View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Chinese Growth:
A Source of U.S. Export Opportunities
Fiscal Affairs and Government Operations Committee
Council of State Governments’ Southern Legislative Conference (SLC)
Louisville, Kentucky
July 31, 2006
Published in the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, November/December 2006, 88(6), pp. 471-83

W

ith all the press reports about the
enormous growth of China’s
exports to the United States, I start
with a story running in the opposite direction. Kanawha Scales and Systems is a
company located in Poca, West Virginia, which
has a population of roughly 1,000. Chinese purchases of this company’s coal-loading machines
have grown to account for about one-third of
the company’s $50 million in annual revenues.1
How many stories are there like the Kanawha
Scales story? Well, I’ll share another example. A
recent report indicates that a group from Kentucky
will be involved in the construction of a Thoroughbred racetrack in China, the first in mainland
China.2 As part of this deal, 1,500 Kentucky
Thoroughbreds will be sold and shipped to China
and it is also possible that a number of Chinese
will come to Kentucky to learn how to be trainers,
exercise riders, jockeys, grooms, and hot walkers.
Are these isolated examples? Just how important to the United States are sales of U.S. goods
and services to China?
My purpose this morning is to convince you
that the answer to this question is clear. Sales of
U.S. goods and services to China are large, are
growing, and are very important to the United
States. In fact, as I’ll detail shortly, firms in the

16 member states of the Southern Legislative
Conference (SLC) are engaged in substantial
exporting activity to China. I’ll discuss major
features of the economic relationship between
the United States and China, but with special
emphasis on U.S. exports to China because that
critically important part of the relationship is not
well understood.
Before proceeding, I want to emphasize that
the views I express here are mine and do not
necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal
Reserve System. I thank my colleagues at the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis for their comments, particularly Cletus C. Coughlin, vice
president and deputy director of Research, who
provided special assistance.

TRADE PROSPECTS
Increases in international trade depend on
three key factors—income growth, reductions in
trade barriers, and declines in transportation costs.
Income growth has been the most important of
these three factors stimulating increased trade
worldwide, with reductions in trade barriers a
distant second and declines in transportation
costs an even more distant third.3 The direct impli-

1

See www.usatoday.com/money/world/2006-04-19-china-exports-usat_x.htm.

2

See http://charlotte.bizjournals.com/charlotte/stories/2006/03/20/ story6.html.

3

See Baier and Bergstrand (2001). Trade barriers and transportation costs are key components of trade costs, which are discussed in detail by
Anderson and van Wincoop (2004).

1

INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FINANCE

cation of this research finding is that any discussion of trade flows should begin by examining
income growth. In fact, almost without exception
over the past 55 years, growth in world merchandise exports has exceeded growth in gross domestic product (GDP).4 (See Figure 1.)
It is reasonable, therefore, to anticipate a
strong relationship between Chinese growth and
U.S. exports, and that’s exactly what we observe.
The transformation of the Chinese economy has
been accompanied by a huge increase in international trade and capital flows. U.S. exports to
China have also been spurred by reductions in
Chinese trade barriers, especially as part of China’s
entry into the World Trade Organization in 2001.
In addition to a substantial decline since 1982
in import tariffs, in 2005 China eliminated the
licenses that were required for the importation
of many goods.5

CHINESE AND U.S. GROWTH
China, with a population in excess of one
billion, has maintained an astonishing rate of
economic growth over the past 28 years. Beginning
in 1978, China embarked on a series of policy
changes that have led to an economy increasingly
reliant on markets and price signals for allocating
productive resources.6
As of July 2006, the Chinese population was
1.3 billion, which is more than four times as large
as the U.S. population of 298 million. In terms of
total production, measured in dollars at purchasing power parity, the Chinese economy is the
world’s second-largest economy, trailing only the
United States. In 2005 the Chinese GDP exceeded

