View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Economic Growth and the Real Rate of Interest
Bryant College
Providence, Rhode Island
October 14, 2003

M

y wife, Gerie, and I are absolutely
delighted to be back in Rhode
Island, here at Bryant College. As
much as I love St. Louis, Little
Rhody, where I lived for almost a quarter century,
sure feels like home.
I came to Rhode Island, to Brown University,
in 1974. The economy was in the middle of a
nasty recession. Interest rates began falling in mid1974—temporarily as it turned out—but at that
time rates as low as today’s seemed impossible.
The rates in the market as I speak are at lows not
seen since the 1950s in the United States. The oneyear constant-maturity Treasury rate, for instance,
averaged 1.22 percent during the third quarter of
this year. A lower yield was last seen in 1954, 49
years ago.
In most market discussion, and in some
Federal Reserve commentary as well, the current
low interest rates are ascribed to easy monetary
policy. The argument usually goes something like
this: The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)
lowered its target short-term nominal interest rate,
the federal funds rate, to a low level, and all other
market-determined interest rates followed. While
this description is certainly accurate on one level,
it is overly simplistic and masks a number of
important issues. In particular, what is it about
the economy today that permits the Fed to set the
intended federal funds rate at such a low level?
No one doubts that setting the funds rate at 1
percent in 1999 would have produced an explosive inflation.
The interest rates I’ve mentioned are nominal
interest rates. A nominal rate contains a component meant to compensate investors for expected
inflation over the holding period. I will concen-

trate this morning on real interest rates, for that
is where the really interesting story lies today.
Real interest rates are interest rates adjusted for
expected inflation.
Most of the explanation of why nominal
interest rates are so much below their level of 20
years ago is that inflation and expected inflation
are much lower today than over most of the period
since, say, 1970. However, although inflation and
expected inflation have drifted down slightly
over the last few years, the big story is that real
rates have declined dramatically since 1999.
What determines real interest rates? How are
these rates related to the pace of economic growth?
And what does trend productivity contribute to
the real rate of interest? These are several of the
issues I’ll discuss this morning.
Before proceeding, I want to emphasize that
the views I express here are mine and do not
necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal
Reserve System. I thank my colleagues at the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis for their comments. James B. Bullard, vice president in the
Research division, provided especially valuable
assistance. However, I retain full responsibility
for errors.

REAL INTEREST RATES
Irving Fisher of Yale University was perhaps
the most famous American economist in the first
half of the twentieth century. One of his many
contributions to economic science was his
analysis decomposing the nominal interest rate
into a real component and an inflation component.
This decomposition was so powerful an idea
that it remains with us today as a fundamental
1

ECONOMIC GROWTH

principle for economists analyzing interest rate
determination.
The decomposition is not hard to understand.
Consider a 1-year Treasury security with a yield of
1.22 percent, the average in the third quarter.
Suppose that one year from now the 12-month
inflation rate turns out to be 1.0 percent. Then,
that investment will realize a paltry 0.22 percent
real yield, or inflation-adjusted yield. Should the
inflation rate be 2.0 percent, then the real yield
will be –0.78 percent.
Now consider an investor who is contemplating buying a Treasury security with a maturity of
one year. The investor wants to be compensated
for any decline in the purchasing power of money
over the term of the investment, but can’t know
the rate of inflation in advance. Thus the investor
forms an expectation as to the rate of inflation. If
the expected rate of inflation is high relative to
the nominal yield on the bond, the investor will
probably look for some other investment. This
phenomenon appeared in spades in the late 1970s;
fearing inflation, many investors shunned bonds
and bid up the prices of land, fine art, gold, and
other goods expected to retain value.
There is little question that expectations play
a critical role in determining interest rates. Since
inflation is controlled over the medium- to longterm by the Federal Reserve, expectations of
future monetary policy are a key component of
observed nominal interest rates. Today, and quite
consistently in recent years, investors have been
confident that the Federal Reserve will maintain
low and stable inflation. For that reason, inflation
expectations have been quite low. Based on market
readings from the Treasury’s inflation-indexed
securities, longer-term inflation expectations
today are approximately 2 percent based on a
10-year maturity.
Although investors want to realize as high a
real yield as possible, given the risk assumed,
they may not in some circumstances be able to
expect even a positive real yield. Today, the oneyear nominal interest rate is about 1¼ percent
while expected inflation, according to several
measures, over the next year is about 1½ percent.
Over a 10-year horizon, investors today expect
2

inflation of about 2 percent and a real yield a bit
above 2 percent. Four years ago, the expected real
yield on Treasury securities was in the neighborhood of 4 percent. Apparently, investors do not
see good opportunities to earn a substantial real
yield today. What has happened?

