View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Free Trade: Why Are Economists and
Noneconomists So Far Apart?
Trade, Globalization and Outsourcing Conference
Reuters America, Inc.
New York, New York
June 15, 2004
Published in the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, September/October 2004, 86(5), pp. 1-6

F

ree trade—are you fer it or agin it? Why?
I’m sure that this audience knows that
most economists support free trade
policies; however, public support for
these policies can be characterized as lukewarm
at best and certain groups are adamantly opposed.
It is not unusual to hear the following reservations expressed about trade: “Trade harms large
segments of U.S. workers.” “Trade degrades the
environment.” “Trade exploits poor countries.”
We have all heard these criticisms and lots of
others.
Many economists, including me, try to change
public attitudes by explaining the advantages of
free trade in speeches and articles intended to
reach a wide range of audiences. But, let’s face
it: We are not very successful in changing public
attitudes. Why, and how can we become more
persuasive? What I will explore today is the gap
that separates economists from the general
public.1
I’ll first present some evidence on the gap
between economists and the general public on
attitudes toward trade. I’ll then outline two principles that help to understand this gap and that
help to frame revealing questions when studying
particular disputes. Finally, I’ll offer a few suggestions on closing the gap.
1

See Coughlin (2002) for additional discussion of this gap.

2

See Alston, Kearl, and Vaughan (1992).

3

See Mayda and Rodrik (2001, p. 1).

Before proceeding, I want to emphasize that
the views I express are mine and do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal
Reserve System. I thank my colleagues at the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis for their comments; Cletus Coughlin, vice president in the
Research Division, was especially helpful. However, I retain full responsibility for errors.

THE GAP
A 1990 survey of economists employed in
the United States found that more than 90 percent
generally agreed with the proposition that the
use of tariffs and import quotas reduced the average standard of living.2 These results are somewhat dated; however, most observers agree that
“[t]he consensus among mainstream economists
on the desirability of free trade remains almost
universal.”3 I don’t have any data to report economists’ views on particular trade disputes, but
am willing to offer the following assertion: In
most specific cases, disinterested economists do
not defend trade restriction. By “disinterested
economists” I mean economists not hired by
firms engaged in the particular disputes and not
employed by government agencies involved in
the disputes.

1

INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FINANCE

If fact, I suspect that disinterested economists’
attitudes about specific disputes are even more
lopsided in favor of free trade than the 90 percent
who generally favor free trade policies. The reason
is that specific disputes almost always involve in
a pretty obvious way special favors to particular
industries. In contrast, economists’ attitudes in
general are influenced by theoretical cases in
which protection may make some sense. I do not
want to try to explain these theoretical cases here,
but do want to note that actual trade disputes
rarely fit such cases.
Let’s now consider attitudes held by the general public. Public opinion polls reveal that the
attitude of the general public toward free trade is
not simply one of either being for free trade or for
protectionism.4 Questions asking about free trade
in principle reveal support for free trade, albeit
not as strong as economists’. However, questions
asking about free trade in practice reveal strong
reservations. That is, when we get to specific
trade disputes, public support for free trade tends
to crumble, whereas economists rarely support
trade restriction in specific disputes.
A majority of Americans do support free
trade in principle. A February 2000 survey by
the Pew Research Center asked the following
question: “In general, do you think that free trade
with other countries is good or bad for the United
States?” “Good” was the response of 64 percent
of the respondents, while “bad” was the response
of 27 percent of the respondents. The remaining
9 percent “did not know.” The general public’s
support for free trade is, therefore, a good bit
lower than economists’ support.

Much evidence exists suggesting that the
general public understands the benefits from
free trade in terms of increased product selection, higher quality, and lower prices. The Pew
Research Center found that 81 percent of the
respondents said that it was either “very good”
or “somewhat good” that trade makes available
different products from different parts of the
world.5
Despite an intuitive understanding of many
of the benefits of free trade, the general public
has strong reservations about embracing such a
policy. One set of reservations concerns distributional effects of trade. Workers are not seen as
benefiting from trade. Strong evidence exists indicating a perception that the benefits of trade flow
to businesses and the wealthy, rather than to
workers, and to those abroad rather than to those
in the United States. A poll taken by the Gallup
Organization in November 1999 found that 56
percent believed that increased trade helped
American companies, but that only 35 percent
believed that increased trade helped American
workers. In fact, 59 percent believed that trade
hurts American workers.
Related to concern about adverse distributional effects of trade is the view that trade is
disruptive. Regardless of whether a sufficient
number of new jobs are created to compensate
for the jobs lost, many Americans are reluctant
to support free trade because trade causes painful
adjustments for those who lose their jobs even if
they find new jobs relatively quickly. The costs
incurred by these workers are not necessarily
offset by the creation of new and possibly better
jobs.6

4

A wealth of information on trade opinions can be found at the following website maintained by the Program on International Policy
Attitudes: www.americans-world.org/digest/global_issues/intertrade/trade-general.cfm.

