View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery




Statement of

William McChesney Martin, Jr.,
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,

before the

Committee on Finance
of the
United States Senate
on
H.R. 6950

March 21, 1967.

Throughout the world there is an imperative need to increase
productive capital.

As population continues to grow rapidly and the

supply of easily accessible natural resources diminishes, we must
look to more efficient technology in production and distribution if
living standards are to bemaintained—

let

alone raised—for the vast

numbers of people now living in poverty.
The scientific base for improving our technology is available,
and growing rapidly as we reap the benefits of two decades of large
expenditures for technological research and development.

What is

lacking, in many countries, is adequate incentive to convert this
scientific knowledge into workingpractice—

into

machinery which can

increase the yield of usable product from our natural resources, into
machinery which can release human labor for more dignified and useful
tasks.
save —

And many countries also lack the incentives or capacity to
to

free the financial and physical resources needed for building

the capital base necessary for increased production in the future.
We in the United States are indeed fortunate to have, in
such large measure, the conditions necessary to exploit scientific
advance in the service of economic progress.

We have a large savings

flow, an efficient financial mechanism for making savings available
to finance investment, the technical knowledge required to develop
complex production processes, a competitive business community
eager to apply technological innovation in the pursuit of profits,
and large and affluent markets receptive to the new and better
products of industry.




In recent years, moreover, our tax structure

-2-

has been revised to promote the long-term economic growth of the
United States. The investment tax credit for equipment, introduced
in 1962, must be regarded as an important landmark in this respect.
This tax change has rewarded us even in the short-term.
As industry responded to new incentives, business expenditures for
new plant and equipment rose rapidly.

In the three year period from

1960 to 1963, the average rise in business outlays for fixed capital
was only about 3 per cent.

But in the past three years--1964 through

1966--such outlays increased, on average, over 15 per cent a year.
The more efficient plant that resulted from rising capital
spending was an important factor in maintaining cost and price stability
during the economic expansion after 1961.

The high rate of investment

helped to employ our growing labor force, and to raise real wages and
incomes.

And labor was employed more effectively; productivity per

manhour rose considerably faster than earlier.

Unit labor costs

in manufacturing showed an almost unprecedented stability, and this
was reflected in a long period of nearly constant prices of industrial
commodities.
These results paid important dividends for our international
balance of payments.

The competitive position of the United States

in export markets was substantially improved, a development that was
vital in offsetting increased outflows of U.S. financial capital.
And the investment credit was also helpful in increasing the
attractiveness of investment in the United States compared to that
overseas.




-3-

While many other measures contributed directly or indirectly
to the exceptionally long and stable expansion, there is no doubt that
the investment tax credit was an important element.

But in economics,

as in all other aspects of life, it is possible to have too much of
a good thing, particularly when it becomes a case of too much, too
fast.

The combination of sharply accelerating military needs after

mid-1965, strong and expanding civilian markets for durable goods,
and sharp further increases in spending for fixed capital spurred
by the tax incentives, focused unmanageable demands on the metals
and machinery producing industries.

Business capital outlays last

year amounted to almost 11 per cent of GNP compared with 9 per cent
in 1961, the year before the investment tax credit was instituted.'
Backlogs of orders for machinery mounted, even though output in the
machinery producing industries had been running at or above reasonable
capacity limits for some time.

The workweek in these industries rose

to the highest levels in over 20 years, owing to shortages of skilled
workers, and imports of equipment increased while exports of capital
goods were cut back.

And shortages of supply of many metals

necessitated releases from the Nation's stockpiles to alleviate
production bottlenecks.
Increases in the prices of machinery and equipment began
to accelerate because of rising order backlogs and rising costs.
Although the price rise last year was not as rapid as in the 1955-57
investment boom, nevertheless the increases were substantial for




-4almost all classes of machinery.

Over the twelve months preceding the

investment credit suspension, electrical machinery prices rose 2-1/2
per cent, farm machinery and construction machinery prices advanced
3 per cent, general purpose machinery 5 per cent, and metal working
machinery 5-1/2 per cent.
With the economy over-stimulated by rapidly expanding
business investment and defense spending, it was natural to search
for any device that could help reduce demand pressures in the metal
and machinery industries.

Monetary policy was doing all it could to

restrain aggregate demand, though its effects could not easily be
focused on the business investment area.
There were differences in view on the wisdom of meeting
the situation by suspension of the investment tax credit.

Some

observers felt that the effectiveness of the tax credit as a long
run investment incentive might be blunted if it were switched on
and off periodically.

Others felt that owing to the long lead time

for large integrated investment projects, the suspension would have
little immediate effect in reducing demand pressures, and instead
might tend to slow down the expansion in productive facilities only
after a substantial lag, perhaps at a time when the pinch on resource
availability was coming to an end.
substantial share of businessequipment—
equipment, and thelike—
and delivery.




has

Still others pointed out that a
such

as trucks, office

a fairly short lead time between order

It was argued that the marginal effects of suspending

-5-

the tax credit would be large enough and come soon enough to be
worth departing temporarily from what was, for the long-term, a
desirable structural feature of our tax laws.
In the event, the suspension of the investment incentives,
following increased restraint on the availability of investment finance,
did prove effective in damping down the investment boom.

