View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Fed Transparency: How, Not Whether
Global Interdependence Center
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Philadelphia, Pennsylvania
August 21, 2003
Published in the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, November/December 2003, 85(6), pp. 1-8

C

entral bank transparency is a topic
discussed almost as much as policy
actions themselves. Market participants have always wanted to know
the implications of policy actions for the likely
future course of monetary policy, but the longstanding practice of central bank secrecy has
frustrated their search. In recent years, monetary policymakers have disclosed much more
than they did in the past, partly because of
growing interest in being more accountable and
partly because of recognition that policy actions
will be more effective if the market understands
them better.
Discussion of transparency has gone well
beyond the financial pages. The past decade has
seen numerous professional papers on transparency issues. In this literature, transparency is
taken to mean public disclosure, and much of the
discussion has centered on questions such as:
How specific should central banks be about their
policy objectives? Should they announce the
weights they apply to their inflation and output
stabilization objectives in conducting monetary
policy? Should central banks disclose their economic forecasts? Should transcripts of the policy
debate be published and, if so, how soon? Should
policymaking meetings be televised?
My intent today is not to review the entire
range of transparency debates but instead to concentrate on issues relating to the effects of monetary policy information on markets and on the
effectiveness of monetary policy. I certainly do
not believe that political accountability issues
are unimportant, but my chosen topic is large

enough to more than fully exhaust the time available today.
Before proceeding, I want to emphasize that
the views I express here are mine and do not
necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal
Reserve System. I thank my colleagues at the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis—especially
Robert Rasche, senior vice president and director
of research, and Daniel Thornton, vice president
and economic advisor—for their assistance and
comments, but I retain full responsibility for
errors.
My plan is to proceed by first outlining my
model of how the economy works. That view is,
I believe, the essential starting place for a discussion of transparency. I will then discuss two cases
in which, depending on what view you have,
market participants did not interpret Fed statements correctly or the Fed did not communicate
clearly. Under either interpretation, there was
some miscommunication.
I will use “transparency” as shorthand for
accurately conveying accurate information including all the information market participants need
to form opinions on monetary policy that are as
complete as possible.

FUNDAMENTALS OF
MACROECONOMIC EQUILIBRIUM
Analysis of policy communication logically
begins with a description of the economic interaction between the central bank and the markets.
I’ve provided my view of this interaction on sev1

MONETARY POLICY AND INFLATION

eral occasions; here I provide just enough of a
sketch of this view to enable me to discuss communication issues.1
At a highly abstract level, I believe that the
appropriate model of the economy is that markets
behave in an efficient, fully informed way. Equilibrium requires that market participants form
accurate expectations about the behavior of the
central bank. The economy will function most
efficiently if central bank policy has two features.
First, the central bank must have clearly understood, appropriate, and feasible objectives.
Second, the central bank must have a highly regular and predictable policy rule or response pattern that links policy actions to the state of the
economy, including all information relevant to
assessing the economy’s probable future course.
Pushing the idea of a full rational expectations
equilibrium one step further, there should be a
political equilibrium in which the central bank
pursues objectives broadly accepted in society.
Without broad political support, monetary policy
objectives are subject to change through normal
democratic processes and such change, or the
prospect of it, adds to uncertainty about future
monetary policy.
With regard to objectives, the Federal Open
Market Committee (FOMC) has stated repeatedly
that one of its objectives is a low and stable rate
of inflation. Although the FOMC has not quantified that target, for present purposes it is useful
to discuss communications issues as if the FOMC
had announced a specific target. Put another way,
with regard to market behavior I believe that the
difference between an explicit target and one
inferred from FOMC decisions is minimal today
and has been for some years.
The FOMC also has the objective of maximum
possible stability of output and employment.
Taken together, low inflation and output stability
along the economy’s growth path are believed to
contribute to maximum possible economic growth
over time. Because of its importance to output and
1