$8 trillion, which was roughly two-thirds the U.S.
GDP. (See Figure 2.) Not surprisingly, these two
countries were two of the three leading exporting and importing countries in the world.7 (See
Figure 3.)
The most vivid illustration of rapid Chinese
growth can be seen by examining the Chinese
economy on a per capita basis. Adjusted for inflation, China’s per capita GDP in 2004 was 6.6 times
its 1980 level. (See Figure 4.) Annual growth rates
of real per capita GDP in excess of 5 percent have
been the norm in recent years. (See Figure 5.) In
the late 1970s, China’s real GDP per capita was
slightly less than 5 percent of the U.S. level. Today
it exceeds 10 percent. (See Figure 6.) Thus,
although the overall Chinese economy is large,
China is still a country with a relatively low level
of per capita income. To provide perspective,
China’s real per capita GDP today is about equal
to U.S. per capita GDP in 1886.

THEORY OF INTEGRATING A
LARGE LABOR-ABUNDANT
COUNTRY INTO THE WORLD
ECONOMY
Some basic economic theory will provide a
foundation for viewing the integration of the
Chinese economy into the world economy. The
analysis applies not only to the integration of
the Chinese economy but also to similar developments that are occurring simultaneously in India
and the countries of the former Soviet Union.8
Economists view the integration of these
economies into the global economy as a labor
“shock.” Their integration can be viewed as a

4

Using annual data from the World Trade Organization’s International Trade Statistics 2005, world merchandise export growth exceeded
world GDP growth in all but eight years between 1950 and 2004.

5

See “Building Explosion in China Pumps Up Exports from USA,” a web article at www.usatoday.com/money/world/
2006-04-19-china-exports-usat_x.htm in USA Today.

6

Prasad and Rajan (2006) estimate that between one-half and two-thirds of the Chinese economy is currently market-based.

7

For 2004, the leading countries in terms of total world exports were Germany with a 10.0 percent share, the United States with an 8.9 percent
share, and China with a 6.5 percent share. In terms of imports, the leading countries were the United States with a 16.1 percent share,
Germany with a 7.6 percent share, and China with a 5.9 percent share.

8

This idea has been expressed by Wolf (2006).

2

Chinese Growth: A Source of U.S. Export Opportunities

Figure 1
World Merchandise Export Growth and GDP Growth, 1950-2004
Growth (% year/year)
16
12
9.0
2004

Export Growth
8
4

3.7
2004

GDP Growth
0

–0.6
1981

–4

–2.8
1958

–7.3
1975

54

57
19
60
19
63
19
66
19
69
19
72
19
75
19
78
19
81
19
84
19
87
19
90
19
93
19
96
19
99
20
02

19

19

51

–8

19

–0.6
2001

–2.2
1988

SOURCE: World Trade Organization, International Trade Statistics 2005.

Figure 2
China: The World’s Second-Largest Single Economy in Terms of Purchasing Power Parity
$12.37

U.S.
E.U.
China

$8.16

Japan
India
Germany
U.K.
France
Italy
Brazil
Russia
0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

$ Trillions in 2005

SOURCE: CIA World Factbook.

3

INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FINANCE

Figure 3
Leading Exporters and Importers in World Merchandise Trade, 2004

Rank

Exporters

Value
($ billions)

Share
(%)

Rank

Importers

Value
($ billions)

Share
(%)

1,525.5

16.1

716.9

7.6

1

Germany

912.3

10.0

1

United States

2

United States

818.8

8.9

2

Germany

3

China

593.3

6.5

3

China

561.2

5.9

4

Japan

565.8

6.2

4

France

465.5

4.9

5

France

448.7

4.9

5

United Kingdom

463.5

4.9

6

Netherlands

358.2

3.9

6

Japan

454.5

4.8

7

Italy

349.2

3.8

7

Italy

351.0

3.7

8

United Kingdom

346.9

3.8

8

Netherlands

319.0

3.4

9

Canada

316.5

3.5

9

Belgium

285.5

3.0

10

Belgium

306.5

3.3

10

Canada

279.8

2.9

SOURCE: World Trade Organization.

Figure 4
China’s GDP per Capita
RMB
12,000
10,000
8,000
6,000
4,000
2,000

0
20
0

5
19
9

0
19
9

5
19
8

0
19
8

5
19
7

0
19
7

5
19
6

19
6

0

0

SOURCE: National Bureau of Statistics, China Statistical Yearbook 2004; National Bureau of Statistics Plan Report.

