View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery

Statement of
William McChesney Martin, Jr. ,
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,




before the
Subcommittee on International Finance
of the
Senate Committee on Banking and Currency

March 10, 1965

For the second time in less than two years, a national
program to reduce and eventually eliminate our large international
payments deficit has been launched.

Our first program, begun

with President Kennedy's message to Congress of July 18, 1963,
met for a time with a measure of success, but in the course of last
year, signs of fresh deterioration appeared.

The fourth quarter of

1964 brought a near-record payments deficit.

During the first six

weeks of 1965 tentative and fragmentary data indicated that a large
deficit was in prospect for the first quarter of the current year.
The need for more vigorous action was clear.

President

Johnson's program of February 10, 1965, was in response to this
challenge.

For an important part of the program, the President

called upon the Federal Reserve to assume major responsibility.
Accordingly, we have now communicated to the commercial banks
and other financial institutions of this country guidelines for a
voluntary effort to restrain their foreign lending.
It may be helpful to you in the course of my statement to
explain briefly the approach to our international payments problem
followed by the Federal Reserve in laying down its guidelines.




-2-

The magnitude of our payments deficit is determined by
three main factors: first, the commercial balance on goods and
services; second, our military expenditures abroad and our
economic aid to foreign countries; and third, the net outflow of our
private capital into foreign countries-

The Presidents program

attacks the deficit on all three fronts.

But as the Federal Reserve

is not asked to deal with Government expenditures, my comments
will be directed primarily to problems on commercial account and
private capital account.
It cannot be stressed too often, in my opinion, that the
main contribution of monetary policy both to our continued domestic
expansion and to the restoration of our international payments
equilibrium is the maintenance of credit conditions that help bring
about cost and price stability.

Avoidance of both inflation and

deflation not only averts one of the main perils to sustainable
economic growth; it is also indispensable to preservation and
improvement of the international competitive position of our indus¬
tries at home and in world markets.
The further expansion of our commercial surplus depends
on continued avoidance of cost and price increases--although,
needless to say, many other factors, such as the level of economic
activity at home and abroad, also play important roles.




-3-

3y providing monetary conditions favorable to price
stability, Federal Reserve policy has, in my judgment, been as
successful as could be expected in furthering a satisfactory
development of our payments balance on current account.

I do

not want to minimize the importance of some signs pointing toward
renewed upward cost and price pressures. As I said in my testi¬
mony before the Joint Economic Committee on February 26, I
cannot avoid the feeling that we have been, and still are, sailing
very close to the edge in this area.

But the over-all changes up

to now in per-unit costs of production, in wholesale prices, and in
the cost of living, have so far not imperiled our international trade
performance.
With regard to the Federal Reserve's contribution to
minimizing outflows on capital account, the matter, unfortunately,
is not quite so simple. While our commercial balance has shown
record surpluses, our capital account has shown record deficits.
The total net private U. S. capital outflow in 1964 amount ed to over
$6 billion--twice as much as our total payments deficit--and the
net expansion of bank credit to foreigners alone accounted for more
than one-third of this capital outflow.




-4-

As a matter of principle, the aim of Federal Reserve
policy is to maintain monetary conditions that are conducive to an
adequate supply of credit and capital.

This means a supply large

enough to finance continuing economic expansion domestically
without inflation, but not so generous as to make possible either an
unsustainable investment boom or an undue spill-over of funds to
foreign countries.
The supply of credit and capital in recent years, in my
judgment, certainly has been large enough to meet all legitimate
domestic financing needs.

It has so far not given rise to an un¬

sustainable boom--although developments in some fields such as
construction need to be carefully watched.

But our monetary policy

has permitted credit in the United States to remain relatively cheap
and plentiful in comparison with other major markets, and thus has
been a factor in the magnitude of our private capital outflow.
While this capital outflow has played an important part in
swelling our payments deficit, we must remain mindful that the
United States is and will probably continue in the future to be an
important source of credit and capital for the rest of the world.

As

the richest and most productive nation of the world, the United States
is capable of generating the largest supply of savings, both in




-5-

absolute terms and in relation to national income.

Our accumu¬

lated stock of invested capital is also larger than that of any other4
country, again both in absolute amounts and in relation to national
product.

Hence, our domestic demand for new investment is more

easily satisfied than in most if not all foreign countries.

With a

larger supply and a somewhat less strong demand than in other
countries, the availability of credit and capital will tend to be greater,
and the cost of credit and capital lower, than in the rest of the
world.
This is not an unusual situation.

In previous periods, the

same relation obtained with respect to those nations that happened
to be in the economic and financial lead for their time.

France, the

Low Countries, and especially Britain were for many generations
a continuing source of credit and capital for the rest of the world,
and during those periods their interest rate levels were naturally
lower than in borrowing countries.
It is clear that restoration of our foreign payments equili¬
brium does not require our capital outflow to come to anything like
a full stop.

Arithmetically, a cutback in our private capital outflow

of about one-half of the 1964 volume would suffice to wipe out the
entire payments deficit provided all other elements in the payments
balance remained the same.

