View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
(Approximately 12 Noon EDT,
Tuesday, June 1, 1965)

Does Monetary History Repeat Itself?

Address of Wm. McC, Martin, Jr. ,
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,




before the

Commencement Day Luncheon
of the Alumni Federation of Columbia University

New York City

June 1, 1965

When economic prospects are at their brightest, the
dangers of complacency and recklessness are greatest.

As our

prosperity proceeds on its record-breaking path, it behooves every
one of us to scan the horizon of our national and international
economy for danger signals so as to he ready for any storm.
Some eminent observers have recently compared the
present with the period preceding the breakdown of the interwar
economy, and have warned us of the threats of another Great
Depression, We should take these warnings seriously enough to
inquire into their merits and to try to profit in the future from the
lessons of the past.
And indeed, we find disquieting similarities between our
present prosperity and the fabulous twenties.
Then, as now, there had been virtually uninterrupted
progress for seven years.

And if we disregard some relatively

short though severe fluctuations, expansion had been underway for
more than a generation--the two longest stretches of that kind since
the advent of the industrial age; and each period had been distorted
in its passage by an inflationary war and postwar boom.




-2-

Then, as now, prosperity had been concentrated in the
fully developed countries, and within most of these countries, in
the industrialized sectors of the economy.
Then, as now, there was a large increase in private
domestic debt; in fact, the expansion in consumer debt arising out of
both residential mortgages and instalment purchases has recently
been much faster than in the twenties.
Then, as now, the supply of money and bank credit and
the turnover of demand deposits had been continuously growing; and
while in the late twenties this growth had occurred with little over¬
all change in gold reserves, this time monetary expansion has been
superimposed upon a dwindling gold reserve.
Then, as now, the Federal Reserve had been accused of
lack of flexibility in its monetary policy: of insufficient ease in times
of economic weakness and of insufficient firmness in times of
economic strength.
Then, as now, the world had recovered from the wartime
disruption of international trade and finance, and convertibility of
the major world currencies at fixed par values had been restored
for a number of years.




-3-

Then, as now, international indebtedness had risen as
fast as domestic debt; recently, in fact, American bank credits to
foreigners and foreign holdings of short-term dollar assets have
increased faster than in the closing years of the earlier period.
Then, as now, the payments position of the main reserve
center--Britain then and the United States now--was uneasy, to say
the least; but again, our recent cumulative payments deficits have
far exceeded Britain's deficits of the late twenties.
Then, as now, some countries had large and persistent
payments surpluses and used their net receipts to increase their
short-term reserves rather than to invest in foreign countries.
Then, as now, the most important surplus country,
France, had just decided to convert its official holdings of foreign
exchange into gold, regardless of the effects of its actions on inter¬
national liquidity.
Then, as now, there were serious doubts about the appro¬
priate levels of some existing exchange rate relationships, leading
periodically to speculative movements of volatile short-term funds.
And most importantly, then as now, many government
officials, scholars, and businessmen were convinced that a new
economic era had opened, an era in which business fluctuations had
become a thing of the past, in which poverty was about to be abolished,
and in which perennial economic progress and expansion were assured.




-4-

If some of these likenesses seem menacing, we may take
comfort in important differences between the present and the inter¬
war situation.
The distribution of our national income now shows less
disparity than in the earlier period; in particular, personal incomes,
and especially wages and salaries, have kept pace with corporate
profits, and this has reduced the danger of investment expanding in
excess of consumption needs.
Perhaps related to that better balance, the increase in
stock market credit now has been much smaller.
Instead of a gradual decline in wholesale prices and
stability in consumer prices, there has now been stability in whole¬
sale prices though consumer prices have been creeping up.
The worst defects in the structure of commercial and
investment banking and of business seem to have been corrected-although we are time and again reminded of our failure to eliminate
all abuses.
The potentialities of monetary and fiscal policies are, we
hope, better understood--although the rise in government expenditures
even in times of advancing prosperity threatens to make it difficult
to be still more expansionary should a serious decline in private
business activity require it.




-5-

In spite of the rise in the international flow of public
and private credit and investment, business abroad appears in
general to be less dependent upon American funds.

The recent

restraint on the outflow of U. S. capital has had little effect on busi¬
ness activity abroad, in contrast to the paralyzing effect of the
cessation of U. S. capital outflows in the late twenties.
While the cold war makes for sources of friction absent
in the twenties, we are no longer suffering from the cancer of repara¬
tions and| war debts.
We have learned the lessons taught by the failure of trade
and exchange restrictions, and of beggar-my-neighbor policies in
general, although the temptation to backslide is ever present.
We have become aware of our responsibility for helping
those less developed countries that seem willing and able to develop
their economies--although the poor countries still are not becoming
rich as fast as the rich countries are becoming richer.
The International Monetary Fund has proved to be a valuable
aid to a better working of the international payments system.
A network of international, regional, and bilateral insti¬
tutions and arrangements has reduced the danger of lack of inter¬
national financial communication.