4

Chinese Growth: A Source of U.S. Export Opportunities

Figure 5
Chinese and U.S. Growth Rates of Real GDP per Capita
Percent
15

10
China
5
U.S.
0

–5

0

19
9

20
0

5

0
19
9

5
19
8

0
19
8

5
19
7

0
19
7

5
19
6

0
19
6

5
19
5

19
5

0

–10

SOURCE: Penn World Tables (constant prices: chain series).

Figure 6
China’s Real GDP per Capita Relative to the U.S.
Percent
15

10

5

0
20
0

19
9

5

0
19
9

5
19
8

0
19
8

5
19
7

0
19
7

5
19
6

0
19
6

5
19
5

19
5

0

0

SOURCE: Penn World Tables (U.S. = 100 in current prices).

5

INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FINANCE

very large increase in the world’s effective labor
supply. To facilitate my discussion, assume that
the bulk of this increase in the labor supply in
recent years has tended to be low-skilled. Employing this simplifying assumption, two consequences
are a direct result of the increased supply of lowskilled labor. One is that wages of low-skilled
labor in high-income countries will tend to fall,
or to increase more slowly, than before China’s
entry into the world trading system. Second, prices
of those goods that require relatively large amounts
of low-skilled labor should tend to decline relative
to the prices of those goods that require relatively
large amounts of high-skilled labor. For convenience of exposition, I’ll refer to goods produced
with low-skilled labor as “low-tech” goods and
goods produced with high-skilled labor as “hightech” goods. Obviously, there is a continuum of
goods from low to high tech, but the simplification
will make it easy to understand the basic economic
forces at work.
The first effect tends to depress income gains
of low-skilled labor in high-income countries.
Obviously, the share in total population of highskilled workers is greater in high-income countries
than in low-income countries. Because of the large
increase in low-skilled workers worldwide, lowskilled workers in the United States are likely to
experience downward pressure on their real wages
due to the increased competition associated with
Chinese exports.9 The adverse income change
generates demands for a government response to
ameliorate the adverse market change.
The problem is real: Low-skilled workers in
the United States have been adversely affected by
imports of goods produced by low-skilled workers
abroad. However, the nature of the government
response is very important. Trade restrictions that
hinder the importation of goods from China are

unlikely to be a good solution because the United
States would simply be forgoing the benefits of
Chinese imports. Indeed, those lower-priced goods
are important to lower-income, working families
in the United States. The only appealing solution
for the United States as a whole is to adopt policies that will increase the skill levels of affected
workers, so that they can increase their compensation and employment prospects, which will
allow them to adjust to the evolving economic
environment.
Now consider the effect tending to reduce
the prices of goods made with low-skilled labor.
This relative price change, in which low-tech
goods decline in price relative to high-tech goods,
is associated with two other important price
changes. The first involves a country’s terms of
trade, which is the (average) price of a country’s
exports relative to the (average) price of its imports.
In the case of China, the prices of the goods that
China ships to the rest of the world should tend
to decline relative to the prices of goods that it
buys from the rest of the world.
Generally speaking, as the price of Chinese
exports declines relative to the price of its imports,
countries purchasing Chinese goods should
become better off. In theory, the more dissimilar
another country’s production and consumption
is to China’s, the more likely the country is to benefit by China’s integration into the world economy.
Thus, a country such as the United States should
tend to benefit from China’s integration. Of course,
the magnitude of the gains for the United States
depends on the impact of Chinese exports on U.S.
import prices. Recent research by staff economists
at the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System found that Chinese exports have caused
declines, albeit small, in U.S. import prices.10,11
The public-policy challenge is considerable, how-

9

In fact, declining real compensation for low-skilled workers has been an issue for many years in the United States.

10

See Kamin, Marazzi, and Schindler (2006).

