operating costs per student of colleges
and universities have increased while there has
been little or no increase in student quality.7
How can universities reduce costs and
increase student quality in an effort to increase
productivity in higher education? Before I can
address this question, it is important that I discuss
several issues that must first be considered before
any cost-saving or quality enhancing policies can
be implemented. These issues are 1. defining the
objectives of the college or university, 2. defining
productivity inputs and outputs, 3. measuring
productivity, and 4. demonstrating productivity
improvements.8 Once these issues are addressed,
strategies to enhance productivity can be analyzed.

Defining Objectives
Defining the university’s objective or objectives is the crucial first step in evaluating productivity. Objectives of the university may include
increasing student quality, increasing access and

3

ECONOMIC EDUCATION

diversity, greater cost-efficiency, a better contribution to the needs of the community and basic
research.9 There may be divergent views among
university officials and state legislators regarding
the top objectives of a university, but improving
student quality is typically the most important
higher education objective claimed by universities and state legislators.10

Defining Productivity
While the economist’s general definition of
productivity, namely outputs relative to inputs,
is straightforward, it is too simple a definition to
guide management strategies aimed at increasing
productivity. A more thorough definition of productivity recognizes that productivity can be
divided into two parts: efficiency and effectiveness. Efficiency refers to the level and quality of
service that can be obtained given an organization’s fixed resources. Thus, an organization is
considered more efficient if it can increase the
level or quality of service without increasing the
amount of inputs used. Effectiveness, on the other
hand, refers to how well an organization meets
the demands of its customers. The customers in
higher education are students, parents, and state
legislatures. Customer demands may include
such outcomes as a specialization of knowledge
in a specific area, career assistance and job placement, and probably most importantly, graduating
well-educated and productive students.
Improving productivity in higher education
thus requires undertaking measures that increase
efficiency and effectiveness. Measures to cut
costs, as universities across the country have
done in the wake of the recent recession and state
budget crises, only address the cost-efficiency
dimension of productivity. Sound management
practices to improve productivity in higher education must also look at the effectiveness of the
organization, be it an academic department, college, or the entire university.
9

Gates and Stone (1997) and Ruppert (1995).

10

Gates and Stone (1997).

11

Gates and Stone (1997) and Bottrill and Borden (1994).

4

Measuring Productivity
Productivity measurement is difficult in most
service industries, and education is certainly no
exception. In education, we need to be wary of
simple measures such as the number of students
per faculty member. Some observers seem to
assume that quality “must” be higher when the
student-faculty ratio is lower. Although one-onone teaching has its place, my own experience is
that a class of 25 is often better than a class of 5
because of student interaction. In any event, when
we study productivity it is important to do the
best we can in measuring output directly and not
make assumptions about what “must” be the case.
Before any measurement of productivity can
occur, administrators need to decide on what
level or levels of the organization’s productivity
should be measured. For example, is the concern
the productivity of an individual, say a professor
or an administrative assistant, or is the concern
the productivity of an academic department or
the university as a whole? All are relevant and
should be measured. An important point in measuring productivity is that measures should not
be constructed prior to setting goals and objectives—doing so will lead administrators to value
something that is measurable rather than measuring something with value.
Measuring productivity in higher education
requires a measure of both efficiency and effectiveness. Efficiency is often measured using ratios,
such as physical output relative to an input or
dollar cost of an input relative to an output. The
exact efficiency measure used depends upon the
objective set by the administration.11 Efficiency
ratios such as enrollment per section or contact
hours per faculty member are reasonable and useful. An objective of improving students’ progress
toward a degree would require measures such as
a withdrawal rate and average course load taken.

Improving Productivity in Higher Education

Examples of cost-efficiency measures include
instructional costs per student, library expenditures per student, and administrative costs per
student.
Measuring effectiveness can be difficult,
though not impossible. Several ideas have been
suggested in the literature.12 One way to measure
effectiveness is to assess community or client
conditions and benchmark them to community
standards or those standards of other institutions
of higher learning. An example could be the
number of graduates who find a job within three
months of graduation. Another option is to measure accomplishments, such as the number of
graduates or the percentage of students taking a
class that requires relatively advanced work, such
as technical research paper. The number of graduates going on to receive advanced degrees is
another such measure. Finally, client satisfaction
is a third avenue to measure effectiveness. Clients
can include alumni or businesses that frequently
hire a university’s graduates. Assessing the satisfaction of these clients can be done via surveys,
focus groups, or personal contacts with top
administrators.