As the

special survey conducted by the Department of Commerce and the
Securities and Exchange Commission indicated, businessmen reported
that the tax law changes induced them to reduce their capital spending
plans for 1967 by $2.3 billion below what otherwise would have been
spent.

And some of the reductions apparently took place rather

promptly.

In the fourth quarter of 1966, business capital spending

was three-quarters of a billion dollars below the amounts businessmen
had earlier reported they intended to spend.

While the amounts of

actual and planned spending reductions involved are small, relative
to the $60 billion annual rate at which capital outlays are running,
the reductions have taken some of the edge off current pressures
on the machinery producing industries.

And the possibility of

further reductions in capital spending was suggested by the most
recent survey of business capital spending plans, which reported
that businessmen are planning to increase investment outlays by
only 4 per cent this year, compared with a 17 per cent rise from
1965 to 1966.




-6-

Even before the latest survey of spending intentions,
evidence of reduced pressure in the metals and machinery industries
was accumulating.

New orders for machinery leveled off in the fall

and recently have begun to decline.

And the accumulation since last

summer of excessive inventories in both investment and consumer goods
industries suggested some weakening in over-all economic prospects,
which would inevitably feed back onto business demands for additional
new equipment.

In recent months, moreover, price pressures have eased

in many of the commodity and product areas where demand had been most
intense.
The time now seems appropriate, therefore, to restore the
incentives for maintaining capital formulation at a rate we will
need over the longer run to meet the requirements of a growing
population desirous of rising living standards.

Physical resources

have come into better balance with demands, suggesting that a somewhat faster pace of investment than presently contemplated by businessmen can be accommodated without regenerating the price pressures
evident a year ago.

And in financial markets, the abatement of

inflationary pressures has permitted the Federal Reserve to resume
vigorous expansion of bank reserves; this, along with a high and
rising rate of personal saving, should provide sufficient funds to
accommodate business financing requirements and an adequate volume
of home financing.




-7Restoration of the investment incentives would be particularly
important for smaller enterprises, the segment of our business community
which contributes so much to technological innovation.

The Department

of Commerce survey to which I referred earlier indicated that suspension of the investment incentives hit hardest on small business-firms with assets of less than $5 million.

In manufacturing and

commercial lines, these small companies accounted for the bulk of the
reductions reported in capital spending programs.
Reinstatement of the accelerated depreciation provisions
should also aid in the recovery of construction activity.

I have

every expectation that home building will increase as the year
progresses, stimulated by an ample supply of credit.

Apartment

building could lag, however, if builders tend to delay their plans
and orders--which in the case of apartment projects often require a
long lead time--until the accelerated depreciation option were
restored.

Investment plans of commercial establishments, where new

construction is a large part of the investment total, are also likely
to be affected by uncertainties about the rapidity of tax write-off
to be permitted.
More generally, reinstating the investment credit now would
avoid the possibility of an unnecessary and undesirable hesitation
in the rate of economic advance as the year progressed.

If the law

were to be left as it is, with reinstatement of the incentives
deferred until next January, we might have to face the possibility of




-8an "air pocket" in new orders for equipment later this year, as
businessmen delayed orders pending final decisions on the fate of the
legislation.

Economic expansion could falter as both Government and

business policy makers found it difficult to assess the strength of
economic prospects.

Now that the need for investment restraint has

lessened, we should not defer the decision to restore to our tax
structure features we regard as desirable for the long run.
Let me note in conclusion that I see no inconsistency in
advocating termination of the investment tax credit suspension now,
and an increase in income taxes later this year.

Restoration of the

incentives to invest in new plant and equipment is needed to maintain
and improve the efficiency of our productive mechanism; it is an
important element in achieving and sustaining our long-term objectives
of rapid economic growth.

And it is appropriate to restore these

incentives now, since some of the bottlenecks in the machinery producing
industries have been removed and some of the pressures on scarce
labor and material resources in that industry have moderated.
But in the short run, we must bear in mind that we are
still fighting a war, that rising Federal spending for this military
effort is contributing to a large deficit in the Federal Government's
accounts, and that a resurgence in economic activity is the most
likely prospect as 1967 progresses.

It seems to me that we should

all be expected to pay our share of military costs. Moreover, on
budgetary grounds, we must recognize that continued large deficits




~9-

in the Government's budget during prosperous times can diminish
confidence, both here and abroad, in the soundness of our money.

On

economic grounds, it seems to me that prudence calls for moderate fiscal
action, as envisaged in the President's tax surcharge proposal, as
insurance against the possibility that we might again confront difficulties of the character that developed in 1965 and

1966.

This course

seems to me to offer the best prospect for achieving the sustained
economic growth that all of us want.