2

employment stability, it is also useful to point
explicitly to the objective of financial stability.
Stabilizing policy responses to severe market
disruptions such as a stock market crash or a liquidity crisis further contribute to fostering maximum possible economic growth.
The FOMC implements policy by setting the
intended federal funds rate. As is well known, a
central bank cannot achieve a stable outcome for
the economy if it pegs the interest rate at an inappropriate level for any length of time. Thus, the
central bank must change its interest rate target
from time to time to achieve its objectives.
In my abstract model of the economy, the
market and the central bank have the same information base; neither has an informational advantage. As new information arrives, the appropriate
interest rate to achieve policy objectives may
change. Given my assumption that the market
and the central bank have the same information,
all players respond the same way to the arrival
of new information. The central bank determines
the appropriate policy response knowing that
the market also has the same information and
understands its implications for the economy
and for policy actions.
At a highly abstract level, I believe that this
model accurately describes the way the U.S. economy has been working in recent years. As we
add more and more detail to the model, we find
areas in which the equilibrium is not complete.
Thus, my view is that the economy has been converging toward a full rational expectations macroeconomic equilibrium, but is not all the way there
as yet. In particular, over the past quarter century
there has been enormous progress in improving
the clarity of the Fed’s objectives and in the Fed’s
discipline in pursuing the objectives. With regard
to the inflation objective, there is a world of difference between today’s situation and that prevailing
in the 1970s.
There has also been enormous progress in
provision of more accurate and timely informa-

William Poole, “Synching, Not Sinking the Markets,” presented before the Philadelphia Council for Business Economics, Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia, 6 August 1999; www.stlouisfed.org/news/speeches/1999_08_06_99.html>. William Poole and Robert H. Rasche,
“Perfecting the Market’s Knowledge of Monetary Policy,” Journal of Financial Services Research, December 2000, 18(2/3), pp. 255-98.

Fed Transparency: How, Not Whether

tion about policy actions. The FOMC announces
its policy actions on the afternoon of the conclusion of each regularly scheduled meeting and
promptly after any interim meeting. The Fed is
more open in many other ways as well; for example, the FOMC now releases a policy statement
at the conclusion of its meeting and dissents, if
any, are also disclosed at that time.
My fundamental conception of the Fed’s communication challenge is to further the progress
toward a more complete rational expectations
equilibrium. Put another way, my question is this:
How might the Fed modify its communications
strategy so that the market can converge on a
rational expectations equilibrium with less error
than we observe today?

MISCOMMUNICATION—
TWO CASES
It is instructive to consider examples in which
communications were less clear than they might
have been and to analyze how such problems
might be avoided in the future. Communications
successes are also worth studying. There is a growing literature along these lines, such as analysis
of the market effects of the change in FOMC practice in February 1994 to immediate disclosure of
policy decisions at the conclusion of FOMC
meetings.
Accurate communication is far more difficult
than it seems at first glance. Complete accuracy
requires that speaker and listener interpret actions
and words the same way. In a normal conversation, individuals have an opportunity to clear up
ambiguity by raising questions about intended
meaning. It is possible to ask for clarification, or
ask again, before acting. What central bank officials (and, of course, other officials as well) say,
however, can have immediate market impact;
market participants may act before ambiguities
or miscommunication can be corrected. This fact
imposes special burdens on central bankers.
To illustrate how difficult the communications process is in the central bank context, let me
relate to you an exercise I go through at the end