Showing Productivity Improvements
After setting productivity objectives, defining
productivity, and measuring productivity, the
next step is to demonstrate productivity improvements, which can be done in several ways.13 One
is to show an increase in revenue or participation
that results from efforts that did not require an
increase in tuition, fees, or taxes. Another is to
show a significant increase in effectiveness, such
as the employment rates of recent graduates,
without increasing costs or using additional
resources. Numerous measures are possible, and
each university should concentrate effort on
those that best fit its own circumstances.
12

Gates and Stone (1997) and Epstein (1992).

13

Epstein (1992).

14

See Hackett (1992).

STRATEGIES TO INCREASE
PRODUCTIVITY
There is an abundant literature on possible
strategies for increasing productivity in higher
education, which can help universities to understand how they can reduce costs and increase
student quality. Many of these strategies require
changes in the administrative culture and the
mindset of faculty and administrators. Attempts
to implement these strategies may be met with
resistance or even legal challenges from the various professional organizations and associations
that support faculty and administrators.
Strategies for increasing productivity focus
on improving the two key components of productivity that were defined earlier—effectiveness and
efficiency. These strategies include privatization,
decentralization, improving student quality, and
increasing the flexibility of faculty.

Privatization
One way of increasing the cost-efficiency of
higher education is through the privatization of
certain services.14 Most universities are vertically
integrated, meaning they not only provide education but also provide food service, student and
faculty housing, cleaning and maintenance, and
records management. While these services contribute to student learning, there is no reason why
these services cannot be performed by private
contractors.
When vertical integration exists, the full
costs of inside staff, such as wages and benefits,
may be accounted for in other budget or service
categories, thus making it difficult to assess the
full costs of a certain service. The fees charged by
outside contractors, however, will more clearly
represent the full cost of providing a particular
service. In addition, competitive pressures will
increase the likelihood that private contractors

5

ECONOMIC EDUCATION

will provide an efficient quantity and quality of
labor for each service.
An issue that arises regarding the privatization of various university services is student
employment. Currently, many students work for
universities as library assistants, food preparers,
and custodians as part of a financial aid arrangement. Privatization may result in a reduction of
staff, forcing some students to find alternative
financial aid packages. However, even when contractors find that hiring students is not cost effective, concern over student employment ought to
be minimal relative to concern over the growing
costs of universities.

Decentralization
Privatization is part of a larger strategy aimed
at increasing productivity in higher education—
the decentralization of the current administrative structure. While decentralization frequently
occurs in the private sector, universities have
generally not followed suit. Centralized administrative structures in universities have been
criticized for several reasons.15 For one, administrators can generally add staff to meet their needs
without having to justify the additions to anyone
except other administrators.
Decentralization can result in several benefits
for universities. First, academic departments will
have more control over their costs and staffing
needs. Departments will have more flexibility in
aligning their resources to meet changes in student demands. My own experience is that universities provide too little in the way of support
staff for faculty, thus forcing faculty to perform
clerical duties. If individual academic departments had more control over their own budgets,
they might decide to replace a faculty position
with several support staff to improve efficiency.
At the same time, university administrators would
have to resist the temptation to cut support staff
15

See Guskin (1996).

16

Guskin (1996, pp. 12-16).

17

Guskin (1996, p. 14).

6

in times of budget stringency. Creating a structure that gets the incentives right is not easy, but
will be an essential feature of longer run reforms
to improve efficiency.
A case-study of successful administrative
decentralization at Antioch University provides
some insights into the challenges of decentralization.16 One such challenge was that a centralized
administration had to reach a decision to decentralize the administration itself. While paradoxical,
the administration realized that decentralization
was, in Antioch’s case, the only real way to control costs. Another challenge was to realize and
accept that some important senior and middle
managers would be let go, and that these individuals would resist any change in administrative
structure. Antioch cut its centralized administration by 14 people, a reduction of 60 percent, and
realized a 25 percent reduction in central administration costs.17 Resistance by lower management,
faculty, and staff to any change in the administrative structure required ever more vigilant leadership by upper management. All employees
were involved in decisions, ensuring that the
process to decentralize remained a collaborative
one between all ranks of administrators and faculty, and ensuring a continuing commitment to
the decision to decentralize despite opposition.