11

Rodrik (2006) argues that China’s export bundle is more sophisticated than other countries with similar per capita incomes. While laborintensive exports, such as toys, clothing, and electronics products that entail simple assembly operations, are important in China’s export
basket, Rodrik argues that foreign investment has played a major role in the evolution of Chinese exports. Foreign investors dominate
Chinese exports. Their contribution of advanced technology, and the resulting transfer of technology, has resulted in Chinese exports that are
relatively more sophisticated than those of comparably developed countries.

6

Chinese Growth: A Source of U.S. Export Opportunities

ever, because gains for the United States as a whole
are accompanied by downward pressure on wages
of U.S. low-skilled workers, as already noted.
There is another change that reduces and
possibly negates the net benefits for the United
States. Coinciding with China’s rapid growth
has been substantial increases in China’s imports
of commodities such as oil. In fact, China has
become the world’s second largest consumer of
oil. Chinese demand for oil has undoubtedly
contributed to higher oil prices. Given the scale
of U.S. oil imports, higher oil prices have certainly
reduced the beneficial effects for the United States
of recent developments in China.12

HOW CHINESE GROWTH
AFFECTS TRADE
The preceding discussion has focused on the
relative-price impacts of China’s integration into
the world economy. Changes in relative prices,
however, are not the only spur to changes in
economic activity. China’s economy has reached
such a size that in recent years it has served as an
engine of growth not only in Asia but also worldwide. Put simply, a wealthier China means rising
Chinese demand for goods of all sorts, including
high-tech goods that China does not produce.
One manifestation of this fact is that Chinese
growth has resulted in large effects on overall trade
flows. The integration of the Chinese economy
into the world economy can be seen very clearly
by examining how Chinese exports and imports
have changed since the late 1970s. In 1979,
Chinese exports as a share of Chinese GDP was
5 percent. Since then the share has risen to 36
percent. (See Figure 7.) The course of Chinese
imports has taken a similar path, rising from
roughly 6 percent of GDP in 1979 to 34 percent
in 2005. These import and export shares may be
compared with the shares for the United States:
Imports are 16 percent of U.S. GDP and exports
are 10 percent.
12

As Chinese exports have grown faster than its
imports, the Chinese trade balance has increased.
A close look at China’s trade balance reveals that
from 1979 to the mid-1990s, the average yearly
balance was roughly zero. (See Figure 8.) Since
the mid-1990s, the balance has tended to rise,
reaching a level of $102 billion in 2005, which is
4.4 percent of China’s GDP.

UNITED STATES–CHINA TRADE
The increase of China’s trade surplus since the
mid-1990s coincides with a substantial increase
in the United States–China bilateral trade balance.
In 1995 the U.S. bilateral trade deficit with China
was approximately $20 billion. (See Figure 9.)
Subsequently, this deficit has increased yearly,
reaching $202 billion for 2005, which was 28
percent of the overall U.S. trade deficit. (See
Figure 10.) Surprisingly, in 1995, China’s share
of the overall U.S. trade deficit was actually larger,
at 35 percent of the overall U.S. trade deficit.
Obviously, since 1995 the growth of U.S.
imports from China has exceeded the growth of
U.S. exports to China. Between 1995 and 2005,
U.S. imports from China increased more than
fivefold, while U.S. exports to China increased
by a factor of 3.6. (See Figure 11.) But note this
important fact: The growth in U.S. exports to
China has been far greater than the growth of U.S.
exports overall. Between 1995 and 2005, total U.S.
exports increased by a factor of 1.6, which is less
than half the rate of increase of U.S. exports to
China. In light of the rapid Chinese growth, it is
not surprising that U.S. exports to China rose
rapidly. It is especially noteworthy that in 1995
China was the 13th leading export market for
goods produced in the United States and in 2005
it was the 4th leading export market. Put simply,
a wealthier China is a better market for U.S. goods
and services, especially for high-tech and agricultural goods, which the United States produces in
abundance.

Not surprisingly, oil is at the center of a contentious political issue. China’s desire for increased oil supplies has led to relationships with a
number of countries, such as Sudan and Uzbekistan, who many view as unsavory in terms of their records on human rights.