5

Other polls find similar results. EPIC-MRA—a polling firm conducting educational, political, industrial, and consumer market research
analysis—found large majorities agreeing that trade allows American consumers to have a larger selection of goods to choose from (87 percent),
improves the quality of American goods (80 percent), and allows low-income families to buy many products that they might not otherwise
afford (74 percent). Polling by EPIC-MRA also found that Americans expected that they would either be paying much more (24 percent) or
somewhat more (37 percent) if they were able to buy only American-made goods.

6

An October 1999 survey conducted by the Program on International Policy Attitudes asked respondents to choose between the following
two statements. First: “Even if the new jobs that come from freer trade pay higher wages, overall it is not worth all the disruption of people
losing their jobs.” Second: “It is better to have the higher paying jobs, and the people who lost their jobs can eventually find new ones.” The
first statement was favored by 56 percent of the respondents, while 40 percent favored the latter statement.

2

Free Trade: Why Are Economists and Noneconomists So Far Apart?

Especially noteworthy is that the sentiments
of poll respondents likely reflect altruism rather
than self-interest. First, only a small minority of
Americans perceive the effects of trade on themselves to be negative. Second, Americans tend to
view others as more vulnerable to increasing trade
than themselves. Thus, it appears that the concern
about the disruptive effects of job loss is for others
rather than for themselves.
The concern for workers appears to go beyond
U.S. borders. Based on a June 2002 survey conducted by the Chicago Council on Foreign
Relations, it is clear that the majority of respondents—93 percent to be exact—think that member
countries in international trade agreements should
be required to maintain minimum standards for
working conditions. Both moral concerns for the
foreign workers and economic concerns for U.S.
workers appear to affect the respondents’ views.
Roughly three-quarters of the respondents to
an October 1999 survey by the Program on International Policy Attitudes felt that the United
States has a moral obligation to attempt to ensure
that workers in foreign countries making goods
for the United States do not work in harsh or
unsafe conditions. Only 23 percent of the respondents felt that the United States should not judge
what working conditions should be in another
country. A country’s national sovereignty was not
viewed as a compelling reason to remain silent.
Moreover, the possibility that trade expansion
might improve working conditions abroad, even
if not to the point of matching conditions in the
United States, was either not considered or
ignored.

Additional results reveal a perception that
countries that do not maintain minimum standards for working conditions have an unfair
advantage that allows for the exploitation of
workers and the production of goods at unduly
low cost. Here there is concern about the jobs of
American workers competing with cheap imports.
A related aspect of this argument is that the
respondents were not convinced by arguments
that forcing higher standards for working conditions in foreign countries might cause elimination
of jobs of extremely poor people abroad who
desperately need jobs.
Strong support exists for including standards
dealing with workplace health and safety, limitations on child labor, the right to strike, the right
to bargain collectively, and minimum wages in
trade agreements. In addition, contrary to World
Trade Organization principles, Americans support
unilateral decisions to bar the import of products
made under substandard working conditions.
Besides the effects of increased trade on
workers, many Americans are concerned that
trade adversely affects the environment and that
environmental standards should be incorporated
into trade agreements. In a June 2002 poll by the
Chicago Council on Foreign Relations, 94 percent
of the respondents felt that member countries in
international trade agreements should be required
to maintain minimum standards for protecting
the environment.7 Support also exists for restricting the importation of goods whose production
damages the environment.8
On all these issues of protecting the environment, health and safety, wages and hours, working conditions, and so forth, I suspect that poll

7

Additional evidence supporting environmental standards in the context of trade can be found in the results of a November 2000 poll by
Tarrance Group and Greenberg Quinlan Research. Respondents were asked to choose which of the following two statements were closer to
their views. First: “Future trade agreements should contain safeguards that require the United States and other countries to enforce strong
environmental protections, even if it limits trade.” Second: “Expanding trade is critical to the U.S. economy and trade agreements are good
for our economy, even if they do not contain strong environmental protections.” The majority of respondents, 62 percent, chose the first
statement as more closely reflecting their views, while only 22 percent supported not linking trade and the environment in trade agreements.

