View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Demographic Challenges to
State Pension Systems Around the World
Culver-Stockton College
Canton, Missouri
February 24, 2005

S

ocial Security has been in the news a
lot lately. For the first time since 1983,
when the Social Security Trust Fund
came within months of running out of
funds, the nation is engaged in a healthy debate
on the nature of the problem the Social Security
System faces, and on the choices that are available to address the problem. My purpose today
is not to enter into this historic debate over the
merits of available choices, but instead to discuss
the fundamental source of the problem and the
fact that the same issue is alive in most countries
around the world.
The fundamental source of the problem, as
most are now aware, is changing demographics.
In all high-income countries the population is
aging as a consequence of a birth rate much lower
than in earlier years and a longer life expectancy
as a consequence of advances in medicine. The
fraction of the population over age 65 is rising,
and if that age continues to mark the traditional
retirement age the number of dependent retired
persons relative to the number of working persons
will rise to levels never seen before.
Naturally, there is considerable aversion
toward making any substantive changes in Social
Security; most persons would like to retire at 65
or earlier. However, changing demographics make
it impossible both to maintain that traditional
retirement age, with the level of benefits defined
in current law, and to maintain the current level
of taxation on the working population to support
the retirement system. The option of raising taxes
on the working population is being actively discussed, but we should be clear about what is

involved. Many of us would find it unthinkable
to ask our own children to divert a growing share
of their own income to support our retirement;
the existence of the Social Security System does
not change the fact that children in general, rather
than children of individual families, will have to
bear a growing burden if retirement benefits are
unchanged.
Thus, changing demographics force us to
make some choices. We will have to either raise
the retirement age for the current level of annual
benefits, reduce the level of benefits in current
law, raise taxes on working persons, or adopt
some combination of the three options. Most
participants in the debate agree that the sooner
we address the issue the better because we should
make changes long enough in advance to give
people ample opportunity to adjust to changed
expectations.
The United States is not alone in facing a
funding problem in its government-run pension
system. Almost all economically advanced
countries have large, government-run pension
programs that replace a high percentage of the
lifetime earnings of retired persons. These programs use the tax payments of current workers
to fund the pension benefits of retired persons
and their dependents. The funding problem all
of these systems face has arisen because the number of persons drawing benefits is rising more
rapidly than the number of working persons paying taxes to fund those benefits. Demographers
project that these trends will continue over the
next several decades; thus, without reforms, the
funding problems of Social Security and the
1

ECONOMIC GROWTH

similar programs of other countries will only
worsen.
I will begin my talk today by reviewing some
of the underlying demographic facts that pose a
challenge for government-run pension systems
such as the U.S. Social Security system. These
data show that some other countries, notably Japan
and a few countries in Europe, are experiencing
a more rapidly aging population than the United
States. Next, I will discuss some of the reforms
already undertaken in other countries to confront
the funding problems of their government-run
pension systems, in the hope that the experiences
of other countries might inform the debate in our
own country.
Before proceeding, I want to emphasize that
the views I express here are mine and do not
necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal
Reserve System. I thank my colleagues at the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis—especially
Howard J. Wall and David C. Wheelock, both
assistant vice presidents in the research division—
for extensive assistance. However, I retain full
responsibility for errors.

DEMOGRAPHIC CHALLENGES
TO GOVERNMENT PENSION
SYSTEMS
Like the government-run pension systems of
most countries, Social Security is a “pay-as-yougo” system, meaning that benefits paid to current
recipients are financed by taxes levied on today’s
workers and their employers. In essence, Social
Security is an intergenerational transfer program
and not a retirement savings program in the traditional sense.
Some lament the pay-go nature of the Social
Security System, and argue that our current problem would never have arisen if the system had
been properly funded. Here it is important to
distinguish what an individual can do and what
a society can do. Let me use food as an example
to illustrate an extremely important point. Consider food consumed at some future time, such
as 2030. The food consumed in 2030 will be pro2

