View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Central Bank Transparency: Why and How?
“How Transparent Should a Central Bank Be?”
The Philadelphia Fed Policy Forum
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Philadelphia, Pennsylvania
November 30, 2001

S

ince arriving at the St. Louis Fed, I’ve
been asked a number of times what I
found to be my biggest challenge. On the
monetary policy side of my responsibilities, I reply without hesitation that my biggest
challenge has been to explain policy to a number
of different audiences. Given that experience, I
believe that the transparency issue is not posed
properly by the title of this session, “How
Transparent Should a Central Bank Be?”; the
issue for me is how in fact to be transparent and
what being transparent really means.
I’ll divide my remarks into two sections. First,
I’ll discuss why I think transparency is important.
Second, I’ll consider the problem of deciding
what actions and statements might improve
transparency and how we might measure the
success of steps to become more transparent. I
must emphasize, however, that I do not have settled views on this subject and believe that there
is much room for constructive development in
this area. The topic is almost unexplored at an
empirical level.
Before proceeding, I want to emphasize that
the views I express here are mine and do not
necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal
Reserve System. I thank my colleagues at the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, especially
Bob Rasche, for their comments, but I retain full
responsibility for errors.

WHY TRANSPARENCY?
Most discussions about transparency are
conditioned by notions of accountability of public

officials in a political setting. Every democratic
society struggles in the purgatory between the
ideal of government responsive to citizen concerns
and the practice of a messy process responsive
to well-financed advocates. We are instinctively
suspicious of secret deals because we fear that
they will come at taxpayer expense or will benefit undeserving special interests. The experience
of our democracy, and that of other democracies,
demonstrates beyond any doubt that the fear of
secret deals is justified. We believe that policy
decisions in the public interest rather than in the
private interest will lead to a healthier and fairer
society.
I hasten to add, however, that as far as I know
special interest motivations have not had an
important bearing on U.S. monetary policy.
Because monetary policy is a generalized policy
instrument, it has inherently little scope for providing special benefits to narrow economic interests. I discussed some of these issues at greater
length several years ago in a lecture entitled, “The
Federal Reserve as a Democratic Institution.”
Transparency in a general sense simply means
providing the fullest explanation possible of
policy actions and the considerations underlying
them, in as timely a manner as possible. An advantage of transparency in this sense, familiar to
every teacher and researcher, is that the best way
to be sure you understand an issue is to explain
it to others in a class, a journal article, a lecture,
or in meeting minutes. Transparency is a great
spur to developing coherent views, and surely it
is beneficial to policymakers to be coherent in
their own thinking.
1

MONETARY POLICY AND INFLATION

I remember my concern in years past, before
assuming my current position, that refusal of
public officials to explain their actions often
reflected their own sense that their views were
not very well formed, rather than a need to hide
unsavory motivations. I personally believe that
my current sense of obligation to explain my
views publicly is as much, or more, a benefit to
me as to my listeners and readers. I regularly use
my speeches as an opportunity to dig into a specific policy issue and to force myself to develop
an opinion on a matter I really ought to understand
thoroughly.
Most discussions of transparency do not seem
to go much beyond a faith that “government in
the sunshine” will yield the desired results. However, naive confidence in “sunshine” is surely
inadequate. One issue is that policy meetings in
the sunshine are simply different meetings than
ones held confidentially. A different meeting in
the sunshine is not necessary a better meeting
from the perspective of serving the public interest
well.
Sunshine advocates expect sunshine meetings
to differ from closed meetings in that policymakers are assumed not to cut deals contrary to
the public interest when they meet in the sunshine. I do not know of a study of the subject, but
my casual impression is that there is no evidence
that there is less special interest legislation now
than there used to be before enactment of various
pieces of sunshine legislation, such as the Freedom
of Information Act.
From an economist’s perspective, the issue
of “Why transparency?” seems pretty straightforward. Put simply, policy actions affect the
economy through expectations in the financial
markets and in the economy more generally.
What the FOMC does most directly is to set a target for the federal funds rate. Expectations about
the level of that target in the future determine
interest rates all along the yield curve. Expectations about how the Fed will respond to various
possible events determine, among other things,
the expected inflation rate. Assuming that the
Fed has sound policy objectives, its success
depends critically on market expectations and
2

market confidence. Those expectations will be
more accurate and confidence more complete
the more accurately the market understands what
the Fed is doing.
I know of no finding in the macroeconomics
literature that provides a theoretical case, or
empirical support, for the view that confusion or
uncertainty in the private sector about the direction of monetary policy serves to better achieve
policy objectives. Indeed, in the rational expectations literature, inaccurate expectations about
policy unambiguously create inefficiencies in the
economy. I take this point seriously, and believe
that it provides a compelling case for policymakers to provide as much information about policy
as they possibly can. But I do want to reemphasize
that a naive approach to disclosure can damage
the deliberative process without providing information of genuine value to the markets.