8

An October 1999 Program on International Policy Attitudes survey asked respondents which of the following statements they agreed with
the most. First: “Countries should be able to restrict the import of products if they are produced in a way that damages the environment,
because protecting the environment is at least as important as trade.” Second: “If countries can put up trade barriers against a product any
time they can come up with something they do not like about how it is produced, pretty soon they will be putting up barriers right and left.
This will hurt the global economy and cost jobs.” Overwhelming support was found for the first statement, with 74 percent of the respondents
preferring the first statement, while 22 percent supported the second statement.

3

INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FINANCE

results reflect general concerns more than trade
concerns per se. In the absence of a specific setting that makes the costs clear, respondents are
not likely to favor accepting weaker protections
for the environment, for example. Few Americans
favor a world trading system in which U.S. policies on environmental and other conditions
could be controlled by foreign governments
through their willingness to accept goods exported
by the United States. Nevertheless, these frequently expressed sentiments indicating a desire
to apply U.S. standards to foreign producers do
affect U.S. positions in trade disputes.

WHY THE GAP?
THE SIMULTANEITY PRINCIPLE
Two principles, I believe, explain the gap
between the economist’s view and the public’s
view on trade. These are what I will call the
“simultaneity principle” and the “political-favors
principle.” I’ll discuss the first of these now and
the second shortly.
The not very insightful or artful term “simultaneity principle” encompasses the economist’s
case for free trade. I’m using the term because
economists think about the economy through a
model in which outcomes in markets are determined together as a consequence of the interactions among markets. Such interactions are
represented abstractly in a mathematical model
with many equations that must be solved
simultaneously.
“Simultaneity principle” sounds complicated,
and is meant to. I used to teach the introductory
macro course to economics majors and remember
well my struggle to explain the characteristics of
the basic Keynesian macro model with 10 equations that had to be solved simultaneously.
Teaching this material required many hours of
classroom time. I could use the model to explain
why, for example, an effort by households to
increase their saving might have as the primary
9

4

effect for a time a reduction in total employment,
with the precise outcome depending on the nature
of monetary policy and the degree of price flexibility. Many other exercises explain counterintuitive outcomes—counterintuitive, that is, until
you have worked with the model long enough to
change your intuition. It is simply a fact that the
outcomes can be complicated to explain when
everything in the economy depends on everything else. Indeed, in large models with scores of
equations it can be difficult even for economists
to identify remote and indirect effects. Elaborate
simulation investigations are typically required
when the models are large and complex.
The economist’s case for free trade rests primarily on the fact that imposing or removing trade
restrictions invariably helps some firms and
people and hurts others but with a positive net
benefit for the country as a whole from moving
toward freer trade. As I emphasized in a speech
in November 2003, a key reason why the general
public is reluctant to embrace free trade is that
many do not understand the benefits.9 And the
reason people do not understand the benefits is
that they do not understand the interactions and
connections across markets. For one example,
people may see the genuine costs imposed on
workers who lose their jobs to imports, but fail
to see the benefits to consumers of lower-priced
goods from abroad.
Economists are trained from their first course
in the subject to understand the interactions
across markets. The interactions are numerous
and sometimes remote from the initial disturbance that sets off a chain of such interactions. It
is usually possible to explain the nature of these
effects to non-economists, and formal statistical
studies can often yield estimates of the magnitude
of effects.
Sometimes, an interaction is pretty obvious
and it may not be difficult to convey the point.
For example, restricting imports of a raw material
will have positive effects on domestic producers
of the raw material, and their employees, but will

The speech was presented to the Louisville Society of Financial Analysts in Louisville, Kentucky, on November 19, 2003. It was published
in the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, March/April 2004, 86(2), pp. 1-7.

Free Trade: Why Are Economists and Noneconomists So Far Apart?

hurt domestic users of the raw material. Indeed,
by forcing up the price of the raw material, domestic producers of the finished product may find
themselves at a competitive disadvantage to foreign companies with a cheaper source of the raw
material. Thus, saving jobs in the industry producing the raw material comes at the cost of
reduced jobs in industries using the raw material
and higher costs to consumers of the finished
product.
Most journalists want to smoke out all sides
of a story. In the case of a story involving a trade
dispute, smoking out the indirect effects is critical
to explaining all sides of the story. Understanding
the simultaneity principle leads immediately to
questions about possible indirect and remote
effects of trade restrictions. Those questions
need to be addressed to economists and industry experts who can uncover the connections
across markets and the indirect effects of trade
restrictions.
It is important to recognize that the case for
free international trade is really part of a more
general case for free markets. The analysis of
interregional trade within a country is in most
respects exactly the same as the analysis of international trade. International trade is a separate
subject within economics primarily because it
deals with restrictions on trade that do not ordinarily exist between regions of a country.
Economic restrictions are of two sorts—
restrictions on trade in goods and services and
restrictions on movement of factors of production.
In today’s world, the most severe of these restrictions is on the movement of labor. Migration
across national borders is controlled almost everywhere, and capital mobility is in many cases subject to some degree of restriction.
Although trade is generally free across state
borders within the United States, some restrictions do exist. In making the case for free international trade, it is sometimes helpful to refer to
analogies created by restrictions within the United
States. One example is state professional licensing requirements that prevent doctors, lawyers,
and barbers from practicing in states where they

