View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Some Aspects of Structural Unemployment
by Hurray Wernick
Much of the recent controversy relating to the causes of
unemployment has largely been concerned with definitions, measurements and the time periods to be used in evaluating the impact of
structural, frictional, and cyclical factors on changes in unemployment. A major difficulty and one which has resulted in differences of
opinion is the inadequacy of the current labor force statistical series
as a measure of the amount and changes in structural unemployment.
While the available data dp provide substantial information on trends,
levels, characteristics of the employed and unemployed, they do not
directly indicate the causes or forces which make for unemployment.
Also, as has been well documented in the Bureau of Labor
Statistics recent study on Terminology, Measurement and Analysis of
Unemployment, presented to the Subcommittee on Economic Statistics
of the Joint Economic Committee, the specific meaning of structural
unemployment is extremely vague and has a variety of definitions.
At times, structural unemployment has been identified with long-term
unemployment; some experts have identified it with technological
change, others with shifts in consumer demands, international competition, or changes in the composition of the labor force. It is little
wonder, with uncertainty as to definitions and inadequate data to
measure these definitions, that differences in judgment as to the
magnitude of structural unemployment have occurred among those who
are concerned with the policies required to alleviate unemployment.
(Statement of Chairman Wm. McC. Martin, for the Joint Economic Comm.
in the Congressional Record of May 10, 1962, p.7620-7622.)




-2-

Fortunately, however, there i s more agreement and less
dispute at the policy level.

"Where misunderstandings have arisen

they have usually been due to a tendency to approach the problems of
unemployment from different

starting

points which often are thought

to lead to clear-cut alternative policy

choices.

However, when the

various approaches are examined in this complex area there are fewer
choices than appeared to be the case at first glance.

For instance,

i t has frequently been emphasized that the problem of increasing the
mobility of labor by a better functioning of the labor market could be
handled more easily under conditions of expanded over-all activity.
This i s undoubtedly true.

The Board of Governors of the Federal

Reserve System i s and has been pursuing a monetary policy which has
as one of i t s major aims the maximum utilisation of our growing
industrial and manpower resources.
The opposite side of the coin also has validity.

I t would,

under current conditions, be much easier to achieve maximum employment
with a relatively stable price level, if we were able t o remove
limitations which handicap the ready flow of the unemployed worker
into useful job opportunities.

Such action would unquestionably help

prevent inflationary pressures developing short of our desired goals.
The threat of inflation and the inadequacy of broad monetary and
fiscal policies to curtail unemployment which i s selective or structural
in nature have been major obstacles to the reduction of persistent
unemployment.




-3Measures continue to be required to reshape and increase
the mobility of certain groups in the labor force. These conclusions
are not new but have been frequently stated by a large majority of
those in labor, management and Government who have expressed opinions
on this subject in recent months.*

(See attachment)

If we take the appropriate measures based on the broad
consensus which now exists on policies to be directed toward the
elimination of the causes of persistent unemployment, rather than
to overplay differences of emphasis of measurements and definitions,
we could well be on our way toward reaching our goals of full employment and price stability simultaneously.
Evidence of substantial structural shifts in occupations
and industries in recent years has been extensively reported to the
Joint Economic Committee, and many other committees of Congress,
Mr. Ewan Clague, the Commissioner of Labor Statistics, only recently,
and in considerable detail, gave testimony to the Subcommittee on
Economic Statistics on December 18, 196l, to the effect that "In
recent years there has been a dramatic shift in the pattern of employment in the United States." These shifts have resulted in a substantial
rise in persistent unemployment in the postwar period evident in both
good and bad times.
Of course, changes in the structure of industry and occupations
are nothing new.

What is new in the recent situation is the large

absolute decline in employment since 1953 of almost 3 million industrial
blue-collar workers; while employment in services, trade and Government,




-4mostly white-collar groups, rose by 7 million.

There has not been

as large and as absolute a displacement of workers in industrial
employment or a shift away from blue-collar employment at any other
periods of our history when over-all employment was rising.
Mining and railroad employment began to decline soon after
the end of World War I I and in manufacturing industries the decline
became evident after 1953.

By early 1962 production worker employment

had declined by over 2 million workers or one-sixth although manufacturing output rose about one-fifth.
Immediately after the Korean h o s t i l i t i e s i t was thought that
the decline in factory employment was temporary and mainly due to the
curtailment in defense industries.

There was, therefore, l i t t l e

general concern in the sharp expansionary period in 1955 and 1956
when factory worker employment failed to return to the previous
postwar highs of 1953 and unemployment among workers from these
industries increased.

Nonindustrial employment was rising very rapidly,

and was accompanied by one of the sharpest increases in the civilian
labor force for a two-year span on record, as workers entered the
labor market to f i l l the new white-collar job opportunities.

But

when in the recovery period of 1959 and 1960, the unemployment rate
did not go below 5 per cent and industrial employment again f e l l below
prerecession 1957 levels, there was more widespread recognition and
concern of the significance of the selective declines in employment
which were so heavily concentrated among certain semiskilled and
unskilled occupations in an exceedingly important sector of the economy.