Improving Student Quality
The quality of students—the knowledge and
skills they gain from a university education—
should be the primary goal of any institution of
higher learning. Just how to increase student
quality, however, remains unclear to many faculty.
One reason for this lack of clarity is that many
faculty, especially those at research institutions,
see teaching as a secondary job responsibility
behind publishing in academic journals and
acquiring research grants. Another reason is that

Improving Productivity in Higher Education

most faculty members do not have training in
good teaching strategies.18
Arthur Chickering and Zelda Gamson summarize good teaching practices in their article,
“Seven Principles for Good Practices in Undergraduate Teaching.”19 These practices include
encouraging student/faculty contact, encouraging active learning, encouraging cooperation
among students, giving prompt feedback, communicating high expectations, encouraging more
time on each task, and respecting diverse talents
and ways of learning. An important point is that
the current passive lecture format in most universities does not account for most of the practices
just discussed. Even in smaller teaching-oriented
colleges many of these practices are likely to be
absent. And, there are huge new opportunities to
employ new technologies such as the Internet to
improve efficiency. For example, there is no reason for libraries to subscribe to statistical publications when the same data are readily available
through the Internet.

Increased Flexibility of Faculty Staffing
Instructional expenditures have historically
accounted for nearly 35 percent of total university expenditures nationwide.20 Although universities spend roughly one-third of every dollar
on instruction, different productivity concepts
are appropriate for research and teaching functions. With respect to research, it is appropriate
to measure productivity in terms of the quantity
and quality of academic research and the amount
of external funding acquired. With respect to
teaching, it is appropriate to measure productivity
by teaching loads and academic advising.21
18

Guskin (1996).

19

Chickering and Gamson (1991).

20

From the National Center of Education Statistics, various years.

21

Brown and Gamber (2002).

22

Waggaman (1991).

23

Mortimer, et al. (1985) and Waggaman (1991).

24

The following discussion of tenure is from McGee and Block (1991).

The important issue of how best to balance
research and teaching would take me too far afield,
but I do want to comment on the issue of how
best to allocate faculty teaching time. Much of
the discussion relating to the role of faculty in
contributing to productivity in higher education
involves increasing the time that faculty spend
in the classroom, enhancing the quality of instruction, and increased flexibility of faculty staffing.
Given the expense of instruction relative to overall university expenditures, an important costsaving and quality-enhancing strategy is to better
align faculty with student needs.22 Currently, in
many universities, as student demands for certain
majors or classes ebb and flow over time there is
little change in the number of faculty in each
department. A failure to match teaching capacity
with student demand is completely opposite the
private sector, where changes in business conditions directly influence staffing levels.
To rein in costs, universities must have the
flexibility to hire more faculty or increase teaching
loads of current faculty when demand for a major
increases and, conversely, universities must have
the flexibility to reduce the number of faculty
when demand for a major decreases. Everyone
understands that an auto producer must be able
to shift production from large SUVs to small cars
when energy prices soar; why are universities so
resistant to making similar adjustments when
student interest in Subject X soars and interest
in Subject Y sags?
Several policies can increase the flexibility
of faculty.23 But, arguably, the greatest obstacle
to increased flexibility of faculty is tenure.24 An
economic argument for tenure is that it saves initial expense on the part of the university. The sav-

7

ECONOMIC EDUCATION

ing arises because faculty with tenure, or those
hired with the possibility of tenure, will work at
a lower salary in return for the guarantee of lifetime employment. However, while there may be
initial cost savings from tenure, the resulting
inflexibility imposed by tenure has greater costs
in terms of both dollars and student quality.25
Tenure prevents significant staffing changes in
response to changes in student demands, and
also may prevent lower quality faculty from being
replaced by higher quality faculty.
Administrators and management professionals
have suggested strategies that can increase faculty
flexibility in the presence of tenure, although
each of these strategies is not without problems.26
Some of these strategies may be met with opposition from faculty or even legal challenges. One
strategy is to impose tenure quotas on the number or percentage of the faculty who may hold
tenure at any one time.
Here is an example of where decentralization
could pay dividends. If a department feels strongly
that it wants to tenure a brilliant scholar, who
promises to greatly enhance the prestige of the
department, the university could permit the
department to exceed the tenure quota provided
that it agrees on some other mechanism to reduce
future outlays should student enrollments drop.
Department members might agree to accept proportional pay cuts, or that one or more would go
on unpaid leave in the future if necessary. Strong
department leadership would be willing to take
such risks, as is typical of strong leadership in
the business world.

CONCLUDING NOTE
When discussing the difficulty created by
tenure of reallocating faculty resources, I suggested several possible approaches. Here is
another: A university might even consider using
the price system, by raising tuition for courses in
high demand and cutting tuition for courses in
25

McGee and Block (1991, p. 545).

