View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

The Critical Role of Economic Education
in the Conduct of Monetary Policy
Hawaii Council on Economic Education Annual Meeting
Honolulu, Hawaii
April 25, 2000

I

am delighted to be here today to speak
before the Hawaii Council on Economic
Education. I have spent most of my life
in higher education and now, as a policy
official in the Federal Reserve System, I am still
intimately involved in education issues. My
audiences may be different, but the issues are
the same. I must say, however, that it is considerably easier to speak to you today than to freshmen
at nine in the morning.
I will proceed by discussing, first, why everyone needs to understand the basics of monetary
policy. Lots of people, especially young people,
seem to believe that those pesky supply and
demand diagrams are too difficult and uninteresting to be worth spending much time on. Most
people, though, eventually find that they cannot
escape knowing something about mortgage interest
rates and other mundane matters that turn out to
be so terribly important for their economic welfare.
Speaking in the abstract about the importance
of understanding monetary policy takes us only
so far, however. To get to the real meat of the argument requires that we entangle ourselves in a live
issue or two, and spend enough time on the issue
to understand why everyone ought to know something about it. For this reason, I’ll tackle three
issues that strike me as particularly relevant in
today’s economy. The first issue is that the Federal
Reserve really has only one policy instrument,
or policy lever. If there is only one instrument,
then there can be, or should be, only one policy
goal. I’ll explain why both of these statements—
that the Fed has only one policy instrument and
that one instrument requires only one goal—are

true. My second subject will be that we must keep
our focus on the long run. John Maynard Keynes
is often quoted to the effect that in the long run
we are all dead, but that is a terribly misleading
thing to say. If we do not look at the long-run
consequences of policy actions, we are bound to
get ourselves into a lot of trouble.
Thirdly, I’ll emphasize that price stability, or
low and stable inflation, is a far more important
goal than many may think. When the price level is
stable for an extended period, people tend to take
price stability for granted and fail to understand
that many other good features of the economy
depend critically on its continued maintenance.
By the same token, when the economy suffers
from price instability, many things go wrong that
should be, but often are not appreciated to be,
linked to the loss of price stability.
Before proceeding, I want to emphasize that
the views I express here are mine and do not
necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal
Reserve System. I thank my colleagues at the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis for their comments, but I retain full credit for errors.

SOME BACKGROUND ON FED
POLICY PROCEDURES
Before digging into the substance of policy, I
need to be sure we’re on the same wave length in
our understanding of Fed policy procedures.
The key interest rate for Fed policy is the federal
funds rate. The funds rate, to use market lingo, is
simply the interest rate banks charge each other on
loans of the funds they hold in reserve accounts
1

ECONOMIC EDUCATION

at Federal Reserve Banks. Commercial banks and
other depository institutions maintain these
reserves on deposit at the Fed in order to meet
their required reserves and to make payments as
checks clear the banking system. Depository institutions—or “banks” as I will call them from now
on—sometimes have surplus funds that they lend
out to other banks that have a deficiency of funds.
These loans are typically for one day at a time, or
“overnight” in market parlance. The Federal Open
Market Committee (FOMC) conducts monetary
policy by determining an intended, or target,
interest rate for federal funds. At the end of each
of its meetings, the FOMC directs the Fed’s Operating Desk at the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York to maintain the federal funds rate near its
intended level. The Desk achieves this objective
by placing additional funds in the market when
the funds rate threatens to exceed the intended
rate, or withdrawing funds from the market when
the rate is falling short of the intended level.
Market participants spend a lot of time forming expectations about the likely course of the
federal funds rate in the future. The rate on a 1week Treasury bill, for example, reflects the market’s best guess as to the average for the federal
funds rate over the next seven days. The interest
rate on a 1-month obligation reflects expectations
about the 1-week rate for the next 4 weeks, and
the 1-year rate reflects expectations over the next
52 weeks. Continuing this line of argument, the
30-year bond rate reflects expectations about the
next 30 one-year rates.
This picture, of course, is complicated by
interest differentials of various kinds, but for our
purposes the big picture is what we need. Let’s
focus on two key elements: First, the FOMC sets
the overnight rate, which quite naturally has a
significant influence over short-term rates. Second,
longer-term rates depend on the markets’ understanding the direction of monetary policy and all
of the economic forces that interact to yield that
long-run direction. Thus, a very important responsibility for the FOMC is to communicate as clearly
as possible the longer-run direction of monetary
policy and the considerations that underlie policy
decisions.
2