of each FOMC meeting. Before the decisions of
the meeting are made public, I estimate—“guess”
is a much better word—the market reaction to
the policy action and press release that are made
public at 2:15 p.m. after the meeting. Then I listen
to the radio or a cable news channel to determine
how the bond and stock markets respond. Ordinarily, but not always, I get the direction of the
market responses correct, but my estimates of
the magnitudes of the market reactions are often
wide of the mark. My personal experience is that
I find it exceedingly difficult to predict how people will interpret policy actions and the nuances
of the press release. I suspect that other FOMC
participants perform similar exercises, though I
have not asked any of them.
I’ve sometimes thought I should keep a formal
record of my market predictions, but have not yet
decided to do so. It could be a sobering exercise
for all FOMC members to maintain such a record.
Communication is obviously imperfect if the
speaker—the FOMC in this case—cannot predict
accurately how listeners will respond.
Now consider two specific examples of FOMC
communications that I believe were misread. The
first is the evolution in the announcement of the
“tilt” in the directive, and the second is the communication last May about “an unwelcome substantial fall in inflation.” I emphasize that I’m
offering my personal interpretation of these
cases; other FOMC members may have different
interpretations.
In the early 1980s the FOMC began to vote
on language pertaining to possible future policy
actions. This language was alternatively called
the “tilt,” “bias,” or “symmetry” of the policy
directive. The language was generally regarded
as applying to possible policy action through the
period ending at the next FOMC meeting. Historically, the FOMC did not release this language
until the minutes of that meeting were published
(subsequent to the next regularly scheduled
FOMC meeting). That meant that the statement,
when released, had no information value about
the probable direction of policy actions because
the statement referred to a period already past.
3

MONETARY POLICY AND INFLATION

In an effort to be more transparent, the Committee decided in December 1998 that it would
release the tilt language immediately with its
policy action at the conclusion of a meeting when
it expected the information to be particularly
important. The minutes of that meeting, released
in late January 1999, contain a paragraph on the
Committee’s discussion of a disclosure policy. A
key passage from the minutes reads as follows:
Nonetheless, the members decided to implement the previously stated policy of releasing,
on an infrequent basis, an announcement
immediately after certain FOMC meetings
when the stance of monetary policy remained
unchanged. Specifically, the Committee would
do so on those occasions when it wanted to
communicate to the public a major shift in its
views about the balance of risks or the likely
direction of future policy. Such announcements
would not be made after every change in the
symmetry of the directive, but only when it
seemed important for the public to be aware
of an important shift in the members’ views.

At the conclusion of the meeting in May 1999,
the FOMC for the first time released a statement
that included the “tilt” in the policy directive.
The formal statement referred to “the federal funds
operating objective during the intermeeting
period.” Many members of the FOMC believed
that the market overreacted to the May tilt statement and to subsequent tilt statements as well.
The statements did attract considerable attention,
and market analysts began to speculate about
changes in the intended funds rate at future
FOMC meetings based on the tilt, or symmetry,
announced by the FOMC.
The market reaction to the statement released
immediately after the May 1999 FOMC meeting
should not, perhaps, have been a surprise to the
Committee. The Committee had said, after all, in
its minutes of the December 1998 meeting that it
would make such an announcement “when it
wanted to communicate to the public a major
shift in its views...”
2

4

In an attempt to clarify its communications,
the FOMC established a subcommittee to review
both its policy directive and the public announcement following FOMC meetings. Communications
practice changed in two respects. First, the FOMC
would issue a statement after every meeting. That
step eliminated the possibility that the mere
existence of a statement would be treated as an
unusual event signaling a major change in policy.
The second step was a new “balance-of-risks”
statement that assessed the outlook for price stability and sustainable economic growth in the
foreseeable future. Despite the FOMC’s stated
intention that its new “balance-of-risks” was not
to be interpreted as an indicator of future FOMC
actions, the evidence suggests that it was one of
the pieces of information that market analysts did
use to form expectations of a likely near-term
policy action.2 My perception, however, is that
the balance-of-risks language did not come to
have a completely settled meaning in the market.
For my second example, consider the statement following the FOMC meeting last May that
referred to “an unwelcome substantial fall in
inflation.” In subsequent commentary in the financial press, this statement was interpreted to mean
one or more of the following things: (i) A cut in
the intended funds rate at the June 2003 meeting
was likely. (ii) Any increase in the intended funds
rate within the next year was highly unlikely. (iii)
The FOMC would implement “unconventional
monetary policy actions” such as aggressively
purchasing long-term Treasury bonds. Interpretation (iii) gained force and a major rally in longterm Treasury markets ensued, driving the 10-year
Treasury rate to a more-than-40-year low of 3.13
percent.
Speaking strictly for myself, I believe there
are two important points that the statement of
May 6 tried to communicate that didn’t really
come across. First, inflation has now receded to
a level where for the first time in 40 years inflation
risks are symmetric: From the current inflation

Robert H. Rasche and Daniel L. Thornton, “The FOMC’s Balance-of-Risks Statement and Market Expectations of Policy Actions,” Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, September/October 2002, 84(5), pp. 37-50.