Realistically, it would be both

impracticable and unwise to put the entire burden of correcting the
payments deficit on private financing.




-6-

The main problem confronting the Federal Re serve--and
our nation at large--is how to reduce the net outflow of credit and
capital without at the same time constricting the domestic supply
so much that financing needed for our expanding economy at stable
prices is unduly impeded.
Two alternative courses of policy are available to cope
with this problem: one, a general increase in the cost and a lessen¬
ing of the availability of credit; and the other, specific action
designed to cut only the supply of credit and capital to foreigners
without impinging on the needed supply to the domestic economy.
The Federal Reserve has to some extent followed the tradi¬
tional course of the first alternative. At the time President Kennedy
was formulating his program and in the prospect of its early
announcement, the Federal Reserve shifted its policy posture in
the direction of less domestic ease and increased its discount rate
from 3 to 3-1/2 per cent, and shortly after lifted the ceiling interest
rate on time deposits in the maturity range of 90 days to one year
to 4 per cent. These actions were promptly reflected in financial
markets. within a few weeks the Treasury bill rate had risen by
more than one-half a percentage point and over ensuing months longterm interest rates drifted upward by just over one-eighth of a points




-7-

These upward shifts in the level of domestic interest rates
went some distance in better aligning our interest rates with those
in foreign markets. Through the second half of 1963 and the early
months of 1964, this alignment continued

tolerably satisfactory.

About this time, in major industrial countries abroad, strong credit
demands accompanying strong economic growth and creeping infla¬
tion were carrying foreign interest rates to levels fully offsetting
the advances that had been experienced in U. S. markets. In
recognition of the pull that the higher foreign rates might exert on
our credit supplies, the Federal Reserve in August firmed domestic
money market conditions slightly further, with the result that the
Treasury bill rate moved modestly above the discount rate.
Under continued pressure of inflationary trends abroad,
however, the availability of credit came under increasing central
bank restraint in various foreign markets.

In these circumstances,

capital outflow from the United States accelerated.
About the time we were experiencing this mounting capital
outflow, an adverse payments balance for the United Kingdom put
the pound sterling under strong pressure in international markets,
resulting in large drains on Britain's monetary reserves.

That

country was obliged to take a number of emergency steps, including
the establishment by its central bank of a discount rate of 7 per
cent. To support the pound in international markets, the Bank of
England arranged for a $1 billion drawing on the IMF along with about
$3 billion of credits with other central banks.




-8-

In view of uncertainties which developed at this point in
international financial markets and in recognition of the advances
in short-term rates that had been occurring in other international
markets, the Federal Reserve raised its discount rate last
November from 3-1/2 to 4 per cent.

At the same time, ceilings

on the interest rates that banks are permitted to pay on time deposits
of over 90 days were raised to 4. 5 per cent.

Short-term rates in

our money market promptly moved upward further about a quarter
of a per cent in adjustment to these changes; long-term rates,
however, continued to fluctuate narrowly within the range that had
prevailed for several years, reflecting the continued large flow of
domestic savings.
It is impossible to say how large the capital outflow in
the fourth quarter might have been if we had not taken the actions
when we did.

All that we now know is that in spite of whatever

inhibiting effect may have come from these actions and the accom¬
panying increase in short rates, there was a further rise in lending
and investing abroad.
Nevertheless, we have not moved further in the traditional
way to constrain our renewed capital outflow.

Considering the

desirability of further reducing our level of unemployment and more
fully utilizing our resources, we have risked permitting some spill¬
over of funds into foreign uses, and have sought other, more
selective means of coping with the outflow problem.




-9-

There are three selective ways by which capital outflow
can be reduced: by tax measures; by exchange! controls; or by
enlistment of voluntary cooperation.
The Interest Equalization Tax is an example of the first
approach.

Experience with this approach so far has indicated

both its strength and weakness.

It is generally agreed that a tax

is more consistent with the principles on which our economy is
based than would be the use of direct controls or an appeal to
voluntary cooperation.

But a tax statute can hardly avoid some

opportunities for legal escape, since it is extremely difficult in
legislative drafting to foresee all loophole possibilities.

Too

embracing a tax, with many exceptions and qualifications, could
be so complicated to administer that its effectiveness would be
seriously impaired.
Exchange controls have not been tried in the past, except
under wartime conditions, and I, for one, hope they will not be
tried.

3y shifting decision making in individual business trans¬

actions from participants to some Government agency, this approach
would be repugnant to the principles of our economic system.

Also,

experience everywhere has shown that exchange regulations, if
couched in general terms, can be avoided as easily as a special
tax; and if elaborated in great detail, become so oppressive that




-10-

they also hamper business activities beneficial to our payments
situation.

And once this route has been chosen, expedience has

demonstrated the difficulty of retracing one's steps towards freedom
from controls.

Of the three methods of selective restraint,

exchange controls are, in my judgment, the one that should not be
seriously contemplated.
This leaves for comment the voluntary approach.
method also has shortcomings.

This

The person, individual or corporate,

adhering to a voluntary program may be penalized in favor of an
uncooperative person.