duced mostly in 2030, with some carried over
from 2029. The working population in 2030 must
produce the food and services to process and
distribute it to the entire population—to both the
working and the dependent population of young
persons and retired persons. It is impossible to
accumulate a food fund now to be used in the
future. Accumulation of financial assets does
not accumulate food assets. If a retired person
sells financial assets to pay for food, someone
must purchase those assets. Dependent persons
cannot purchase the assets—only working persons can. So, accumulating a retirement fund,
whether in the Social Security Trust fund or
private retirement accounts, does not solve the
problem for society as a whole raised by an aging
population.
The Social Security system was established
in the mid-1930s as one of several programs introduced to combat the Great Depression. In the
1940s, there were some 40 persons paying into
the system for every one person then drawing
Social Security benefits. In the 1950s, the ratio
was about 16 working persons paying taxes to
support every one person receiving benefits.
Today, however, there are just over three persons
financing the benefits of each recipient, and over
the next thirty years the ratio will fall to two persons paying taxes for each benefit recipient. These
projections take into account the scheduled
increase in the normal retirement age to 67 but
not other possible changes in labor force participation that could be induced by changes in work
incentives for those over age 67.
What explains the decline in the number of
persons currently paying into Social Security
relative to those drawing benefits? The answer
has two parts. First, over the past century, the
United States, like most if not all economically
advanced countries, has experienced an increase
in average life span. Second, these countries have
also experienced a decline in the birth rate, especially since 1960 or so. Consequently, the number
of persons who have reached the age at which
they are eligible for benefits has been rising faster
than the number of persons in the labor force
paying taxes. Demographers expect these trends

Demographic Challenges to State Pension Systems Around the World

in life span and birth rate to continue. Thus, without reforms to the system, the number of working
people paying Social Security taxes will continue
to fall relative to the number of people receiving
Social Security benefits. I should also note that
labor force participation of males aged 55 to 64
declined substantially from 89.5 percent in 1948
to 68.7 percent in 2004. Early retirement has
added to the problem.
The increase in life span reflects the wonders
of modern medicine and our rising standard of
living. The world’s fastest-growing age group is
comprised of those persons aged 80 and over. In
2000, 69 million persons, or 1.1 percent of world
population, were aged 80 or older. By 2050, the
number aged 80 or older is expected to more than
quintuple to 377 million and be 4.2 percent of
world population. In that year, 21 countries or
areas are projected to have at least 10 percent of
their population aged 80 or over. Japan is expected
to have 15.5 percent of its population over age
80—the highest of any country—and nearly 1
percent of its population aged 100 or more. The
United States is projected to have 7.2 percent of
its population consist of those 80 and older. In
1940, U.S. life expectancy at age 65 was an additional 13 years; today it is an additional 18 years.
Obviously, it is a great achievement that people are living longer and usually in better health
and financial comfort than their parents and
grandparents. The downside, however, is that
the benefit payments from existing governmentrun pension systems will in the near future exceed
the inflow of tax revenues to finance those payments unless steps are taken to reduce benefits,
raise the retirement age, and/or increases taxes
on current workers and their employers.
Those persons born in the first years of the
post-World War II baby boom are today nearing
our traditional retirement age of 65, and as this
demographic group passes from their working
years into retirement, the funding gap in Social
1

Security will open wide. Without reforms, the
trustees of the Social Security trust fund tell us
that Social Security outlays will begin to exceed
payroll tax revenues in 2018 and the Social
Security trust fund will be exhausted by 2042.1
It is important to understand just how large
has been the magnitude of the decline in the fertility rate, which determines the size of the working age population to support the baby boom
generation when it retires. In the 1950s, women
in the United States had, on average, 3.5 children
in their lifetime. By 2000, the fertility rate had
fallen to about 2.1, the minimum necessary for a
population to be self-sustaining. The United
Nations projects the U.S. fertility rate will continue to fall to about 1.85 by the middle of the
century. Most economically developed countries
already have fertility rates well below the replacement rate. Some representative examples are the
United Kingdom, 1.60, Germany, 1.35, Italy, 1.23
and Japan, 1.32. With such low fertility rates, the
populations of these countries are aging rapidly
and forcing reforms to public pension systems.

REFORMS AROUND THE WORLD
Now let us consider some steps that other
countries have already taken to shore up the
financing of their government-run pension systems. The systems of other countries vary greatly
in their details, but there is one characteristic
that, for our purposes, helps distinguish among
systems. That characteristic is the extent to which
the contributions a person makes to the system
during his or her working years are linked to the
benefits that person receives in retirement. In
some systems, there is little or no link between a
person’s contributions and retirement benefits.
In others, benefits are closely tied to contributions, often through the use of privately funded
retirement accounts. Our Social Security system
falls somewhere in the middle. We have a system

2004 Annual Report of the Social Security and Medicare Boards of Trustees. The U.S. Social Security program comprises two parts. The
Old-Age and Survivors Insurance (OASI) program pays retirement and survivor benefits, and the Disability Insurance (DI) program pays disability benefits. The years in which benefit payments exceed revenues and the Social Security trust fund will be exhausted refer to the combined OASDI programs.