Fed Transparency: How, Not Whether

rate neither sustained increases nor sustained
decreases are desirable. Second, in the words of
my FOMC colleague Governor Bernanke, “FOMC
behavior and rhetoric have suggested to many
observers that the Committee does have an
implicit preferred range for inflation. Most relevant here, the bottom of that preferred range
clearly seems to be a value greater than zero measured inflation, at least 1 percent or so.”3 On several occasions in the past I have stated that my
preferred inflation target is zero inflation, properly
measured. Since I believe that the major price
indices employed today are subject to some
upward bias and measurement error, the goal
“zero inflation, properly measured” translates
into a low, positive measured rate of inflation. In
my judgment, 1 percent measured inflation for
the consumption price index is in the neighborhood of price stability as I define it.
To me, though, an announcement that inflation
is now down to an appropriate long-run target
should not by itself have led to a sharp decline
in the 10-year bond rate. What I think happened
was that the market, seeing that the intended
federal funds rate was down to 1 percent, thought
that the Fed was running out of room to implement policy through setting a target federal funds
rate. If the Fed were to switch to setting a target
for long-term interest rates, then such a policy
would reduce or eliminate for a time downside
price risk on long-term Treasury bonds. That
would justify bidding the 10-year bond price up
(the rate down), because the price risk would
become one-sided—bond prices could go up but
not down, or at least not down by very much
very soon. Over time, however, the market came
to believe that the FOMC was not contemplating
the need for an unconventional policy in the near
term, and bond prices fell. Indeed, bond yields
backed up to a level above where they had been
just before the May FOMC meeting.
3

DISCLOSURE STRATEGY
Given my emphasis on the economic purpose
of disclosure, I see no room for merely satisfying
curiosity about what goes on in FOMC meetings.
The general nature of what goes on in meetings
can easily be inferred by reading meeting transcripts, which are released with a five-year lag.
The appropriate communications goal, in the context of how the economy functions, should be to
minimize market uncertainty about monetary
policy. It is important to emphasize that uncertainty about future monetary policy actions cannot be eliminated because those actions depend
critically on information that cannot itself be predicted. What needs to be minimized, therefore,
is uncertainty about central bank responses to
new information.
I’m going to concentrate my discussion on
the policy statement issued at the conclusion of
each FOMC meeting, but some of my comments
have broader applicability. The communication
at the conclusion of each FOMC meeting is a critical one because market participants are primed
to react to news of a policy action and its rationale. The statement is necessarily short and it sets
the stage for FOMC members to provide subsequent, more thorough discussions of policy. I’ll
concentrate on two aspects of the statement. The
first is the extent to which the statement should
provide a forecast in some form of future policy
actions, and the second is the structure of the
statement itself.
Given my rational expectations macroeconomic model and my desire to create a more
complete equilibrium—an equilibrium in which
expectations errors are minimized—the central
communications issue is to explain to the market
the nature of the policy rule that determines
how new information feeds into policy actions
designed to achieve as closely as possible the
central bank’s policy objectives. Achieving clarity with respect to policy objectives is actually

Ben S. Bernanke, “An Unwelcome Fall in Inflation?” presented before the Economics Roundtable, University of California, San Diego, 23
July 2003, in La Jolla, California; <http://www.federalreserve.gov/ boarddocs/speeches/2003/20030723/default.htm>.