7

INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FINANCE

Figure 7
Chinese Exports and Imports as a Percent of GDP
Percent
40
35
30
25

Exports

20
15

Imports

10
5

20
0

4

9
19
9

4
19
9

9
19
8

19
8

19
7

4

9

0

SOURCE: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics, and official Chinese statistics.

Figure 8
China’s Trade Balance, 1979-2005
$ Billions
$101.9
2005

100
80
60
40

$32.0
2004

20
0

SOURCE: China Statistical Yearbook.

8

4
20
0

9
19
9

4
19
9

9
19
8

4
19
8

19
7

9

–20

Chinese Growth: A Source of U.S. Export Opportunities

Figure 9
U.S.–China Bilateral Trade Deficit and U.S. Trade Deficit
$ Billions
100,000
U.S.–China Bilateral Trade Deficit

0
–100,000

–201.54
2005

–200,000
–300,000
–400,000
–500,000

U.S. Trade Deficit

–600,000
–716.73
2005

–700,000

3

8

20
0

19
9

19
9

3

8
19
8

19
8

19
7

3

8

–800,000

SOURCE: U.S. Census Bureau, Foreign Trade Statistics.

Figure 10
China’s Portion of the U.S. Trade Deficit
Percent
45
35

28.12
2005

25
15
5
–5

3
20
0

8
19
9

3
19
9

8
19
8

3
19
8

19
7

8

–15

SOURCE: U.S. Census Bureau, Foreign Trade Statistics.

9

INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FINANCE

Figure 11
U.S. Exports to and Imports from China
$ Millions
250,000

Import Growth

200,000

150,000

100,000
$45,543
1995
$11,754
1995

50,000

Export Growth

5
20
0

2
20
0

9
19
9

6
19
9

3
19
9

0
19
9

7
19
8

4
19
8

1
19
8

19
7

8

0

SOURCE: U.S. Census Bureau, Foreign Trade Statistics.

Chinese purchases of U.S. goods took center
stage during President Hu Jintao’s visit to the
United States last May. During the visit, President
Hu agreed that China would buy $16.2 billion
worth of Boeing jets and various other goods, such
as networking equipment, medical devices, and
beef. A close look at the top 10 exporting industries to China in 2005 reveals that the industry
code including aircraft was the third leading
export industry and that the industry code including medical devices was the fourth leading export
industry. (See Table 1.) The two leading industry
codes were (i) electrical machinery and equipment
and (ii) nuclear reactors, boilers, machinery, and
mechanical appliances. Together, these industries
accounted for 31.5 percent of U.S. exports to China.
Large multinational corporations play a major
role in U.S. exports to China. However, according
to the U.S. Commercial Service, since 1992 the
number of small and midsize exporters has
increased from 3,143 to 19,201, a gain of 511
percent.13 I opened my remarks today with an
example of exports sales by Kanawha Scales and
13

Systems. This same phenomenon of small firms
selling to the Chinese market is found all over the
United States. Consider Sharpe Mixers of Seattle.
This firm makes specialized “absorbers mixers”
that strip sulfur dioxide from power plant emissions. Chinese power plant construction is proceeding rapidly to meet large increases in power
demand. Most of these power plants are coal-fired,
and Sharpe has seen its Chinese business increase
substantially since receiving its first order in 2004.
This additional business has led to 10 additional
employees for a total of 30.

EXPORTS FROM SLC MEMBER
STATES
Let’s look more closely at the total exports
from the SLC states to China. It turns out that the
two leading export sectors are the same as for the
United States as a whole. Together, these industries—electrical machinery and equipment and
nuclear reactors, boilers, machinery, and mechan-

See www.usatoday.com/money/world/2006-04-19-china-exports-usat_x.htm.