It was the judgment of many informed observers the forces making
for higher unemployment could not be wholly explained by an insufficiency of aggregate demand.

In 1959, consumer demands were

high and the economy was being excessively stimulated, by a rapid
run-up in inventories before the steel strike, and again in early
1960 when inventories were being replenished.
The employment patterns of recession and recovery obvious
since 1953 seem to be repeating themselves again this year.

In

February 1962, although industrial production and GNP were at about
the highest levels in history, following a vigorous recovery, there
were 600,000 fewer factory workers employed than when the recession
began in the spring of 1960.
A critical aspect in measuring the magnitude of structural
unemployment is to know what has happened, on net, to the over 2 million
production workers who were displaced in manufacturing activities
between 1953 and 1962. This is impossible to answer accurately at
present because our current statistics primarily give us a crosssectional view of the labor force and unemployment at a given point
in time. We would know much more about the various causes of unemployment if we were able to trace the flow of displaced workers as they
moved into other jobs, unemployment, or outside the labor force. This
can now be done only in a very indirect way.
The decline in industrial employment, as best we can tell,
has resulted in a substantial rise in unemployment among experienced
workers who were previously employed in factories and related activities




-6as well as some withdrawal from the labor force.

Because of their

specialised s k i l l s , previous experience, and geographical location,
only a small proportion of these workers have been readily absorbed
into the expanding industries.

The available s t a t i s t i c s do show that

characteristics and employability of workers released from the declining
industries is substantially different from the new entrants and reentrants into the labor market.

They have been mainly adult males,

a high proportion of whom are heads of families and were formerly
employed in semiskilled occupations.

Once unemployed their spells of

unemployment tend to be relatively long.
Secretary of Labor Goldberg, in his testimony before the
Joint Economic Committee on January 31, 1962, pointed out that the
long-term unemployed were concentrated in several groups out of
proportion to their number in the labor force.

In 1961 the long-term

unemployed, those unemployed 15 weeks or more, averaged 1.5 million
and was the largest number in over 2 decades.

The problem involves,

he testified:
"1.

Men 45 years of age and over who represented 1/3 of

the very long-term unemployed, even though they accounted for only
1/4 of the total labor force.
"2.

Workers from durable goods industries accounted for

14% of the labor force and 25% of the long-term unemployed.
"3.

Negroes accounted for 24% of persons jobless for over

six months and only 11% of the civilian labor force.




"4. Semiskilled operators and unskilled laborers represented
45% of the very long-term unemployed compared to only 24% of the labor
force.

In contrast, professional workers made up less than 3% of the

very long-term unemployed even though they account for 11% of the
labor force.
"5.

Persons with no previous work experience, who accounted

for less than 1% of the civilian labor force, made up 9% of the
persons looking for work for over six months. These were chiefly
young workers in search of their first job."
The growth in the number of workers reporting long duration
of unemployment, and the fact that the hardest hit have been unskilled
and semiskilled males in the middle age groups, indicated by the
Secretary of Labor, confirm other findings that those who were displaced
because of structural factors have had a more difficult time in
adjusting to new employment opportunities. They have contributed
significantly to the rising levels of long-term unemployment in recent
years.

Their job needs as heads of families and their limitations in

making a rapid transition to new skills or different geographical areas
has resulted in real hardship. Measures to reduce unemployment in
these groups is especially urgent.
There has also been an increase in recent years in unemployment
of workers who report that their last job was in nonindustrial activities.
In part this is a statistical classification problem.
lifelong

A worker whose

or major experience has been in a declining industry will,

nevertheless, be classified as unemployed in, say, trades and services




-8if that was the industry in which he held his last job, even if i t
were only of short duration or part-time job.
The greatest cause of unemployment, aside from layoffs in
declining industries, appears to have been the rapid rise in the
number of new entrants or re-entrants into the labor force in recent
years.

These unemployed are more diffuse in origin and not as

concentrated geographically.

An important distinction is that the

characteristics of these unemployed in respect to age, sex, s k i l l ,
educational background and duration of unemployment i s substantially
different from those whose loss of jobs can be related to structural
factors.

The unemployed who are associated with the expanding industries

tend to consist mainly of secondary workers; mainly youths and married
women, many of whom supplement family income.

They may have had some

work experience but their spells of unemployment are relatively short.
If they fail to find jobs, they are likely to withdraw from the labor
market.

They almost always seek work in nonindustrial activities

such as trade or services which employ persons with entirely different
occupational and demographic characteristics than those of the laidoff factory workers.
Recent analysis of labor force movements indicate there are
large potential resources of manpower now classified outside the labor
force.

Knowledge of the complex relationships between changes in

output, labor force and unemployment are uncertain.