5

MONETARY POLICY AND INFLATION

quite simple compared with explaining the nature
of the policy rule.
The fundamental problem is that there is no
policy rule by which we can calculate the appropriate policy action from observed data. There is
instead a regularity to policy of the sort “you know
it when you see it.”
Sometimes we observe a striking change in
some particular variable, such as the unemployment rate, that all but demands a policy response.
Most of the time, though, policy actions flow from
an accumulation of data, most of which point in
the same direction. It just is not easy to describe
“you know it when you see it.” I would be absolutely delighted if researchers could provide a
quantified policy rule, at least as a base case.
The rule suggested by John Taylor is helpful, but
very incomplete. I think it unfortunate that we
have not seen in the professional literature an
evolution of a policy rule that builds substantially
on the work begun by Taylor. But the problem is
a very difficult one; for one thing, it is necessary
from time to time to discount changes in an important economic variable because of suspected
anomalies in the statistics themselves.
Thus, we have to live with the unfortunate
fact that the monetary policy world is one of “I’ll
know it when I see it.” We need to keep that fact
in mind when designing communications policy.
Explaining a policy action—elucidating the
considerations that led the FOMC to decide to
adjust the intended funds rate, or to leave it
unchanged—is worthwhile. Over time, the accumulation of such explanations helps the market,
and perhaps the FOMC itself, to understand what
the policy regularities are. It is also important to
understand that many—perhaps most—policy
actions have precedent value. If the FOMC takes
action A in circumstances X, the next time circumstances X arise the FOMC should also take
action A, or have good reason not to do so. One
of the advantages of public disclosure of the reasons for policy actions is that the required explanation forces the FOMC to think through what it
is doing and why.
Discussing future policy actions is a different
matter. In my view of the world, future policy
6

actions are almost entirely contingent on the
arrival of new information. For that reason, I
believe that an FOMC forecast, or tilt, toward a
specific future policy action is more likely to be
misleading to the market than helpful. It is true
that at the conclusion of a meeting I have a sense
of the probabilities of various future policy
actions, and I suspect that other FOMC members
think about the policy process the same way. I
might believe, for example, that new information
would be very unlikely to lead me to want to raise
the intended funds rate at the next meeting but
might, in combination with information already
known, make the case for cutting the intended
rate. And I might assign a probability to a future
cut of 0.5, or 0.3, or some other value. But even
in this situation I would not want to rule out an
increase in the intended rate, for I can certainly
imagine new information that would compel an
increase.
Question: Could the FOMC as a practical
matter decide on the probability and convey that
probability accurately to the market? My own view
is that only rarely could the FOMC agree on what
the probability should be, and even then it would
be extremely difficult to convey that probability
to the market. Moreover, if the probability is high,
it seems to me that in most cases it would make
more sense to simply take the policy action at
the current meeting rather than broadcast it as
likely at the next meeting.
The old “tilt” language caused problems, I
think, precisely because different FOMC members
had different interpretations of what probabilities
attached to what words. And I think the market
view was, at least sometimes, that if the FOMC
chose to change the bias, it must be doing so to
announce a significant probability of future policy action. I think some observers also tend to
react as follows: If the probability is high, why
shouldn’t the FOMC act now? If the probability
is low, why talk about it? If the probability is in a
middle range, will disclosing the tilt help the
market to price securities more efficiently—that
is, more in line with the true likelihood of future
policy action?