HOW TO ACHIEVE
TRANSPARENCY?
From what I’ve just said, the answer to “Why
transparency?” is that we hope to achieve better
policy results. But how to achieve greater transparency, or whether any particular step will be
constructive, is far from simple.
Consider the possibility of televising FOMC
meetings, so all can observe the proceedings.
One issue is the mismatch between the technical
level of the meeting and the knowledge of the
audience. If I really want to convey information
on a particular subject effectively, I’ll give a different lecture to a freshman economics class than
to a graduate seminar. Monetary policy needs to
be conducted at the highest possible technical
level; a general audience is more likely to be confused than enlightened by watching an FOMC
meeting live. Most viewers would get little out of
watching a discussion of technical econometric
issues— which do arise from time to time in
FOMC meetings—and might well misinterpret
such discussion. Perhaps we shouldn’t worry
too much about this issue, as the audience for an
FOMC meeting would probably be pretty small

Central Bank Transparency: Why and How?

after a few such episodes. I do not think we would
compete very successfully with daytime television!
Of course, a televised FOMC meeting would
not be the same meeting we hold today. For one
thing, the deliberations could not include discussion of information obtained under pledge of
confidentiality. Information from individual firms
does play a useful role in policymaking, and the
Fed could not obtain such information without
maintaining its confidentiality. Moreover, there
is ample evidence that people in televised meetings behave differently than those in closed meetings. Some participants might have a tendency
to grandstand for the audience and to avoid discussing difficult or controversial issues. In a
completely open meeting, it is hard for some
participants to try out ideas and then admit that
the arguments offered by others are better. It is
particularly difficult to analyze unpleasant possibilities in public, such as that a particular policy
action might have the effect of increasing the risk
of recession.
Anyone who has held a policymaking position
knows how important confidentiality issues are.
The Federal Reserve faced a sudden and severe
confrontation with this issue in October 1993,
when information concerning the long-standing
practice of taping FOMC meetings became public.
Most FOMC members were unaware that the
meetings were being taped; the published transcript of the FOMC conference call of October 15,
1993, demonstrates vividly the anguish and uncertainty about how to proceed. It is clear from that
transcript that the members were unanimous in
believing that quick release of meeting transcripts
would severely inhibit free exchange of ideas
and information and damage the deliberative
process. Many members were concerned that
release of transcripts even after a lag of three to
five years would also be harmful.
I’m told—but have no firsthand knowledge—
that after the taping of FOMC meetings became
publicly known, the meetings changed significantly for a time. Members read from prepared
statements and give-and-take discussion did not
occur as readily as it had previously. During the
time I’ve been in St. Louis, my impression is that

FOMC deliberations are extremely open and that
issues are thoroughly explored. I do not think
that disclosing the transcript with a five-year lag
inhibits my discussion, and believe that to be the
case for most other members as well. I also believe
that the transcript provides a valuable record for
scholars and I strongly support the current system
of releasing lightly edited transcripts.
So, my answer to why transparency is that
we expect better public policy outcomes from a
transparent process, but the more I consider how
transparency, the more difficult the issue seems.
The current system of releasing the FOMC transcript with a five-year lag works well. I do not
believe that monetary policy actions motivated
by special interests were a problem in the first
place, and so the transcripts have not had a bearing on that issue. But the transcripts have served
to enhance knowledge of the policy decision
process and that has been constructive.
Probably more important than the transcripts
in recent years was the decision in February 1994
to release the policy decision promptly at the conclusion of each FOMC meeting. My colleagues in
the St. Louis Fed research division and I have
conducted some research on the effects of that
step. The bottom line from this research is that
prompt disclosure of policy actions significantly
improved the accuracy of market forecasts of
policy actions.
The FOMC began disclosing its so-called
“bias” in 1999 and later revamped the language
of that statement. Moreover, disclosure of the
policy action is now accompanied by a short
statement. I have not examined empirically the
effectiveness of these steps and have an open
mind as to whether they have in fact improved
public understanding of policy actions or the
accuracy of market forecasts of future policy
actions. I think it important to maintain an empirical perspective on these issues, for there is no
other way to decide whether a particular step in
the name of transparency is in fact effective.
Differences in central bank disclosure practices offer a great opportunity to conduct research
on how best to pursue an effort to increase transparency. Many policies and practices differ among
3

MONETARY POLICY AND INFLATION

the world’s central banks. If we are to make genuine progress on determining what works and
what doesn’t with regard to disclosure, we need
to dig into the research opportunity presented by
these different disclosure practices.
I’ll finish by mentioning two specific ideas
for improving Fed transparency. One is that the
Fed could announce an explicit inflation objective, expressed either as a point target or a target
range. I have long believed that such a step would
be useful, and I advocated an explicit inflation
objective not too long after arriving in St. Louis.
A number of other central banks have explicit
inflation objectives; however, comparing U.S.
and foreign inflation experience does not provide
a convincing case that an announced objective is
necessary to maintain a low rate of inflation. Thus,
although I do favor an announced inflation
objective, it is clear that an empirical case is not
a decisive consideration; transparency issues
can never be resolved entirely through empirical
investigation.
A second specific suggestion is that the FOMC
might consider reducing its end-of-meeting statement to relatively simple boilerplate language.
This suggestion may appear to be a step backward,
but the issue is that the current statement is open
to a variety of market interpretations, and the
uncertainty about exactly what the statement
means may not be helpful to the cause of clear
communication. Boilerplate language with a relatively few options might have, or come to have, a
settled meaning that would reduce market uncertainty. This example is also interesting because
it illustrates the general point I’m emphasizing
that how transparency is not a simple issue.
In summary, the case for why transparency
is clear. Transparency promotes accountability,
improves market efficiency and probably
improves the clarity of policymaking itself. How
transparency is just plain hard. It is easy to find
communications gaps, but not at all easy to fill
them.

4