are not licensed. Another is regulation of taxis,
which may prevent taxis licensed in one jurisdiction from picking up passengers at airports in
other jurisdictions. This restriction creates the
inefficiency of a taxicab going one way empty,
even when potential passengers are waiting in a
long line for a taxi. Such examples can be multiplied many times over, and are often useful in
explaining the nature of inefficiencies created by
trade restrictions.
One of the most difficult interactions to
explain is the connection between imports and
exports. Even though a country can attract capital
for a time—perhaps for a period measured in
decades—in the long run, imports must be paid
for by exports. Most people understand this point,
but not the same point put the other way—exports
require imports. Restrictions on certain imports
lead, quickly or eventually, either to increases in
other imports or decreases in exports. This point
is extremely important, for it means that “saving
jobs” by restricting imports saves only jobs in the
particular protected industry. Saving such jobs
necessarily means losing jobs in other importcompeting industries or in export industries.
Consequently, one of the points economists
emphasize over and over is that saving jobs in
particular industries does not save employment
for the economy as a whole. Economists are sometimes charged with insensitivity over job losses,
when in fact most of us are extremely sensitive
to such losses. What good economics tells us is
that saving jobs in one industry does not save
jobs in the economy as a whole. We urge people
to be as sensitive to the jobs indirectly lost as a
consequence of trade restriction as to those lost
as a consequence of changing trade patterns.
Indirect job loss is part of the story of trade restriction and can be smoked out if journalists will
consult knowledgeable experts.
I’ve already emphasized that the case for free
trade is really part of the case for free, competitive markets more generally. This fact opens up
another avenue for informative coverage of trade
issues. Why should we be more concerned about
job losses from international trade than we are
5

INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FINANCE

about job losses from domestic competition or
changing technology? Outsourcing has been an
issue recently. Some firms have replaced staff
handling phone inquiries with staff abroad; other
firms have replaced call-center staff with automated message systems. Is it better for the caller
to be able to talk with a person, who may be
abroad, or to go through endless menus of the
form, “press 1 if you are a retail customer, press 2
if you are a wholesale customer, press 3 if …”?
When I go through these menus, I’m usually looking for “press 4 to transfer to our competitor.”

WHY THE GAP? THE POLITICALFAVORS PRINCIPLE
Trade restriction requires legislative intervention, or regulatory intervention authorized by
legislation. That means that trade restriction is
inherently political. I do not mean to use “political” in a pejorative sense, for politics is an essential part of democracy and democracy is an
essential part of liberty.
Legislation involving economic issues typically creates gains for some and losses for others.
Every legislator is aware of this fact. Legislation
is typically drawn in such a way to minimize the
visibility of the losses, to avoid creating resistance
to the legislation and lost votes. Legislation is
often drawn to increase the visibility of the gains
to those who benefit, to attract votes. However,
sometimes legislation hides the benefits, to reduce
the possibility that publicity will lead to opposition. Those who benefit, of course, may be well
aware of the benefit. It is perfectly natural that
legislators should write legislation this way.
You and I would do the same thing if we were
legislators.
Because they understand the importance of
the political-favors principle, journalists know
immediately what sorts of questions to ask. When
evaluating a particular trade restriction, who gains
and who loses? What is the net for the economy
as a whole of the gains and losses?
When I read a story that reports only the benefits of trade restriction, I know the story is incom6

plete. I also know that losers from restriction often
do not realize they’ve been hurt. I’m reminded of
the story some years ago of a bank employee who
found a way to skim fractional interest payments
into his own account. The depositor didn’t realize
that his account had been rounded off to $308.27
whereas his account really had $308.274. The
extra 4 tenths of a cent, if left in the account, would
have earned interest and have led to a larger
account balance in the future. The accountant
who skimmed a few tenths of a cent from thousands of accounts put a lot into his own account,
until he got caught. Many trade restrictions work
this way—they cost consumers just a little, but
add up to a lot for the protected industry.
Perhaps there is no reason to feel much outrage about such trade restriction, but in most cases
legislators would not be able to impose a small
sales tax on the good and funnel the revenues to
the favored industry. The stratagem works when
it is hidden. Telling the full story of any particular
trade restriction may require adding up lots of
pennies extracted from those who do not realize
they are paying.