10

Chinese Growth: A Source of U.S. Export Opportunities

Table 1
Top 10 U.S. Exports to China—Ranked by 2005 Exports
HS Industry Codes ($ millions)
Code

Description

2005

Share of U.S.
exports to China (%)

85

Electrical machinery and equipment and parts thereof;
sound recorders and reproducers, television recorders
and reproducers, parts and accessories

6,851

16.3

84

Nuclear reactors, boilers, machinery and mechanical
appliances; parts thereof

6,357

15.2

88

Aircraft, spacecraft, and parts thereof

4,381

10.4

90

Optical, photographic, cinematographic, measuring,
checking, precision, medical or surgical instruments
and apparatus; parts and accessories thereof

2,397

5.7

12

Oil seeds and oleaginous fruits; miscellaneous grains, seeds
and fruits, industrial or medicinal plants; straw and fodder

2,289

5.5

39

Plastic and articles thereof

2,259

5.4

72

Iron and steel

1,555

3.7

29

Organic chemicals

1,475

3.5

52

Cotton, including yarns and woven fabrics thereof

1,411

3.4

47

Pulp of wood or other fibrous cellulosic material; recovered
(waste and scrap) paper and paperboard

992

2.4

ical appliances—accounted for 25 percent of the
SLC states’ exports to China during 2005.
Looking at the SLC states individually, we see
substantial differences in their exports to China.
Electrical machinery and equipment is the leading
export category for only two states—Texas and
South Carolina—while nuclear reactors, boilers,
machinery, and mechanical appliances is the
leading export category for four states—North
Carolina, Missouri, Maryland, and Oklahoma.
(See Table 2.) For the remaining 10 states, various commodity codes appear: plastic products
for Alabama and West Virginia, oil seeds for
Louisiana, cotton for Tennessee, wood pulp for
Georgia, base metals for Virginia, iron and steel
products for Kentucky, fertilizers for Florida,
vehicles and parts for Mississippi, and inorganic
chemicals for Arkansas.
For these states, 2005 exports to China range
from $4.9 billion from Texas to $0.1 billion from
Oklahoma. One fact is that, for SLC states, exports

to China relative to gross state product tend to be
below the national average for all states together.
Using figures for 2005, only 4 of the 16 SLC states
had shares in excess of the national average of
0.36 percent. Those states were Louisiana (1.1),
Tennessee (0.62), Texas (0.50), and South Carolina
(0.45).
What is especially encouraging, however, is
that firms in the SLC states have played a key role
in the growth of exports to China. Comparing
2002 with 2005, total U.S. exports to China
increased by a factor of 1.9. However, 13 of the
16 states represented at this meeting experienced
export growth faster than the national average. The
leader was Tennessee, whose exports increased
by a factor of 4.2. Missouri was the second leading state, with exports to China increasing by a
factor of 3.9. The only states lagging the national
average were Mississippi (1.2), Florida (1.0), and
West Virginia (0.9).
11

INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FINANCE

Table 2
SLC Top State Exports to China 2005

State

HS
commodity
code

Commodity description

Top export
2005 value
($ millions)

Total 2005
exports value
($ millions)

Top export
as percent of
total exports

TX

85

Electric machinery, etc.; sound
equipment; TV equipment; parts

1,164.30

4,901.30

23.76

LA

12

Oil seeds, etc.; misc. grain, seed, fruit,
plant, etc.

1,193.10

1,896.00

62.93

TN

52

Cotton, including yarn and woven fabric
thereof

760.40

1,411.40

53.87

GA

47

Pulp of wood, etc.; waste, etc. of paper
and paperboard

139.30

978.70

14.23

NC

84

Nuclear reactors, boilers, machinery,
etc.; parts

163.90

774.40

21.17

VA

81

Base metals nesoi; cermets; articles
thereof

77.20

721.50

10.70

FL

31

Fertilizers

255.10

690.40

36.95

SC

85

Electric machinery, etc.; sound
equipment; TV equipment; parts

88.30

622.20

14.18

MO

84

Nuclear reactors, boilers, machinery,
etc.; parts

84.60

499.50

16.94

AL

39

Plastics and articles thereof

153.40

467.00

32.84

KY

72

Iron and steel

103.60

400.90

25.85

MD

84

Nuclear reactors, boilers, machinery,
etc.; parts

55.40

284.30

19.49

MS

87

Vehicles, except railway or tramway,
and parts, etc.