WHY EVERYONE NEEDS TO
UNDERSTAND MONETARY
POLICY BASICS
Business enterprises often borrow large
amounts of funds, and so the probable direction
of interest rates and the monetary policy considerations behind future interest rates are of direct
and immediate interest to every corporation.
Every firm must also be concerned about future
wage and price developments, which means that
an understanding of the Fed’s objective of price
stability and its success in achieving that objective
is important for business managers.
Each of us as a member of a consuming household also needs to understand the basics of monetary policy. From time to time, almost every
household is faced with a decision about purchasing a house and must understand the basics of
mortgage finance. These basics today require some
knowledge of the relative advantages and disadvantages of fixed-rate and adjustable-rate mortgages.
To understand the consequences of choosing one
of these alternatives over the other, households
need to know something about the basics of monetary policy and the likely success of the Federal
Reserve in keeping inflation low on a sustained
basis. In addition, households need to understand
why the Fed is doing what it is doing so that
family financial decisions will not be made on
the basis of misinformation about monetary policy.
Finally, just as businesses need to know something about prices, because businesses buy and
sell goods, and about wages, because businesses
hire labor, so also households must know something about these same issues. Households, after
all, are on the opposite side of these economic
transactions from businesses. Households pay
the prices that businesses charge and receive the
wages that businesses pay.

THREE ILLUSTRATIVE ISSUES
THAT REALLY MATTER
The importance of understanding monetary
policy basics really comes alive when we con-

The Critical Role of Economic Education in the Conduct of Monetary Policy

sider some examples. I’ve selected three specific
examples that are simple and easy to explain and
yet extremely important.

One Policy Instrument Means One
Policy Goal
I’ll start this topic by making a statement that
sounds technical and complicated, but really isn’t:
In engineering control theory, we know that to
achieve N goals requires at least N instruments.
For example, if we have three goals like controlling an airplane’s speed, altitude and direction,
the plane must have at least three control instruments. The throttle instrument controls speed,
the rudder in combination with some other surfaces controls direction, and the elevators on the
horizontal stabilizer control the plane’s altitude
by directing it up or down.
Consider another simple example. With two
objectives, such as controlling a car’s speed and
direction, the driver needs two control instruments—a steering wheel and an accelerator.
What is the relevance of all this for monetary
policy? The Federal Reserve has only one main
policy instrument at its disposal. That instrument
is the rate of creation of money, or more generally,
liquidity. The Fed exercises control over money
creation on a day-by-day basis by adjusting the
intended federal funds rate. With only one policy
instrument, the Fed can pursue successfully only
one policy goal. That goal is low and stable inflation, or price stability, depending on the exact
phrase used.
This simple fact that the Fed has one policy
instrument and must, therefore, decide which
single goal it will pursue is of tremendous consequence. People often insist that the Fed ought to
pursue other objectives, such as reducing the
unemployment rate, stabilizing the foreign
exchange rate, or nudging the stock market up or
down. The Federal Reserve cannot in fact pursue
multiple objectives and hope to achieve them all.
Given that the main consequence of excessive or
deficient liquidity creation is inflation or deflation,
either of which creates a whole host of other
problems, the Federal Reserve must not allow its

primary mission of achieving price stability to
be deflected by attempting to pursue other goals.
The issue I want to emphasize is not that
other goals are unimportant. All of us want the
unemployment rate to settle at as low a level as
possible, and we want the stock market to be
priced correctly, and we want the foreign exchange
rate to settle at an appropriate level. But the Fed
simply does not have policy instruments to achieve
all of these goals and must instead concentrate
on the goal that is its direct responsibility. To
repeat, that goal is maintaining low and stable
inflation.
Now this basic view can and should be modified just a bit. It is possible for the Fed from time
to time to adjust monetary policy to counter problems in achieving other goals, but only to the
extent that such policy adjustments do not damage
the long-run cause of low and stable inflation. For
example, in the fall of 1998, the FOMC reduced
the intended federal funds rate to respond to
financial disturbances that arose following the
Russian bond default. Easing monetary policy
temporarily did assist the economy in working
through these financial disturbances, without a
long-run consequence for the goal of low and
stable inflation. By responding to the disturbance,
the Fed was able to keep those problems from
having an impact on employment and economic
activity. The principle involved here is well understood in control theory. The application of a particular instrument may have simultaneous effects
on several goals. For example, applying more
power to an airplane will increase its rate of climb.
But the point is that to fully achieve goals for both
altitude and speed, the aircraft must have more
than a throttle.
I invite you to keep your eyes and ears open
for examples of people urging the Fed to pursue
multiple objectives. I suspect that you will find
many such examples and that a little thought will
indicate just how uninformed these policy proposals are. It is important for the Fed to maintain
its focus on what it can reasonably accomplish,
and not to permit other issues to deflect it from
its principal responsibility.
3