CLOSING THE GAP
Once the reasons for the gap between economists and noneconomists are understood,
approaches to closing the gap become clear. I’ve
already emphasized the important role of journalists. In this area, as with all other public policy
areas in a democracy, a free and enterprising
press is essential to effective government in the
interest of the nation at large.
As a former university professor, it is natural
for me to believe that formal education plays an
important role. Nevertheless, every educator is
aware of the short half-life of much of the material
taught. Students’ knowledge usually peaks at
exam time, and then starts to decay. What I hope
my students retained is some very basic principles,
such as the gains from voluntary exchange, and
respect for economics as a discipline. Years after
formal study, people need to be reminded of the
analysis and how it applies to real-life policy

Free Trade: Why Are Economists and Noneconomists So Far Apart?

issues. Educators can play a continuing role, by
writing and speaking for noneconomist audiences.
But I began this speech by expressing disappointment over the effectiveness of economists’
speeches, and that is why I’m emphasizing the
importance of the role of the press today. I’ve
suggested that every story on trade issues, to be
complete, must explore who gains, who loses,
and the net of gains and losses for the nation as a
whole.
Whenever faced with a policy choice that
creates winners and losers, we face the difficult
problem of somehow weighting one person’s
benefit against another’s loss. The issue appears
constantly, and we take two general approaches.
The first is that the government does not take
property without compensation. The second is
that the government stands aside from the competitive market system and lets the chips fall as
they may.
Government provides compensation when it
takes land for a highway. It is important to note,
however, that the compensation is an estimate of
fair market value. We understand the loss to a
family when government takes land that has been
in the family for generations, but we do not try
to compensate for the sentimental value of the
land. It is simply not possible to maintain a vigorous, growing economy while giving great weight
and actual compensation for loss of sentimental
value.
Government provides generalized compensation, or adjustment assistance, through unemployment insurance. The United States does not
have a general program to compensate owners of
capital. Unemployment assistance is relatively
limited, as it must be to retain incentives to return
to work. Existing legislation also provides some
extra benefits for adjustment to losses arising from
international trade. My view of this legislation is
that in the abstract there is no particular reason
to provide more assistance for job loss due to
international trade than for any other reason, but
as a practical matter such assistance is warranted
if it helps to gain acceptance for trade liberalization. We should recognize that many of the arguments for maintaining certain industries in the

United States are essentially sentimental, the
case being essentially the same as that for avoiding taking land that has been the family farm for
generations.
We live in a society that on the whole accepts
an economic system that lets the chips fall where
they may. Some decry the nature of this system,
but its general support rests on the progress and
the higher standard of living it affords. We should
not underestimate the individual protections
built into this system. Our sophisticated market
system includes insurance markets that permit
individuals and firms to protect themselves
against many forms of risk. More importantly,
the vitality of our markets creates opportunities
for new firms and new employment to absorb
those displaced by changing competitive conditions. Our dynamic economic system, and not
restrictive trade legislation, provides the best
protection for our citizens.

THE BOTTOM LINE
We all know that a vigorous and just democracy depends on a free and enterprising press. I
urge you to keep my two principles—the simultaneity principle and the political-favors principle—in mind when reporting on trade issues.
The first requires that you identify the complicated and indirect effects of trade restrictions,
and the second requires that you understand the
winners and losers from restrictions. I believe
that the general voting public will be more likely
to favor free trade policies if it understands the
issues at a deeper level.
So remember: Every trade story requires at
least three sections. One reports who gains, one
reports who loses, and one reports the net of the
gains and losses for the country as a whole. There
is an enormous opportunity here: Sound and
impartial reporting case by case by case will do
more, I believe, to promote free trade policies
than all the economists’ speeches extolling the
benefits of trade laid end to end.
7

INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FINANCE

REFERENCES
Alston, Richard M.; Kearl, J.R. and Vaughan, Michael B.
“Is There a Consensus among Economists in the
1990’s?” American Economic Review, May 1992,
82(2), pp. 203-29.
Coughlin, Cletus C. “The Controversy Over Free Trade:
The Gap Between Economists and the General
Public.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review,
January/February 2002, 84(1), pp. 1-22.
Mayda, Anna Maria and Rodrik, Dani. “Why Are
Some People (and Countries) More Protectionist
than Others?” Working Paper No. 8461, National
Bureau of Economic Research, September 2001.
Poole, William. “A Perspective on U.S. International
Trade.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review,
March/April 2004, 86(2), pp. 1-7.

8