22.00

164.80

13.38

AR

28

Inorganic chemicals; precious and rare
earth metals and radioactive
compounds

31.30

144.40

21.66

WV

39

Plastics and articles thereof

53.90

135.40

39.82

OK

84

Nuclear reactors, boilers, machinery,
etc.; parts

46.70

94.30

49.55

CONCLUSION
My message for you today can be summarized
very succinctly: The growth of the Chinese economy has provided and will almost certainly continue to provide U.S. firms with important export
opportunities. This growing demand for U.S.
goods and services provides not only more but
14

also better-paying employment opportunities.
This simple message is easy to miss because
the continuing integration of China into the world
economy presents both political and economic
challenges. It is still very easy to identify numerous factors that hinder the sales of goods and
services to China by U.S. firms.14 Without ques-

E. Anthony Wayne, Assistant Secretary for Economic and Business Affairs in the U.S. Department of State, enumerated many of the contentious issues in a speech on May 25, 2005, at the Executive’s Club of Chicago.

12

Chinese Growth: A Source of U.S. Export Opportunities

tion, Chinese infringement of intellectual property
rights remains a problem that limits U.S. exports.
In addition, government procurement policies,
restrictions involving the wholesale and retail
distribution of foreign products in China, and
the lack of transparency of many regulations also
limit U.S. exports.
As I look to the future, I continue to see much
negotiation between the Chinese and U.S. governments as well as many adjustments to the changing economic and political environment by U.S.
firms and consumers. Political pressures will
continue to be felt by U.S. policymakers. Given
the insights from economic theory as well as the
lessons of economic history, my hope is that
policymakers will resist the calls for isolationist
responses. U.S. trade restrictions are highly
unlikely to increase employment opportunities
at home, but clearly would deprive American
consumers of lower-cost goods from China. The
best course of action is to continue to encourage
China to protect intellectual property rights and
to lower barriers on trade.
Taking advantage of the opportunities presented by Chinese growth—rather than simply
attempting to negate the competitive pressures—
is in the best interest of both countries. Opportunities to increase exports are in fact being seized
by U.S. firms, many of which are located in the
16 states served by the Southern Legislative
Conference. Recent export growth by nearly all
of these states has exceeded the national average.
In light of the continuing strong Chinese growth
prospects, prospects for exports to China from
the states represented here today are very bright.
I’ll finish with a general comment. For over
70 years, since the Reciprocal Trade Agreements
Act of 1934, the United States has led the way
toward a more open international trading system,
and I am hopeful that this historic process will
continue. Both economic theory and economic

history have provided ample reasons showing
that changes in legislation and regulation that
tilt toward economic isolation are unwise. Our
future prosperity depends on continuing to build
on past successes in extending open markets and
enjoying the fruits of the productivity advances
open markets promote.

REFERENCES
Anderson, James E. and van Wincoop, Eric. “Trade
Costs.” Journal of Economic Literature, September
2004, 42(3), pp. 691-751.
Baier, Scott L. and Bergstrand, Jeffrey H. “The Growth
of World Trade: Tariffs, Transport Costs, and Income
Similarity.” Journal of International Economics,
February 2001, 53(1), pp. 1-27.
Kamin, Steven B.; Marazzi, Mario and Schindler,
John W. “The Impact of Chinese Exports on Global
Import Prices.” Review of International Economics,
May 2006, 14(2), pp. 179-201.
Prasad, Eswar S. and Rajan, Raghuram G. “Modernizing
China’s Growth Paradigm.” American Economic
Review, May 2006, 96(2), pp. 331-36.
Rodrik, Dani. “What’s So Special about China’s
Exports.” NBER Working Paper 11947, National
Bureau of Economic Research, January 2006.
Wayne, E. Anthony. “China’s Emergence as an
Economic Superpower and Its Implications for
U.S. Businesses.” Remarks at The Executives’ Club
of Chicago, International Leadership Conference,
Chicago, IL, May 25, 2005;
www.state.gov/e/eb/rls/rm/2005/46950.htm.
Wolf, Martin. “The Answer to Asia’s Rise Is Not To
Retreat from the World.” Financial Times, March 15,
2006, p. 17.

13