3

ECONOMIC GROWTH

of notional accounts that relate to some extent a
retiree’s promised benefits to the amount he or
she paid into the system in the form of payroll
taxes. Nevertheless, all benefits are financed by
taxes imposed on current workers.
France and Germany are among the countries
where the relationship between the benefits people receive in retirement and the taxes they pay
during their working years is relatively weak.
Such countries have typically offered generous
benefits to those who take early retirement. Thanks
to both a tradition of generous benefits and unfavorable demographics, many of these countries
have already begun to experience serious problems
in the financing of public pensions. They have
tended to undertake reforms that strengthen the
link between contributions and benefits, and thus
make their systems more like the U.S. system.
At the other extreme are countries that impose
a tight relationship between a person’s payments
into the system and his or her ultimate benefits.
Several countries, including Sweden, Italy, the
United Kingdom and Chile, have strengthened
this link by shifting some of the financing of state
pensions onto private sources. In these systems,
early retirement places little, if any, burden on
the system, and these systems are relatively well
poised to handle the problem of an aging population. Still, several of these countries are considering further reforms of their systems.
For convenience, I will place the various
reforms that countries have undertaken into four
categories: tax increases, benefit reductions, measures to encourage later retirement, and expansions
of private funding for government pensions. The
first three categories are “parametric reforms.”
That is, these reforms alter some of the parameters
of the existing system, whereas the fourth category
includes changes to the structure of the system.

TAX INCREASES
For European countries, further tax increases
are, for the most part, a non-starter for addressing
2

4

the state-pension problem. To begin with, many
European countries already have high taxes—
much higher than in the United States. Furthermore, the populations of these countries are aging
rapidly, and the scope of the looming public
pension funding problem is such that only drastic
tax increases could hope to solve the problem. In
fact, as a recent OECD report concludes, large tax
increases could make matters worse by reducing
the incentives for market work and for saving.2
High taxes discourage economic activity, and
without strong economic growth, countries will
have trouble generating enough revenue to fund
promised benefits to retirees.

BENEFIT REDUCTIONS
In countries where the challenges presented
by demographic trends are more severe, and
more immediate, than in the United States, statepension reform has included benefit cuts.
Several countries have sought to reduce the
growth of benefits by modifying how benefits are
indexed. Many countries, including the United
States, automatically increase public pension
benefits annually to reflect increases in the
general level of wages. In the United States, the
initial benefit is indexed to wages and once benefits are paid they are indexed to the Consumer
Price Index. Indexing the initial benefit to wages
passes along the benefits of higher productivity
and wages to persons at the time of retirement.
This system maintains an initial benefit that is
roughly constant over time as a percentage of the
economy’s average wage level.
However, in a country with an aging population and a pay-as-you-go retirement system, wage
indexation implies that the average taxpayer is
called upon to devote an ever larger share of his
or her income to financing the benefit payments
of retired persons and their dependents. With
rising life expectancy and a lower fertility rate
than in earlier years, stabilizing the initial benefit
as a fraction of the economy’s wage level neces-

OECD. “Strengthening Growth and Public Finances in an Era of Demographic Change.” May 2004.

Demographic Challenges to State Pension Systems Around the World

sarily reduces the after-tax wage for employees,
because the tax rate to support the retirement
system must rise.
Because consumer prices tend to rise more
slowly than wages, several countries, including
Italy, Japan, Spain, and France have recently
switched from wage indexation to price indexation in an effort to slow the growth of benefit
payments while still protecting retirees from
inflation. By indexing to prices instead of wages,
the initial benefit will keep up with inflation but
gradually decline as a percentage of the economy’s
average wage level. This method of reducing the
initial benefit level is under active consideration
in the United States as well.
Another of the parametric reforms is to raise
the age at which a person is eligible for pension
benefits. This reform recognizes increased life
expectancy. Finland has already taken the step
of indexing its full-pension retirement age to life
expectancy. Other countries, including the United
States, have made small increases in their normal
retirement age, though usually less than the
increase in life expectancy. Still others have
increased the number of years that a person
must work in order to receive full benefits.
Several countries have taken steps to encourage people to remain in the labor force as they
get older. Some have done so by strengthening
the link between contributions and benefits.
Sweden, for example, has introduced “notional
accounts,” by which participants can see their
potential pension benefits rise as they work
longer and contribute more to the system. In this
sense, Sweden’s system has become more like
the U.S. Social Security system.
Other countries have taken steps to reduce
payments to persons who retire before the normal
retirement age. Many countries have traditionally
offered generous benefits to people who choose
to retire early. Although early retirees typically
receive a smaller annual pension than persons
who wait until they are older to retire, the differ-