-6-

And finally, the experience of the twenties has
strengthened the resolution of all responsible leaders, businessmen
and statesmen alike, never again to permit a repetition of the
disasters of the Great Depression,
But while the spirit is willing, the flesh, in the form of
concrete policies, has remained weak.

With the best intentions,

some experts seem resolved to ignore the lessons of the past.
Economic and political scientists still argue about the
factors that converted a stock-exchange crash into the worst
depression in our history.

But on one point they are agreed: the

disastrous impact of the destruction of the international payments
system that followed the British decision to devalue sterling in
September 1931. At that time, sterling was the kingpin of the world
payments system, exactly as the dollar is today.

While changes in

the par values of other peripheral currencies affected mainly or
solely the devaluing countries themselves, the fate of sterling shook
the entire world.
This is not wisdom of hindsight.

Only a few weeks before

the fateful decision was taken, the most eminent economist of the day
stated that "for a country in the special circumstances of Great
3ritain the disadvantages (of devaluation) would greatly outweigh the
advantages" and he concurred with his colleagues in rejecting the idea.
His name was John Maynard Keynes.




-7And soon afterwards, another great British economist,
Lionel Robbins, declared that "no really impartial observer of
world events can do other than regard the abandonment of the Gold
Standard by Great Britain as a catastrophe of the first order of
magnitude."

This was long before the final consequences of that

step had become apparent — the political weakening of the "West which
followed its economic breakdown and which contributed to the success
of the Nazi revolution in Germany, and thus eventually to the out¬
break of the Second World War and to the emergence of Communism
as an imminent threat to world order.
As if neither Keynes, the founder of the anti-classical
school of economics, nor Robbins, the leader of the neo-classical
school, ever had spoken, some Keynesian and neo-classicist
economists--fortunately with little support at home but with encourage¬
ment from a few foreign observers—are urging us to follow the British
example of 1931 and to act once more in a way that would destroy a
payments system based on the fixed gold value of the world' s leading
currency.

In doing so, they not only show that they have not learned

from monetary history; they also impute to our generation even less
wisdom than was shown in the interwar period.




-8-

The British Government in 1931, and the U. S. Adminis¬
tration in 1933, can rightly be accused of underestimating the adverse
international effects of the devaluation of the pound and the dollar.
But at least they had some plausible domestic grounds for their
actions.

They were confronted with a degree of unemployment that

has hardly ever been experienced either before or after.

They were

confronted with disastrously falling prices, which made all fixedinterest obligations an intolerable burden on domestic and international
commerce.

They were confronted with a decline in international

liquidity, which seemed to make recovery impossible.
Neither Keynes nor Robbins have denied that, from a
purely domestic point of view, there was some sense in devaluation.
In the United States of 1933, one worker out of four was unemployed;
industrial production was little more than half of normal; farm prices
had fallen to less than half of their 1929 level; exports and imports
stood at one-third of their 1929 value; capital issues had practically
ceased.

In such a situation, any remedy, however questionable,

seemed better than inaction.
In the 3ritain of 1931, things were not quite as bleak as
in the United States of 1933; but fundamentally, the economic problems
were similar.

Ever since 1925, the British economy had failed to

grow, and by 1931, one out of five workers had become unemployed,
exports--far more important for the British economy than for our




-9own--had declined by nearly one-half, and most observers believed
that over-valuation of the British pound was largely responsible for
all these ills.

Can anybody in good faith find any similarity between

our position of today and our position of 1933, or even the British
position of 1931 ?
In 1931 and 1933, an increase in the price of gold was
recommended in order to raise commodity prices.

Today, a gold

price increase is recommended as a means to provide the monetary
support for world price stability.

In 1931 and 1933, an increase in

the price of gold was recommended in order to combat deflation;
today it is recommended in effect as a means to combat inflation.
In 1931 and 1933, an increase in the price of gold was recommended
as a desperate cure for national ills regardless of its disintegrating
effect on world commerce; today it is recommended as a means to
improve integration of international trade and finance.

Can there

be worse confusion?
True, most advocates of an increase in the price of gold
today would prefer action by some international agency or conference
to unilateral action of individual countries.

But no international

agency or conference could prevent gold hoarders from getting wind¬
fall profits; could prevent those who hold a devalued currency from
suffering corresponding losses; could prevent central banks from




-10-

feeling defrauded if they had trusted in the repeated declarations of
the President of the United States and of the spokesmen of U. S.
monetary authorities and kept their reserves in dollars rather than
in gold.