26

Mortimer et al. (1985)

8

slack demand. That is what auto producers do
when the demand for SUVs falls and for small
cars rises.
I know that many will dismiss such an idea
out of hand, and that is part of the reason universities have a productivity problem. Yes, education
is different but it is not all that different. Too few
administrators and faculty are willing to even
consider innovations that could make a real difference. We need thinking on all levels about
innovative ways to deliver educational services.
Not every idea will turn out to be a good idea,
but every idea needs a hearing. Great universities
have a culture of scholarly excellence, of nurturing students, and of open and free inquiry. They
need to add to that culture a spirit of productivity
enhancement so that tuition resources raised from
families, and funds from state legislatures and
donors are used wisely. To my knowledge, at
most universities there is no culture of productivity enhancement nor are university trustees
much interested in the issue.
Universities that can deliver high quality
education at an attractive price will make a difference—an enormous difference—to our society. I
must say that my experience as a Webster board
member convinces me that Webster is such an
institution. Its growth is evidence that educational innovation works, and I am proud that I
have been able to make a small contribution as a
Webster board member.

REFERENCES
Bottrill, K. and Borden, V. “Appendix: Examples
from the Literature,” in V. Borden and T. Banta,
eds., Using Performance Indicators to Guide
Strategic Decision Making. San Francisco, CA:
Jossey-Bass, 1994.
Brown, Walter and Cayo, Gamber. Cost Containment
in Higher Education. San Francisco, CA: Jossey
Bass, 2002.

Improving Productivity in Higher Education

Chickering, Arthur and Gamson, Zelda. “Seven
Principles for Good Practices in Undergraduate
Teaching,” in New Directions in Teaching and
Learning no. 47. San Francisco, CA: Jossey Bass,
1991.
Epstein, Paul. “Measuring the Performance of Public
Services,” in Marc Holzer, ed., Public Productivity
Handbook. New York: Marcel Dekker Inc., 1992.
Gates, Susan and Stone, Ann. “Understanding
Productivity in Education.” Institute on Education
and Training, RAND, January 1997.
Guskin, Alan E. “Reducing Student Costs and
Enhancing Student Learning: The University
Challenges of the 1990s.” Occasional Paper No. 27,
Association of Governing Boards of Universities
and Colleges, Washington, DC, 1996.
Hackett, John T. “Productivity Through Privatization,”
in Richard Anderson and Joel Meyerson eds.,
Productivity and Higher Education. Princeton, NJ:
Peterson’s Guides, 1992.

National Commission on the Cost of Higher
Education. Straight Talk About College Costs and
Prices. Phoenix, AZ: Oryx Press, 1998.
Norman, Donald. Things That Make Us Smart:
Defending Human Attributes in the Age of the
Machine. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley, 1993.
Ruppert, Sandra. “Roots and Realities of State-Level
Performance Indicator Systems,” in G. Gaither, ed.,
Assessing Performance in an Age of Accountability:
Case Studies. San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass, 1995.
Trombley, William. “The Rising Price of Higher
Education.” San Jose, CA: National Center for
Public Policy and Higher Education, Winter 2003.
Vedder, Richard. “The Tuition Puzzle: Putting the
Pieces Together.” Washington, DC: The Institute for
Higher Education Policy, February 1999.
Vedder, Richard. Going Broke by Degree: Why College
Costs Too Much. Washington, DC: American
Enterprise Institute Press for Public Policy
Research, 2004.

McGee, Robert W. and Block, Walter E. “Academic
Tenure: An Economic Critique.” Harvard Journal
of Law and Public Policy, Spring 1991, 14(2), pp.
545-72.

Vedder, Richard. “Ugly Truths About Runaway
College Tuition.” The American Enterprise Institute
The Education Economist, December 2004.

Mortimer, Kenneth; Bagshaw, Marque and Masland,
Andrew. Flexibility in Academic Staffing. ASHEERIC Higher Education Report no. 1. Washington,
DC: The George Washington University Association
for the Study of Higher Education, 1985.

Waggaman, J. Strategies and Consequences:
Managing the Costs in Higher Education. ASHEERIC Higher Education Report no. 8. Washington,
DC: The George Washington University School of
Education and Human Development, 1991.

National Center for Education Statistics. Digest of
Education Statistics. Washington, DC.

Webster University. Sum and Substance. 2004.

9