ence in many countries has been insufficient to
discourage large numbers of people from retiring
early. The United States has long been something
of an exception. For a man with average income,
our Social Security System is roughly actuarially
neutral between ages 62 and 70. That is, the
annual benefit rises as retirement is delayed about
in accord with the decreased number of years
benefits will be received. Beyond age 70, however,
the incentive to remain in the U.S. labor force is
low, because benefits are not further increased if
retirement is further delayed. Of course, a person
can work and receive income while also receiving
Social Security benefits, but the person’s benefits may be taxed at a relatively high marginal
rate, depending on income, and the person must
also pay Social Security taxes as with any wage
earner. For these reasons, the implicit tax of
remaining in the labor force past age 70—the
foregone after-tax benefits—is relatively high.
Not coincidentally, the United States stands
out in terms of the extent to which older workers
participate in the labor force. In 2000, 68 percent
of American males aged between 55 and 64 were
in the labor force. The corresponding numbers
for France, Germany, Italy, and the Netherlands
were 42 percent, 56 percent, 45 percent and 46
percent, respectively. Britain, Sweden, and
Norway are similar to the United States in that
over 66 percent of persons aged 55 to 64 are in
the labor force.3
Consistent with these figures, a recent OECD
study found a close correlation between incentives to retire and retirement behavior—not surprisingly, people do respond to incentives! The
implication of this research, according to its
authors, is that labor force participation in the
55-64 age group could be increased substantially
by reforms that abolished policy-induced incentives to retire early. Indeed, the report goes on to
suggest that policymakers should consider skewing incentives against retirement, at least up to
some age, in recognition that people who work
provide a net positive impact on public budgets.4

3

OECD. “Policies for an Ageing Society: Recent Measures and Areas for Further Reform.” November 2003.

4

This research is summarized in “Strengthening Growth and Public Finances in an Era of Demographic Change.” OECD, May 2004.

5

ECONOMIC GROWTH

By continuing to work past normal retirement
age, people support themselves and pay taxes
that help to reduce the tax burden that would
otherwise fall on others.
Let me now turn to the issue of private
financing. As a prelude, allow me to quote from
a Presidential address to the U.S. Congress. The
address proposes a Social Security system that
ultimately is comprised of two components. One
component is to consist of “compulsory contributed annuities which in time will establish a
self-supporting system for those now young and
for future generations.” A self-supporting system is
one in which “funds for the payment of…benefits
[do] not come from the proceeds of general taxation.” Our current system does not satisfy this
principle completely because it cannot be selfsupporting for many years. But with adjustments, perhaps it might become so eventually.
The second component called for by the
President is to consist of “voluntary contributory
annuities by which individual initiative can
increase the annual amounts received in old age.”
In other words, the system should include voluntary personal accounts to go along with the mandatory notional accounts of the current system.
A particularly astute student of presidential
history might recognize that I am quoting from
an address of President Franklin Roosevelt,
who presented these proposals in an address to
Congress on February 17, 1935. President
Roosevelt’s notion of personal accounts was not
quite the same as those proposed by the current
Administration, but a key principle is the same:
Alongside notional accounts funded by Social
Security taxes on a pay-as-you-go basis, some of
the money to pay for a person’s retirement benefits through the Social Security system should
come from his or her voluntary purchase of
financial assets.
The advantage of moving toward increased
use of personal accounts in government pension
systems is that it would reduce the taxes imposed
on one generation to fund the benefits paid to an
older generation. Unlike our present system, a
portion of each generation’s retirement would be
funded by the earnings of their private accounts.
6