ECONOMIC EDUCATION

It’s the Long Run That Matters
One of my favorite formats for a student term
paper was to ask the student to review a particular
economic episode by going back to news magazines and newspapers. Asking a student to read
the newspapers for a few weeks on either side of
the stock market crashes of 1929 and 1987, or over
a few months during the recession of 1982, or a
few months as inflation rose sharply starting in
the fall of 1973, is an excellent way to get the
student to develop a sense of these events.
Economic historians writing about such
episodes distill the detailed record into the key
events and policy decisions. The job of the historian, of course, is to put events into a longer-run
perspective by examining the key milestones,
policy decisions, and causal mechanisms. But at
any given time, people get caught up in the events
of the day and find it difficult to put these events
into the appropriate perspective.
As I reflect on how events unfold, I am always
struck by the enormous amount of attention paid
to information that will, to the historian, be at
most random noise. Perhaps you have had the
strange sensation, as I have had more times than
I like to admit, of picking up a newspaper and
after reading for a few minutes developing a
strange sense that you must have read this paper
before. I look at the date, and discover that I’ve
picked up a newspaper several weeks old. I’ve
already read the paper and have discarded from
memory almost every single bit of information in
it. Yet, all too many policy positions are driven
by the trivial information that happens to hit the
headlines.
The long run is, of course, the sum of a series
of short runs. One year is the sum of 12 months,
and one decade the sum of 10 years. Our economic
well-being depends mostly on averages over a
decade, and only to a relatively small extent on
fluctuations around those averages. Policymakers
usually prefer to minimize fluctuations around
the long-run trends, but the government’s power
to do so is often very limited. Thus, a key objective
for policy is to prevent short-run fluctuations
from affecting policy in such a way as to drive
the economy off the desired long-run track.
4

Policymakers often find themselves confronted
by a public clamor to do something in response
to a short-run problem. On occasion, a short-run
policy response can be constructive, as was the
case in the Russian bond default in 1998. But
more often the appropriate advice is, “Don’t just
do something, stand there!”
One argument for keeping policy on a steady,
even course is that policy actions in response to
short-run disturbances are seldom successful. But
the argument is really deeper than that. Productivity growth and job creation in a market economy
are driven by thousands upon thousands of decisions in the private sector. An important responsibility of government, including the Federal
Reserve’s responsibility for monetary policy, is
to set a stable and predictable course within which
private decisions can be made efficiently. On the
whole, households and firms, interacting through
markets, do make efficient decisions about prices
and quantities of goods and services. Excessive
government activism can interfere with the efficiency of those decisions.
If you have any doubts about the overriding
importance of the long run, try to think back to
the detailed events of a year or two ago. If you
start reading newspapers several years old, you
will find your memory refreshed but you will be
impressed by how trivial in the light of subsequent
developments most of those day-to-day events
were.

Price Stability Is More Important Than
You May Think
The ultimate goal of Federal Reserve policy
is to promote maximum sustainable economic
growth. We emphasize the importance of price
stability because that is the single most important
contribution that monetary policy can make
toward achieving the deeper objective of maximum sustainable economic growth. The Federal
Reserve also contributes to society’s growth goals
by supervising and regulating banks to maintain
a sound banking system and by providing efficient
payment services such as check processing and
electronic payment mechanisms.

The Critical Role of Economic Education in the Conduct of Monetary Policy

With regard to monetary policy, too few people
seem to understand how greatly price stability
contributes to the economy’s general welfare.
Price stability will not by itself guarantee success,
for there are many other cooperating conditions
necessary. But price instability without question
can guarantee significant problems in any economy. The public often attributes these problems
to non-monetary conditions when they in fact
stem from monetary instability.
The U.S. economy today, and for the past
several years, has been enjoying extraordinarily
low unemployment and rapid job growth. I believe
that stable monetary conditions yielding a low
and stable rate of inflation and solid expectations
of continuing stability have played a substantial
role in the economy’s success in the labor markets.
U.S. inflation in the 1970s certainly contributed
substantially to the employment volatility of that
period. The recessions of 1973-75 and 1981-82
were the most serious downturns since the Great
Depression, and these downturns arose on the
backs of accelerating inflation and expectational
errors caused by unanticipated changes in monetary policy. Today, despite an economic expansion
of record length, we see no signs that the expansion is closing in on old age. If inflation gets away
from the Fed to any significant degree in the years
ahead—and I am pushing with every bone in my
body to do what I can to make sure that circumstance does not face us—then the dangers of
recession will surely rise.
Monetary instability and inflation damage
stability not only in the labor market but also on
a host of other fronts. Some of you may recall the
difficulty people had in buying homes when mortgage rates averaged more than 15 percent in 1982.
During much of the decade of the 1970s, falling
stock and bond prices damaged income security
for older Americans. Public concern over inflation
led to the unwise political response of wage and
price controls in 1971, and those controls created
a vast array of other problems.
I could extend this list to great length, but will
not do so. My point is that many features of the
1970s were related to the inflationary environment, and many favorable features of today’s