THE REAL COMPONENT AND
ECONOMIC GROWTH
I’ve been discussing the real yield on Treasury
securities. Treasuries have zero default risk, or
at least as close to zero as we’ll find. However,
because of arbitrage, other, generally riskier, instruments will be priced to yield a suitable amount
above this risk-free rate. In particular, investments
in productive capital should have a real yield
above the risk-free yield, but the two yields should
fluctuate together over time because investors
can choose what investments to make. What determines the real yield on productive capital? There
is some well-established theory that helps to
answer this question. However, the theory I’m
about to discuss abstracts from important complications raised by uncertainty and connections
among countries through international capital
flows. Growth theory helps us understand fundamental economic forces but should not be interpreted as providing precise quantitative guidance.
Many people think about wealth in financial
terms, but for some purposes that view can be
misleading. Every financial asset is someone’s
financial liability. For the world economy as a
whole, then, financial wealth nets out to zero.
Beyond financial wealth, American households
own the nation’s capital stock, either directly or
through ownership of financial claims on businesses. (Of course, some of the U.S. capital stock
is owned by investors abroad, but I’ll neglect this
fact as it is not important for the issue at hand.)
This collection of real assets—buildings, machines,
land, transportation equipment, highways, intangible capital, and so on—is the productive capital
that, combined with labor, produces national
output. The statistical measure of that output is
gross domestic product (GDP). Calculations vary,

Economic Growth and the Real Rate of Interest

but estimates of the ratio of the value of the capital
stock to one year’s GDP are in the neighborhood
of 3. So, with U.S. GDP in current dollars running
at an annual rate of just under $11 trillion, the
U.S. capital stock is worth something approaching
$33 trillion right now.
Economists analyze the relationship between
inputs and output using the concept of a production function. The production function shows
how inputs of capital and labor are combined to
produce output. One of the features of the modern
industrialized world is productivity improvement—that is, using the same inputs to produce
higher output of goods and services. Technology
is improving over time. This fact is no mystery
to anyone who has lived in a growing economy
for more than a few years. We see technological
improvements all around us. Prices of goods like
TVs and computers can decline because producers
are constantly finding ways to create more output
from inputs of labor and capital.
Total output grows from larger quantities of
inputs and from higher output per unit of input.
Because the standard of living is measured by
consumption per capita, it is useful to measure
total output per hour of labor input. Output per
hour of labor input, or labor productivity, rises
as more capital is employed relative to labor and
as technological change raises output for any
given amount of labor and capital.
If there were no shocks to the economy, a
constant pace of productivity improvement combined with a constant rate of labor force growth
would determine a balanced growth path for the
economy. Along the balanced growth path, all
markets in the economy are in equilibrium and
expectations of the future are consistent with
actual outcomes. And also along this balanced
growth path, households holding the capital stock,
either directly or through ownership of businesses,
would receive a real return. What would the level
of that real return be?
In standard models of economic growth, this
real return turns out to be the rate of productivity
improvement plus the rate of labor force growth.
For the United States, business-sector productivity
has improved at an annual rate of about 2½ per-

cent in recent years. Estimates of the long-run rate
of labor force growth are around 1 percent. Therefore, a value of 3½ percent is a good, back-of-theenvelope calculation concerning the long-run
risk-free real rate of return in the U.S. right now.
In a standard model, this would also be the longrun rate of output growth.
Let me try to provide some insight, at least
qualitatively, into this result. First, from a household’s point of view, interest is compensation for
delaying consumption. At a 4 percent rate of interest, for example, delaying one dollar’s worth of
consumption for one year, and saving instead, permits consumption of $1.04 at the end of the year.
Now consider the role of population growth.
A growing population needs a growing capital
stock—factory buildings, machines, houses,
schools, aircraft, highways, and so forth. If the
capital stock does not grow, then the amount of
capital per capita declines as population grows.
To provide the growing capital stock, people and
businesses must save—must forego current consumption out of current production. The higher
is the rate of population growth, the higher must
be the rate of saving and investment to equip the
growing population with capital. A higher real
interest rate persuades people to save more to
provide capital for the growing population.
The role of productivity growth can be analyzed in similar fashion. Assume, as economists
usually do, that a worker is paid his marginal product, at least in equilibrium. Suppose the worker’s
output is worth $20 per hour today and, because
of productivity growth, $21 per hour in one year.
Would you prefer to work an hour when your pay
is $20 or $21, which is 5 percent higher? The
answer is obvious. But not all work can be delayed
to next year. A higher real interest rate can persuade people to provide labor now. Working an
hour now, saving and investing the hourly earnings of $20 at 5 percent interest yields $21 dollars
in one year, the same amount that would be realized from delaying work for one year.
In short, the higher is population growth and
the higher is productivity growth, the higher will
be the equilibrium real rate of interest. The result
that the real rate of interest is precisely equal to
3