To this day, the French, Belgian, and Netherlands central

banks have not forgotten that the 1931 devaluation of sterling wiped
out their capital; and much of the antagonism of those countries
against the use of the dollar as an international reserve asset should
be traced to the experience of 1931 rather than to anti-American
feelings or mere adherence to outdated monetary theories.
But most importantly, no international agency or confer¬
ence could prevent a sudden large increase in the gold price from
having inflationary consequences for those countries that hoarded
gold, and deflationary consequences for those that did not.

And the

gold holding countries are precisely those whose economies are least
in need of an inflationary stimulus since they are most prosperous-not prosperous because they are holding gold, but holding gold
because they are prosperous; in contrast, those that do not hold gold
are most in need of further expansion.

Hence the inflationary and

deflationary effects of an increase in the price of gold would be most
inequitably and most uneconomically distributed among nations.
If we were to accept another sort of advice given by some
experts, we might repeat not the mistakes of 1931-33 but those of
earlier years.




We are told that a repetition of the disaster of the

-11-

Great Depression could be averted only, or at least best, by return¬
ing to the principles of the so-called classical gold standard.

Not

only should all settlements in international transactions between
central banks be made in gold; but also the domestic monetary policy
of central banks should be oriented exclusively to the payments
balance, which means to changes in gold reserves.

Whenever gold

flows out, monetary policy should be tightened; whenever it flows
in, it should be eased.
This is not the place to discuss whether this pure form
of gold standard theory has ever been translated into practice.

I

doubt that any central bank has ever completely neglected domestic
considerations in its monetary policy.

And conversely, we do not

need to adhere to an idealized version of the gold standard in order
to agree that considerations of international payments balance need
to play a large role in monetary policy decisions.

But even strict

adherence to gold standard principles would not guarantee inter¬
national payments equilibrium.

As a great American economist,

John H. Williams, put it in 1937:




"For capital movements, the gold standard is not a
reliable corrective mechansim. . . .

With capital the

most volatile item in the balance of payments, it is apt
to dominate and to nullify any corrective effects which
might otherwise result from the gold standard process

-12-

"of adjustment,

. . .It is surely not a coincidence that

most booms and depressions, in the nineteenth century
as well as in the twentieth, had international capital
movements as one of their most prominent features. "
Even countries that advocate a return to gold standard
practices do not practice what they preach.

Gold reserves of some

Continental European countries have been rising strongly and continu¬
ously for many years, and according to the rules, these countries
should follow a clearly expansionary policy.

But in order to offset

inflationary pressures, they have done exactly the opposite—and who
is there to blame a country that wishes to assure domestic financial
stability even at the expense of endangering equilibrium in inter¬
national payments?
But obviously, if we permit one country to violate the
rules of the gold standard in order to avert domestic inflation, we
must also permit another country to violate those rules in order to
avert domestic deflation and unemployment.

In other words, we must

agree that a country may be justified in avoiding or at least modifying
a tightening of monetary policy even though its gold reserves are
declining, if otherwise it were to risk precipitating or magnifying a
business recession.




-13-

True, this deviation from gold-standard rules could be
carried too far.

Domestic developments might be taken as a pre¬

text to avoid an unpopular monetary move, although the payments
situation would seem to demand it and although the action would be
unlikely to be damaging to the domestic economy. But the possibility
of abuse and error is inherent in all human decision, and just as no
sane observer would ascribe infallibility to the decisions of central
bankers, neither should he ascribe infallibility to a set of rules.

Few

experts today would want to argue that it was right for the German
Reichsbank in 1931, in the middle of the greatest depression that ever
hit Germany, to follow the gold standard rules by raising its discount
rate to 7 per cent merely in order to stem an outflow of gold; or that
it was right for our own Federal Reserve to take similar restrictive
action,

for the same reason, in the fall of 1931.
And just as the success of monetary policy cannot be

guaranteed by an abdication of discretion in favor of preconceived
gold-standard rules, it cannot be guaranteed by following the advice of
those who would shift the focus of policy from national agencies to an
international institution.

Surely, international cooperation should be

encouraged and improved whenever possible.

And the functions of

the International Monetary Fund might well be enlarged so as to re¬
inforce its ability to act as an international lender of last resort and
as an arbiter of international good behavior.




-14But no institutional change can exclude the possibility
of conflicts between national and international interests in specific
circumstances.

Moreover, there is no reason to believe that such

conflicts would necessarily be resolved more wisely, more
speedily, and with less rancor and dissent if they were fought out
in the governing body of some supra-national bank of issue rather
than by discussion and negotiation among national authorities.
It is true that such discussion and negotiation may prove
fruitless and that inconsistent decisions may be taken on the
national level.