economy are related to the price stability the
economy has enjoyed in recent years. Price stability is an abstract goal and is not much worth
pursuing for its own sake. But so many aspects
of our economic welfare are directly and indirectly
connected to price stability that it is important
not to underestimate the importance of achieving
that goal.
I said a moment ago that I was not going to
extend the list of ills from price instability, and
the virtues of price stability, but I will break that
promise just briefly to comment on the economics
of the education sector. Our current prosperity
has generated large amounts of tax revenue at all
levels of government. These resources are available for a great variety of public responsibilities,
including education. With university budgets
growing, I know that the university demand for
economists is high; that demand makes it difficult
for us to hire the young economists we need for
our staff at the St. Louis Fed. In contrast, during
the 1970s, many state budgets were under substantial pressure because rising prices were outrunning the available tax revenues. Some of you
may recall the periods of stringency during those
years.
Moreover, the relative stability of wages and
prices has made the job of educational budget
planning a lot easier. All of us may have to scramble to find the talent we need, but we do our
scrambling within an environment in which we
can reasonably plan our budget outlays. The end
result is greater efficiency in matching talent and
resources. Clearly, also, with the job market so
strong, there are ample employment opportunities
for our students as they finish their degrees.

CONCLUDING OBSERVATIONS
By now, I’m sure you have a good idea of the
thrust of my thinking. I will, however, point out
that I have discussed these and other monetary
policy issues that really matter at greater length
in a number of speeches over the last two years
that I have been at the St. Louis Fed, and I’ll put
in a plug for our web site that contains those
speeches.
5

ECONOMIC EDUCATION

Finally, then, let me circle back to my main
theme about the importance of public understanding of these monetary policy issues for the job of
the Federal Reserve System. Some people may
take the view that the public should simply put
good people in office and then allow these experts
to do the job right without further public interference. If that view were correct, then there would
be no need for the public to understand much
about what we do.
I reject this view for two reasons. First, my
observation of American politics tells me that, in
a vigorous democracy, people will not sit back
and let the experts do their own thing. In fact, I
think the voters are right to pay attention to what
we do, for experts in power do not always make
the proper decisions. Wherever you come out on
this issue, the fact is that voters do not ignore what
we do, and therefore it is in the interest of the
nation that voters understand what good policy
is all about. Otherwise, they and their representatives may demand the Federal Reserve to move in
directions that will not turn out to be constructive.
There is another reason for the Federal Reserve
to be concerned about public understanding of
monetary policy issues. In my brief description
of monetary policy at the beginning of this speech,
I pointed out that the Fed directly sets an intended
rate for the overnight federal funds rate while the
market sets longer-term interest rates on the basis
of expectations about the future. How can the
market set the 10-year bond rate or the 20-year
mortgage rate without knowing something about
monetary policy? The interaction of borrowers
and lenders in the marketplace determines those
longer-term rates. Mortgage borrowers, for example, need to make judgments about whether the
current rate is likely to reflect a good buy or
whether the mortgage rate might be lower in the
coming months. Similarly, lenders need to decide
when to lend and when to hang on to funds in the

6

expectation that the interest rate received will be
higher in the future. To make these decisions intelligently, borrowers and lenders need to understand the basics of monetary policy. Otherwise,
they will make mistaken decisions that will ultimately damage the economy’s long-run growth.
Thus, in pursuing the goal of maximum sustainable economic growth, the Fed must be concerned
with much more than setting the intended federal
funds rate at the next FOMC meeting. We need
to do the best job we can in conveying to the
market the reasoning and outlook for monetary
policy and the economy more generally. We cannot, of course, forecast the unforecastable, but
we can make clear our conviction that maintaining
low and stable inflation is our primary responsibility. We can also provide a sense of how we go
about responding to and analyzing the flow of
incoming information.
Looking at this argument from a business
perspective, we know that efficient business
management requires firms to make correct decisions in hiring labor, building plant and equipment, designing and pricing goods and services,
and so forth. These decisions include efficient
financial decisions. And those decisions in turn
require some knowledge of monetary policy issues.
I’m sure that most of you in this audience are
convinced of the importance of economic education. We need to convince those who teach
English, foreign languages, history, and other
non-economics subjects that at least a taste of
economics is good for every student. Everyone
needs to understand the basics to make sound
decisions in household financial management.
Understanding the basics of monetary policy
will pay dividends, both for individuals as citizens and for them as members of households
and in their capacity as productive employees
of businesses.