A move toward personal accounts would
strengthen the links between one’s contributions
and the benefits he or she receives, and thereby
lessen the burden of an aging population on the
funding of retirement benefits.
Opponents of the Administration’s proposal
for personal accounts have pointed out that those
who choose to use personal accounts will face
some financial-market risks. Depending on the
types of assets that can be held in these accounts,
however, these risks need not be particularly
high. On the other hand, personal accounts will
allow people to insulate themselves from the
risks inherent in a system that relies on taxing
one generation to fund the benefits of another
generation.
It was 70 years ago almost to this day that
President Roosevelt proposed personal retirement
accounts as a pillar of our Social Security. Only
recently, however, have countries begun to make
personal retirement accounts a part of their government run pension systems. Britain and Chile
have gone the farthest down this road, with
reforms dating back to the early 1980s. More
recently, Sweden and Italy have made personal
accounts a part of their public systems. As a
point of reference, if the Bush Administration’s
proposals are enacted and optional personal
accounts are created, our Social Security system
would resemble Sweden’s, except that in Sweden
personal accounts are mandatory.
The British pension system has seen ongoing
reform that began under the Conservative government of Margaret Thatcher in 1980 and has continued through the Labour government of Tony
Blair. As a result, the British pension system is
the most reliant on private finance of any highincome country. It is also among the most complicated, so I will try to simplify it as much as I can.
The mandatory first tier of the British system
includes a basic pension that is financed on a payas-you-go basis from taxes on current workers.
The level of benefit from the basic pension is fairly
low, however, and benefits are supplemented by
various means-tested payments including a
Minimum Income Guarantee and housing benefits.
The second tier of the British system is manda-

Demographic Challenges to State Pension Systems Around the World

tory for all those in paid employment who earn
above a certain level. Within this tier, individuals
can choose from among various approved private
pension plans, a heavily regulated “basic pension”
plan, and a second state pension. The third tier
of the British pension system allows people to
contribute to private pension plans from their
pre-tax income and includes various other tax
breaks for payments and capital gains from pension plans. Thus, the third tier of the British system is very similar to the system of tax advantages
afforded to those with private pension plans or
IRAs in the United States.
The relatively heavy use of private pension
plans within the state pension system means that
state pension spending in Britain accounted for
only 5.5 percent of GDP in 2000. Further, this
figure is expected to decline to 5 percent by 2040.
In contrast, across a list of European countries,
the average expenditure on state pensions was
over 10 percent in 2000 and is expected to rise to
nearly 14 percent by 2040.5 By comparison, in
the United States expenditure on Social Security
benefits was 4.3 percent of GDP in 2003.
The country that has moved farthest in converting its state pension scheme into a primarily
private one is Chile. Like the British system, the
Chilean system has three tiers. The primary difference between the two systems is that Chile’s first
tier provides a much lower minimum pension,
which makes the Chilean system even less reliant
on government funding. In fact, the Chilean government’s expenditure on first tier pensions is
expected to remain below 0.5 percent of GDP for
the foreseeable future.6 The conversion into the
new system has been very costly, however,
because the government decided to continue
funding the pension promises made to those
who were working before the new system was in

place. Even so, by the late 1990s, total spending
on state pensions had fallen to below 4 percent
of GDP.7
Individuals have enjoyed average annual
returns of more than 10 percent per year on their
private retirement savings accounts under the
Chilean system, thanks to the rapid growth of
Chile’s economy during the 1980s and 1990s.
The perceived success of the Chilean reforms
has led many other countries to undertake similar
reforms to their own state pension systems. As
of last year, 11 Latin American countries had
adopted some version of the Chilean model.8

CONCLUSION
The debate over the future of Social Security
has just begun. There are no easy solutions to the
problem of how to ensure that our public pension
system remains sound in the face of inevitable
demographic changes. Compared to many countries, however, we in the United States are lucky.
We have a strong economy supporting a high standard of living, a high rate of labor force participation, and our Social Security system imposes
relatively little distortion on the retirement decisions of persons younger than age 70. Moreover,
compared to other developed countries, the
changes in the age distribution of our population
have been and will continue to be relatively
modest.
Still, we must make some changes in our
Social Security system to ensure its long-run
solvency, and those changes will involve some
hard choices. Understanding the nature of the
available choices, why choices must be made
and lessons from experience abroad should help
the nation address these important issues in a
sound and long-lasting way.

5

Disney, Richard. “Public Pension Reform in Europe: Policies, Prospects and Evaluation.” World Economy, 2003, 26, pp. 1425-45.

6

Acuña, Rodrigo R. and Iglesias, Augusto P. “Chile’s Pension Reform After 20 Years.” World Bank Social Protection Discussion Paper No. 0129,
December 2001.

7

Acuña, Rodrigo R. and Iglesias, Augusto P. “Chile’s Pension Reform After 20 Years.” World Bank Social Protection Discussion Paper No. 0129,
December 2001.

8

Corbo, Vittorio. “Policy Challenges of Population Aging and Pension Systems in Latin America.” Presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of
Kansas City Symposium Global Demographic Change: Economic Impacts and Policy Challenges, Jackson Hole, Wyoming, August 26-28, 2004.

7