ECONOMIC GROWTH

the sum of population and productivity growth
rates depends on the details of the model, but the
general qualitative result makes a lot of intuitive
sense.
The real rate calculation I have just completed
is for a balanced growth path in a world of no
uncertainty. It is only a benchmark since, of
course, actual economies must adapt to shocks
all the time. Unusual weather affecting agriculture,
the rise and fall of industries, changing government policies and, yes, wars all have important
impacts on the economy. Thus the economy is in
a constant state of adjustment, and probably only
rarely actually on a balanced growth path. The
pace of technological change itself, and the rate
of growth of the labor force, are not completely
smooth processes. The usefulness of the balanced
growth path concept is that when important disturbances occur, we have some idea about the
state to which we expect the economy to return.
I think it is clear that many observers of the
world’s industrialized countries have some type
of theory like this in mind when thinking about
interest rates and their relation to fundamental
factors in the economy. In particular, it is not surprising that the United States, with positive population growth and robust productivity growth,
has a higher real rate of interest than a country
such as Japan, which faces the prospect of a longterm decline in population and has lower productivity growth than in the United States. Nor
it is surprising that capital is flowing from Japan,
where returns and capital requirements are relatively low, to the United States where returns and
requirements are relatively high.
What are the implications for policymakers?
Clearly, we must keep a sharp eye on productivity improvements when thinking about the appropriate level of nominal interest rates, because the
real component of the nominal rate is driven by
productivity in an important way. Some of the
increases in productivity registered in the quarterly statistics recently have been quite extraordinary indeed. The prospects for continued
productivity improvement also appear to be good.
Eventually, but no one knows when, it seems
likely that market interest rates will rise to reflect
4

these fundamental real economic forces. We
ignore these fundamentals at our peril.

TREND BREAKS IN
PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH
Given the growth theory result, that the real
rate of interest will equal the rate of productivity
growth plus the rate of population growth, it is
clear that analysis of changes in productivity
growth is important for understanding changes
in real interest rates. But recent behavior of interest rates and productivity growth only deepens
the mystery. Productivity growth seems to have
been rising at the same time real interest rates
have been falling. Over the eight quarters ending
with the second quarter of this year, productivity
growth for the U.S. business sector has averaged
4.8 percent per year. The average over the last 12
quarters is 3.6 percent. The rate of productivity
growth averaged about 2½ percent per year in
the second half of the 1990s. On this calculation,
the long-term real rate of interest should have
increased by about 1 percentage point after 1999,
instead of falling by about 2 percentage points.
Before I try to address this apparent anomaly,
let’s go back in history a few decades. The period
from the late 1940s to the late 1960s was a golden
era for U.S. productivity growth. While actual
measurements are volatile, the average pace of
productivity improvement was clearly high during
this period—perhaps in the neighborhood of 3
percent per year. But sometime in the late 1960s
or early 1970s, productivity growth rates slowed
substantially, a widely studied but poorly understood event that became known as the productivity
slowdown. Productivity growth rates fell by half.
This decline in productivity growth had a dramatic impact on the U.S. economy, as it meant
that real income for the average household would
improve much less rapidly than earlier. With a
productivity growth rate of 3 percent, real household income doubles every 25 years; with productivity growth at 1.5 percent, real household
income doubles every 48 years.

Economic Growth and the Real Rate of Interest

The decline in productivity growth should
have had a direct impact on the risk-free real rate
of interest, causing it to fall in the 1970s by an
amount about equal to the decline in productivity
growth. But nominal interest rates rose during
the 1970s, because inflation increased. The
increases in inflation were too large and volatile
to allow us to see the decline in real interest rates
associated with the productivity slowdown.
Is it a coincidence that inflation rose as productivity growth slowed starting in the early
1970s? There are certainly reasons to believe that
part of the inflation run-up was in fact due to the
slowdown in productivity growth. Declining
productivity growth not only puts direct upward
pressure on goods prices but also, by slowing trend
output growth, makes it all too easy for policymakers to misread the state of the economy. Monetary policy was too expansionary in the 1970s,
in part because policymakers overestimated the
economy’s capacity to grow. Because productivity
is notoriously difficult to measure, and available
statistical measures are noisy, the realization that
productivity growth was slower on a sustained
basis, and not just as a short-run aberration, did
not occur for some years after the slowdown
began. In the meantime, expansionary monetary
policy built an inflation problem into the economy.
Failure to recognize the productivity growth slowdown is certainly not the whole story of monetary
policy mistakes in the 1970s, but probably part
of the story.
In any event, given the economic instability
created by inflation in the 1970s and disinflation
in the early 1980s, we certainly cannot characterize the U.S. economy during this period as growing along a balanced growth path. Real rates of
interest were lower in the 1970s and higher in
the 1980s, but these changes seem to have had
more to do with inflation-forecasting errors and
cyclical processes set up by inflation than with
changes in long-run productivity growth.
The 1990s brought a pleasant and unexpected
surprise: The trend rate of productivity growth
rose significantly. And, as I’ve emphasized already,
productivity growth has been even stronger
over the last three years. Unexpected, persistent