But similarly, lack of consensus within a supra¬

national agency may result in a paralysis of its functions, and the
effects of such paralysis could well be worse than those of inconsistent
national actions.
If then we doubt the wisdom of the three most fashionable
recent proposals--to increase the dollar price of gold, to return to
pure gold-standard principles, or to delegate monetary policy to an
international agency--what should be our position?

And what is the

outlook for solving present and future difficulties in international
monetary relations, and thus for avoiding a repetition of the disasters
of 1929-33?
In my judgment, it is less fruitful to look for institutional
changes or for a semi-automatic mechanism that would guarantee
perennial prosperity than to draw from interwar experience some
simple lessons that could save us from repeating our worst mistakes.




-15-

First, most observers agree that to a large extent the
disaster of 1929-33 was a consequence of maladjustments born of
the boom of the twenties.

Hence, we must continuously be on the

alert to prevent a recurrence of maladjustments--even at the risk
of being falsely accused of failing to realize the benefits of unbounded
expansion.

Actually, those of us who warn against speculative and

inflationary dangers should return the charge:

our common goals

of maximum production, employment, and purchasing power can be
realized only if we are willing and able to prevent orderly expansion
from turning into disorderly boom.
Second, most observers agree that the severity of the
Great Depression was largely due to the absence of prompt anti¬
recession measures.

In part, the necessary tools for this were not

then available nor were their potentialities fully understood.

Today

it is easy to understand where observers went wrong 35 years ago.
3ut it is less easy to avoid a repetition of the same mistake; we
always prefer to believe what we want to be true rather than what
we should know to be true.
vigilance.

Here again, we need most of all eternal

But we must also be ready to admit errors in past judg¬

ments and forecasts, and have the courage to express dissenting
even though unpopular views, and to advocate necessary remedies.




-16-

Third, and most importantly, most observers agree that
the severity of the Great Depression was due largely to the lack of
understanding of the international implications of national events
and policies.

Even today, we are more apt to judge and condemn the

worldwide implications of nationalistic actions taken by others than
to apply the same criteria to our own decisions.
Recognition of the close ties among the individual
economies of the free world leads to recognition of the need to main¬
tain freedom of international commerce,

This means not only that

we must avoid the direct controls of trade and exchange that were
characteristic of the time of the Great Depression.

It means also

that we must avoid any impairment of the value and status of the
dollar, which today acts--just as sterling did until its devaluation in
1931--as a universal means of international payment between central
banks as well as among individual merchants, bankers, and investors.
If the dollar is to continue to play its role in international
commerce, world confidence in its stability must be fully maintained;
the world must be convinced that we are resolved to eliminate the
long-persistent deficit in our balance of international payments.

The

measures taken in accordance with the President's program of
February 10, 1965, have so far been highly successful.

But some of

these measures are of a temporary character, and these include the
efforts of the financial community to restrain voluntarily the expansion




-17-

of credit to foreigners.

We should not permit the initial success of

these efforts to blind us against the need of permanent cure.
Some observers believe that our responsibility for main¬
taining the international function of the dollar puts an intolerably
heavy burden on our monetary policy; that this responsibility prevents
us from taking monetary measures

which might be considered

priate for solving domestic problems.
view.

appro-

I happen to disagree with that

I believe that the interests of our national economy are in

harmony with those of the international community.

A stable dollar

is indeed the keystone of international trade and finance; but it is also,
in my judgment, the keystone of economic growth and prosperity at
home.
Yet even if I were wrong in this judgment, and if indeed
an occasion arose when we could preserve the international role of
the dollar only at the expense of modifying our favored domestic
policies--even then we would need to pay attention to the international
repercussions of our actions.

We must consider these international

effects not because of devotion to the ideal of human brotherhood, not
because we value the well-being of our neighbors more than our own.
We must do so because any harm that would come to international
commerce and hence to the rest of the world as a result of the dis¬
placement of the dollar would fall back on our own heads.




In the

-18-

present stage of economic development we could not preserve our own
prosperity if the rest of the world were caught in the web of depression.
Recognition of this inter-dependence gave rise to the Marshall Plan-in my judgment the greatest achievement of our postwar economic
policy.
It should not have taken the Great Depression to bring
these simple truths home to us.

Today, as we approach the goal of

the "Great Society11--to make each of our citizens a self-reliant and
productive member of a healthy and progressive economic system—we
can disregard these truths even less than we could a generation ago.
By heeding them instead, we will have a good chance to avoid another
such disaster.

If monetary history were to repeat itself, it would be

nobody's fault but our own.