But if widespread voluntary restraint can

reasonably be expected, the method has three advantages: first, it
leaves the ultimate decision to the market participants; second, it
is flexible enough to take care of changing circumstances and of
the experience gained in the process; and third, given the good faith
of all parties, it avoids the encumbrance of legalistic interpretations
of the "rules of the game. "f
With regard to the expansion of credits to foreigners granted
by banks and other financial institutions) the prospects of general
compliance with voluntary efforts are particularly good because a
comparatively few institutions account for the great bulk of the total
funds involved.

And the response the Federal Reserve has en¬

countered in its initial efforts to implement the President's program
has been quite encouraging.




-11-

Last week, the Federal Reserve issued its guidelines to
the banks and to other financial institutions.

The guidelines provide

that any bank may expand its credit to foreigners by 5 per cent of
the amount outstanding at the end of 1964,

Such a figure is consistent

with the expected growth of our national product and also the expected
growth of international trade.

But it is much smaller than was the

rate of last year's credit outflow.

All of us realize that the restraint

asked for may create hardship in individual cases.
Our guidelines, which are directed to each bank individually,
are designed to distribute the burden as equitably as possible and
to avoid unnecessary inconvenience.

In particular, they are designed

to avert any adverse repercussions on our international commerce;
on sound development efforts of less developed countries; and on
such countries as Canada and Japan, which are largely dependent on
U. S. financing, and Britain, which is suffering from serious payments
difficulties of its own.
We expect that banks will continue to grant bona fide export
credits; such credits are to be

given absolute priority.

Obviously,

no priority can be claimed for credit extensions that substitute a
credit sale for a cash sale or that substitute financing by U. S. banks
for financing from nonbank or foreign resources.




-12-

We also expect that banks will continue to finance sound
development projects of less developed countries.

But clearly a

less developed country should not rely on U. S. credit for projects
that can and should be financed either with the country's own
resources, or by other industrial nations--e. g. , where the project
envisages imports from European suppliers.
The guidelines explicitly state that substantial cutbacks
are expected only in nonexport credits to those fully developed
countries that are not customarily dependent on U. S. financing
and that do not suffer from payments difficulties.

Most if not all

Continental European countries should fall into this category.
The guidelines for nonbank financial institutions are more
general and tentative in their specifications.

They envisage cut¬

backs in the placement of liquid funds abroad, primarily in the
so-called Euro-dollar market.

In the case of short- and medium-

term credits, the guidelines for banks are in effect applicable to
nonbanks.

But in the case of long-term credits (with a maturity of

five years or more), which are probably more important in the case
of nonbanks than of banks, no specific target has been set.

Most

longer-term credits to fully developed countries are subject to the
Interest Equalization Tax,

No effort is being made to discourage

continued long-term investments in less developed countries, which
need this type of assistance more urgently than additional bank credits.




-13-

While I am optimistic about the effectiveness of the
voluntary restraint efforts, it would be impossible to give any
quantitative estimate of their probable impact on our payments
balance this year. Some banks greatly increased their credits to
foreigners during the first six weeks of this year; some made very
heavy advance commitments which they will have to honor; some
carry many long-term credits among their outstanding assets, on
which only small repayments are expected this year; others expect
to have to increase their export credits and their loans to less
developed countries without being able immediately to reduce
sufficiently their nonexport credits to industrial countries.

Banks

that find themselves in such predicaments as these have been given
12 months to reduce their outstanding credits to no more than 105
per cent of the 1964 level.
Moreover, we realize that in spite of all good will and
vigilance there may be some shifting of bank credit to nonbanking
institutions.

The effect of this shift on the over-all reduction of

nonbank credits to foreigners cannot be predicted at this stage.
For the moment, we appear to be making good progress
indeed.

But of course, the real test of the program lies ahead.

Meanwhile, I should not like to say more than that we expect the
net expansion of both bank credit and total credit to foreigners to be
reduced this year by a substantial amount,




-14-

This reduction in capital outflows will be welcome.

But in

itself it will not be sufficient to assure the success of the Presidents
program.

For that, two things more are required: a further increase

in our export surplus and a further decrease in our Government
expenditures abroad.

To borrow a word from the other side of the

Iron Curtain, the program is like a troika, which cannot move if only
one of its three horses keeps going.
Since I envisage success for the program, there is no need
for me to dwell on actions that might become necessary if the program
were not as successful as expected.

But the inference from the

analysis of the situation is unequivocal. with exchange controls
decidedly inadvisable, and with tax measures unlikely to be more
effective than voluntary action, a return to the traditional recipe of
further restraint may be necessary in the monetary sphere, as may
be further restraint in the spheres of military expenditures,
economic aid and tourism.
But even if the program of voluntary cooperation achieves
the greatest possible degree of success, we cannot think of it as a
permanent institution.

This program can serve as a dyke for a

period of time, but still farther ahead we have to look for a more
basic adjustment of our international payments balance.

The better

we succeed in keeping our industries competitive in international




-15-

commerce, and the better we succeed in reducing our Government
payments abroad, the less we will need to be concerned about our
capital outflow, and the sooner we can return to a system that
leaves balance on capital account to the forces of a free market.