increases in productivity growth might have
effects on inflation and monetary policy opposite
to those created by the surprise shortfall in productivity growth in the 1970s.
During the early 1990s, U.S. inflation rates
were higher than they are today, and the economy
was in the midst of a recovery from the 1990-91
recession. At some point in the recovery process,
usually dated 1995, the trend productivity growth
rate increased. Again, because the data contain a
lot of noise and because measurement issues are
quite difficult, it was far from clear until several
years after the event that the trend pace of productivity improvement had increased to about
2½ percent. Real household income would double every 30 years at this pace of productivity
improvement.
During the last two years, nonfarm business
sector productivity growth has averaged about
4¾ percent at an annual rate. At this rate, real
household income would double, astonishingly,
every 16 years.
Two years is too short of a time to reach firm
conclusions about persistent changes in the trend
pace of productivity growth. And certainly, some
of the productivity gains seem to be connected
with an unwillingness of firms to hire additional
labor over the last two years while they wait for
economic conditions to improve. To the extent
this is true, productivity gains may be lower when
employment starts to grow at a sustained healthy
pace.
Still, the earlier lessons with trend productivity changes and the impact those changes have
on real interest rates and on the level of output
consistent with balanced growth suggest caution.
There is a distinct possibility that the underlying
pace of productivity growth has increased again.
If so, and if the FOMC does not make appropriate
policy adjustments, inflation could drift away
from current low levels. The short-run impact of
higher productivity growth might be to lower the
inflation rate, as rising output places downward
pressure on prices. However, over the longer run,
higher productivity growth will probably require
higher interest rates. If monetary policy adjustments do not keep up with a rising equilibrium
5

ECONOMIC GROWTH

real rate of interest, then the inflation rate may
ultimately rise. However, my best guess is that
the current stance of policy makes adequate
allowance, offsetting the risk that the current
low inflation will turn into a period of deflation,
and Fed vigilance over the longer run will, I
believe, keep inflation under control.

SHORT-TERM REAL INTEREST
RATES
I’ve concentrated on the real rate of interest
on longer-term bonds and on physical capital.
Nevertheless, it is hard to ignore the fact that at a
one-year maturity, the real rate of interest is about
zero today. That rate, I believe, should be viewed
as a transitory situation during the process of
economic adjustment reflecting fundamental
longer-term forces. Among these fundamental
forces, the rate of productivity growth is certainly
at the top of my list.
Policymakers do not have the luxury of calculating an interest rate theoretically consistent
with a balanced growth path, as I did earlier, and
then simply providing that interest rate to the
market. It is useful to understand the economics
behind the long-run balanced growth path, but
those considerations provide little practical guidance for short-run monetary policy. Because of
short- and medium-term shocks, the economy
can wander away from its steady-state growth
path and interest rates can depart from their longrun equilibrium values. The Fed would hinder
rather than support a return to the equilibrium
path were it to determine its interest rate stance
only on the basis of the long-run equilibrium.
Four years ago, real interest rates were high
because of the increase in productivity growth in
the mid 1990s, and also because excessive optimism—excessive in retrospect, anyway—led to

6

an unsustainable investment boom, which was
particularly marked in the telecom and dot-com
industries. Over the last several years, real rates
have been low as the investment slump has gradually worked off excess capital stock and as a series
of shocks—9/11 terrorist attacks, major bankruptcies, and corporate governance scandals—created
a pervasive air of caution. These are oscillations
around the economy’s long-run growth path.
Short-run adjustments in monetary policy have
been of enormous help in damping the oscillations, but it is beyond the FOMC’s power at the
current state of knowledge to eliminate the oscillations altogether.
As important as short-run policy adjustments
are, if the FOMC focuses only on transitory disturbances and fails to understand the longer-run
forces, it runs the risk of falling behind as the
economy converges toward its balanced-growth
path. That is part of the story behind policy mistakes in the 1970s. I do not know what the trend
rate of productivity growth will turn out to be,
but if is in the neighborhood of 3 percent, then a
reasonable guess on the equilibrium real rate of
interest is about 4 percent—3 percent from productivity growth plus 1 percent from population
growth. In the meantime, the Fed’s task is to promote as rapid a return to the long-run growth
path as is consistent with maintaining a rate of
inflation that is low and steady.
I’ve offered you my take on where the stance
of monetary policy is today and on how the appropriate policy stance is likely to evolve in the
future as events unfold. I’ve emphasized that
fundamental real forces affecting the real rate of
interest are likely to be critical to the long-run
path of interest rates, but that the timing of interest rate changes is highly uncertain. Now I’d be
pleased to take your questions.