Fed Transparency: How, Not Whether

Furthermore, the tilt language was sometimes
used in an effort to reduce the number of dissents
in the FOMC. In this case, the language may have
provided inaccurate information, because the
majority may not have believed that there was
any significant probability of future policy action
in the direction indicated.
Another problem is that of acting consistently
with guidance about the probable direction of
future policy. Sometimes new information arrives
that is clearly compelling in the direction of not
acting in accordance with the guidance. A forecast of a policy action, made before the new information arose, may then have created a dilemma
for a central bank. The central bank then either
breaks what the market regards as a commitment
or lives up to the commitment at the cost of
ignoring new information calling for a different
policy action. However, more often information
will be indecisive; once guidance is announced,
the burden of proof tends to shift toward showing
why the forecasted action is inadvisable, whereas
without guidance the burden of proof tends
toward justifying an action.
All in all, then, I’ve come to the view that
FOMC language forecasting future policy actions
is probably counterproductive in most circumstances. I do not, however, rule out the desirability
of forecasting future policy in some cases given
that the rational expectations model from which
I am reasoning is clearly an abstraction. What I
think we need to do is to analyze the circumstances under which the abstract model provides
misleading guidance with respect to communications strategy.
It is true that policy works in part by changing
expectations and therefore the term structure of
interest rates; that is the basic argument favoring
disclosure of future policy direction. However,
the crux of the matter is this: If the market fully
understands the policy rule, or policy regularity,
and has the same information the FOMC has,
then an FOMC forecast of future policy direction
is useless information because it is redundant. If
the market and the Fed have the same information,
then the market can determine the probabilities

that new information will arrive pointing toward
future policy actions. Understanding policy objectives and the policy rule, the market can put itself
inside the Fed’s head and make the same guesses
the Fed can make.
If information on the Fed’s thinking about its
future policy direction is not redundant, then
that fact alone does not necessarily call for the
Fed to forecast future policy actions. The issue
for me is quite different. If the market doesn’t see
what I see, why not? What is the market missing,
and what do we make of the fact? Perhaps the
better course would be to disclose the underlying
information the market is apparently missing, or
call attention to information the market is neglecting. That to me is a better strategy than hinting at
an unconditional policy direction, because the
essence of what the market needs to know is not
the intended federal funds rate in six weeks. What
the market needs to know is the policy response
function by which the central bank acts in a consistent way over time and one that is efficient in
fostering success in achieving policy objectives.
This discussion assumes that the market is
missing something. But, could the problem be
that the market sees something I do not? How can
I be so sure that I know the appropriate direction
for future policy actions? If it is the Fed that is
missing something and not the market, then disclosing a policy tilt will clearly be misleading, or
the odds are that it will turn out to be misleading.
Historically, the FOMC (and other central
banks) went to great lengths to avoid providing
guidance about future policy direction. Indeed,
one of the arguments that the Fed used in the
defense of secrecy in the Merrill case in 1975 was
that the immediate release of the information in
the directive or in FOMC deliberations would
produce expectations that would destabilize
financial markets. That argument is incomplete
at best. Some disclosures clearly stabilize rather
than destabilize markets; secrecy can create incorrect market guesses about what the Fed is doing.
One such case arose on Thanksgiving eve 1989,
when the Open Market Desk intervened to supply
reserves for technical reasons. At this time there
7

MONETARY POLICY AND INFLATION

was no announcement of the intended funds rate.
The intervention was widely interpreted by market participants as a signal that the FOMC had
reduced its target for the federal funds rate from
around 8.50 to about 8.25 percent. It took several
trading days before the market sorted out the confusion. On this occasion secrecy produced unnecessary volatility in financial markets. Numerous
other examples provide convincing evidence, in
my view, that, in general, disclosure of actual
policy actions is stabilizing rather than destabilizing. But it is not appropriate to generalize from
the value of immediate disclosure of policy actions
to disclosure of “everything.”
To discuss the format of the policy statement
at the conclusion of each FOMC meeting, I’ll start
with an observation. Suppose the statement is
confined to one page. With even those few words,
the richness of language and the importance of
word order in conveying meaning yield the result
that the statement contains an enormous range of
possibilities. The multiplicity of possible meanings is made even larger since each statement is
read against the backdrop of the previous one.
Thus, what is relevant is not just word choice and
order but changes from the previous statement.
As an aside, the importance of statement
changes can make it difficult to improve the
statement over time. To avoid misinterpretation
of changes, it is best if a changed approach or
format can be announced in advance so that the
change in approach is clearly separated from a
change in policy.
If the statement is to convey policy intent
accurately and with minimal ambiguity—surely
desirable characteristics in terms of minimizing
expectational errors in the market—then the
number of possible meanings must be narrowed
in some way. One way would be for the FOMC to
choose among a relatively few standard phrases,
at least in language providing a summary statement of the policy stance.
Some will regard this approach as providing
“boilerplate” language with little real meaning.
My own judgment is that it is better to provide
boilerplate with clear meaning than rich language
with a multiplicity of possible meanings. It just
8