I t i s entirely

possible, under present labor market conditions, for any increase in
demand for labor, more than cyclical in nature, to be largely met by a




-9flow of persons into the labor force rather than in a reduction in
high levels of persistent unemployment. It is therefore a mistake
to think there are simple or precise solutions of our persistent
unemployment problems.
Our best judgment continues to be that structural unemployment
has increased over the last decade as reflected in the sharp decline in
industrial employment and an increase in persistent unemployment which
has not been responsive to general monetary and fiscal measures even
during periods of high level of activity and rising prices.




* The Report of the Commission on Money and Credit, Prentice-Hall, Inc.,

1961, pp. 27, 29-30, 35.
"Despite the wealth of detail available on the characteristics
of the unemployed, there are no reliable ways of determining from current
figures how many are unemployed as a result of which cause. . .
"What is the prospect for future levels of unemployment?
Unfortunately the trend of unemployment has not been improving. Not
only were unemployment rates higher in 1959 and early 1960 than in
earlier recovery periods, but the proportion of long-duration unemployment has been higher. This long-duration unemployment continues to be
serious in depressed areas, and it has become more widespread. Technological displacement of workers in manufacturing and agriculture has
been heavy, and the total number of jobs in those sectors as a percentage
of total employment has been decreasing,
"Two factors of special importance may make more difficult
the achievement of low-level unemployment in the decade ahead. First,
the expected rate of growth in the labor force increases sharply in
the sixties, compared to the fifties, as the population bulge reaches
the employable age. Many more jobs per year will be required to keep
the unemployment rate low. Second, the pace of technological change,
typified by the term automation, shows no sign of abating; on the
contrary it may be increasing. Whether technological change will
create new job opportunities as rapidly as it displaces other workers
is not predictable. In addition, there are the problems of obsolete
skills of some workers and resistances to labor mobility flowing
from such things as nontransferable pensions and labor union restrictions on entry into some occupations,
"The employment problem ahead is formidable. It calls for
effective use of monetary, credit, and fiscal policies to induce adequate
levels of demand and to stimulate economic growth. It also requires
new and imaginative programs to deal directly with structural unemployment—programs for distressed areas, education and training of new and
displaced workers, an improved job information service. Action is also
needed to ease the burdens of the technologically, unemployed lest
restrictive work practices develop which will inhibit productivity gains.
"Measures which improve the efficiency of labor will also
contribute to growth. Incentives for advancement in income and job
responsibility, effective employment services, retraining programs for
workers displaced by technological change, programs to help move
workers from depressed areas and industries into others, policies to
move marginal farm workers into more productive nonfarm employment,
elimination of redundant workers—all are measures that have favorable
effects upon the growth rate."




-2President's Advisory Committee on Labor-Management Policy, January 11,
1962, pp. 2-3.
"While advancing technology has given rise to new industries
and jobs, it has also resulted in employee displacement; the fact
that new work opportunities are eventually created is no comfort or
help to the displaced individual who cannot, for one reason or another,
secure comparable or any employment. • . .
"Regarding technological advance in unemployment, it is
clear that unemployment has resulted from displacement due to automation
and technology. It is impossible, with presently available data, to
isolate that portion of present unemployment resulting from these
causes. Whether such displacement will be short-run depends to a
considerable extent on our ability to anticipate and plan for programs
involving technological change and to make better use of various
mechanisms for retraining and relocating workers who find themselves
unneeded in their former occupations."
Ewan Clague, Commissioner of Labor Statistics, Testimony before the
Subcommittee on Economic Statistics, Joint Economic Committee,
December 8, 1961.
"Some analysts believe that the current high rate of
unemployment is entirely a junction of inadequate aggregate demand.
This analysis discounts the apparent uptrend in unemployment rates
at the end of World War II to about 1956 and places all the emphasis
on the rise in unemployment that has occurred in the last 4 years. . .
"The other point of view is that structural changes which
have taken place in recent years have had some influence in causing
higher rates of unemployment. In my judgment, this is a factor which
cannot be ignored."
Arthur J. Goldberg, Secretary of Labor, Testimony before Joint Economic
Committee, January 31, 1962.
"Again, to say that we can put all of our people to work in
useful and satisfying activities only or mainly by upsetting our
monetary system, or by massive intervention of the government into
the millions of free decisions which are the basic essence of our
economic system—to say these things is to demonstrate a lack of
understanding of our dynamic system. We do not advocate growth for
growth's sake, nor can we advocate stability for stability's sake.
We need both. . . . "




-3Stanley Ruttenberg, Research Director, AFL-CIO. Paper presented at
the Annual Meetings of the American S t a t i s t i c a l Association,
December 29, 1961.
levels of
people on
aggregate
i t i s not

"It i s unfortunate that the problem of our persistent high
unemployment has been framed by some very well-intentioned
an 'either-or' basis—that i s , that our problem i s one of
demand rather than structural unemployment. In my view,
'either-or'; i t i s both.

"To achieve full employment we must simultaneously increase
aggregate demand and address ourselves to the structural problems.
Neither one alone will attain our objective in the years immediately
ahead."