is not true that lots of words equals lots of disclosure and greater transparency.
Because the market responds immediately to
policy actions and statements, it is important
that the FOMC not find itself in the position of
having to clarify its statements to correct misinterpretations; explaining the explanation can add
to uncertainty and raise questions about future
policy statements, which market participants
might come to expect to be clarified or interpreted.
The best way to avoid these problems is to narrow
the range of phrases used in the statement.
As I explained earlier, my view is that the
statement should concentrate on explaining the
policy action and its rationale, and not hint at
future policy actions. Given information available at the time of a meeting, I believe that the
standing assumption should be that the policy
action at the meeting is expected to position the
stance of policy appropriately. The purpose of the
statement should be to explain why the policy
action, or lack of action, has positioned policy
appropriately given the information available.
As a matter of logic, the current balance-ofrisks language creates some ambiguity. If risks
are assessed as unbalanced, why was policy not
adjusted further to create a balance going forward?
A possible answer is that an unbalanced risk
assessment foreshadows future policy action.
But the “tilt” interpretation of an unbalanced
risk assessment seems at odds with the rationale
for substituting the balance-of-risks language for
the previous tilt language. What would be clearer,
I think, would be to use the balance-of-risks language to explain that information since the previous meeting indicated that risks were becoming
unbalanced in a particular way, and for that reason the FOMC adjusted the intended federal funds
rate.
Separating growth risks from inflation risks,
as in the May statement, makes a lot of sense.
When employment change and inflation data are
plotted in a scatter diagram, all four quadrants
contain lots of observations. Sometimes employment and inflation rise together, or fall together.
However, just about as often the two variables
move in opposite directions. Because all four

Fed Transparency: How, Not Whether

quadrants are populated, a summary policy judgment has to be communicated indicating the
FOMC’s weighting of the risks. It is relatively
easy to explain that a policy tightening was occasioned by a rising risk of higher inflation and
stronger employment growth; but when employment growth and inflation are headed in opposite
directions, the summary policy language needs to
indicate that the FOMC acted, or didn’t, because
it gave more weight to the inflation risk than the
employment risk, or vice versa. The issue is not,
by the way, that inflation risk is more or less
important than employment risk, but rather that
current information might suggest that recent
employment changes, say, are transitory.
This discussion makes clear that a minimally
accurate summary statement explaining a monetary policy action is still pretty complicated. The
FOMC must weigh inflation risks, employment
risks, and form a judgment balancing or weighting the two risks. Beyond that, from time to time
special factors will intrude, such as the tragic
events of 9/11 or unusual liquidity crises.

CONCLUDING OBSERVATIONS
Transparency is a worthy goal, but improving
transparency is hard work. My thinking is still
evolving, but one thing I know is that the more I
consider the issue the harder it seems.

I’ve tried to present a framework for thinking
about how to improve transparency. I start with
a view of the world based on a standard rational
expectations macroeconomic model. An efficient
equilibrium requires that the markets understand
what the central bank is doing. The communications challenge for the central bank is to explain
more thoroughly and completely what it is doing.
That means, above all, explaining how new information feeds into policy actions. I have a lot of
skepticism about forecasting future policy actions
because they properly flow from new information
that is not itself predictable.
Accurate communication requires settled
meanings for words. For any given word, we can
consult a dictionary and we usually discover that
each English word has several meanings, which
can be quite different. There is no dictionary in
which we can look up the several meanings of a
paragraph. The meaning of a policy statement—
preferably only one—must be established by the
central bank, through consistent practice over
time and through more extended discussion of
what the language means.
I think it fair to say that systematic study of
the how of transparency is in its infancy, and I
hope that my remarks here spark others to analyze
these issues.

9