View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL DEPOSI T I NSURANCE CORPORATI ON,

OFFICE

QF

THE

C H A I R M A N

HOLD FOR RELEASE UNTIL 2 P.M.
March 26 , 1983




(EST)

WHOSE BANK IS IT, ANYHOW?

An address by

li
(y

William M. Isaac, Chairman
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
Washington, D.C.

presented to the

Independent Bankers Association
of America

San Diego*
x March 26, 1983

Washington, 0. C. 20429

Good morning.
It is a real pleasure to have this
opportunity to address so many community bankers from
around the nation.
The banking industry is in the news on almost a daily
basis: we hear about entry into the business by new com­
petitors, deposit interest rate deregulation, volatile
interest rates, a troubled worldwide economy, bank failures,
problem banks, proposals for expanded powers, new disclosure
requirements, pressures for reforms in the regulatory and
deposit insurance systems, foreign loans, and geographic
restraints.
I will touch on many of these subjects today,
beginning with the condition of the banking system and then
turning to a number of regulatory reform issues.
m

THE c o n d i t i o n o f t h e b a n k i n g s y s t e m

It is no secret that we have experienced a significant
increase in the number of problem banks and bank failures
during the past year or so. Two points should be empha­
sized:
a) the problems have been foreseen and b) they have
been and will continue to be handled in a manner that
maintains public confidence in the system.
We have experienced four successive years of economic
stagnation and extraordinarily high and volatile interest
rates, following more than a decade of rampant inflation.
Even in the best of times, banks will suffer loan losses if
they are aggressively meeting the credit needs of their
communities.
However, one of the insidious effects of
inflation is that marginal borrowers or marginal projects
obtain financing on the assumption that continuing inflation
will make them viable.
These borrowers and projects are the
first and hardest hit by high interest rates and an economic
slowdown.
During 1981 we handled 10 bank failures, and at the end
of that year we had 220 banks on our problem bank or watch
list.
Early in 1982 I asked our regional directors to
forecast the number of banks that would fail in their
regions during 1982 and to estimate the number of problem
banks we would have by the end of the year. They forecast
between 40 and 50 failures; we actually experienced 42.
They estimated we would have 375 banks on our problem list
by year-end; we actually had 370. The point is, while we
cannot forecast each and every failure, we have a pretty
good feel for the magnitude of the problems and are able to
prepare ourselves to deal with them in an orderly way.
So far this year there have been 10 bank failures, and
there are currently about 425 banks on our problem list. Wre
expect the number of problem banks to continue to grow
throughout the year and the failure rate to equal or exceed
last year’s total.




Despite the extraordinary cost of handling recent bank
failures -- about a billion dollars in each of the past two
years -- the deposit insurance fund continues to grow and is
stronger than ever.
At the beginning of 1981, the fund
totalled $11 billion; today it exceeds $14 billion, after
absorbing the full impact of over 60 failures.
Our revenue
this year from assessments and interest on our investments
will approach $3 billion.
In sum, the banking system is experiencing problems,
but none that have not been expected or cannot be managed.
Our personnel have faced long hours and many sleepless
nights, but the safety net has held; stability has been
maintained.
II.

REGULATORY AND INSURANCE REFORMS

The important question is where do we go from here -what changes do we need to make in our systems of regulation
and insurance to maintain a strong, profitable and stable
banking system in the years and decades ahead? We are
convinced that substantial reforms are badly needed.
From the 1930s through most of the 1960s, competition
in the financial services field was tightly controlled.
Price competition was restricted by Regulation Q. Product
competition was curtailed by limiting the asset powers and
permissible activities of banks and other intermediaries.
Entry into the business was carefully regulated, as was
expansion.
It was rare for a bank to encounter difficulty;
only a half dozen or so banks failed each year, almost
always due to fraud or insider abuse.
You do not need anyone to tell you this has all changed.
The current economic climate is anything but benign; banks
and borrowers can no longer count on economic expansion,
inflation or stable interest rates.
Deposit interest rate
controls have been almost completely dismantled in response
to market pressures.
Product distinctions among banks, S§Ls
and other intermediaries are barely discernible.
Restric­
tions on entry and expansion have been eased.
The new environment offers exciting opportunities for
well-managed banks of all sizes, particularly as we expand
the range of permissible activities in such areas as in­
surance, real estate, securities, data processing and
travel services.
At the same time, it presents many
challenges for our regulatory system.
How, in the absence of rigid, government -imposed
restrictions on competition, do we control destructive
competition and excessive risk-taking? How do we insure




that deposits flow to the vast majority- of banks that are
prudently operated rather than to the marginal banks which
are willing to make the highest risk loans and pay the
highest rates for deposits?
We have two options. We can adopt countless new laws
and regulations to govern every aspect of your operations
and hire thousands of additional examiners to monitor and
enforce compliance.
Or, we can seek ways to increase
marketplace discipline.
The FDIC clearly prefers to allow the marketplace to
function to the maximum possible extent. We are flatly
opposed to unnecessary regulations.
A.
Disclosure. For the marketplace to perform its
disciplinary function, it must have information.
This is
the reason we have decided to make public the new call
report data on interest-rate sensitivity and nonperforming
loans and why we are considering additional disclosures
covering such matters as insider-lending practices and
enforcement actions.
We are attempting to turn the spotlight on marginal,
high-risk banks.
We believe this will deter unsound banking
practices and destructive competition.
If problems nonethe­
less arise, troubled banks will either correct them promptly
or will fail more quickly, causing less damage.
It may seem harsh, but we cannot coddle marginal
banks.
To do so would undermine the vast majority of banks
that are operating prudently by making sound loans, main­
taining adequate capital ratios and paying reasonable rates
for their deposits.
That we will not do.
B.
Large Depositor Risk Sharing. The other ingredient
essential to instilling marketplace discipline is the risk
of loss. Although the explicit coverage under our deposit
insurance system is limited to $100,000, in practice we have
for years been providing implicit 100V coverage for de­
positors and other creditors at most banks, particularly the
larger ones.
This has resulted from our practice of merging failed
banks into other banks.
Under current law, we are required
to make all general creditors whole when we arrange a merger
(or ’’purchase and assumption transaction") .
We have a strong preference for handling bank failures
through mergers; it is ordinarily the least expensive and
least disruptive method.
We nevertheless abhor the side




4
effect of providing 1001 deposit insurance coverage; we are
convinced it has eroded marketplace discipline and provided
larger banks a substantial competitive advantage.
Prior to the Penn Square Bank failure, it was generally
believed the FDIC would never pay off depositors in a bank
larger than $100 million.
That episode has obviously
caused people to raise their estimate of the size limit, but
most still believe there is a limit beyond which we will not
go.
As a practical matter, they may be right.
It is not,
as some people think, a matter of money.
The percentage of
insured deposits in most large banks is comparatively modest
and paying them off would not be prohibitively expensive.
The problem is that billions of dollars of uninsured funds
would be tied up for years in a bankruptcy proceeding,
possibly causing severe repercussions throughout the economy.
We are currently searching for solutions to this
dilemma.
One possible approach may be to modify the deposit
insurance system to provide 100% coverage for the first
$100,000 in deposits and a smaller percentage -- say 75% -for all deposits over $100,000.
This would be the coverage
whether we paid off depositors or arranged a merger.
Another possibility would be to maintain the insurance
limit at $100,000 and, at the time of failure, pay that
amount, plus an amount equal to the estimated ultimate
recovery on the uninsured portion.
Again, this could be
accomplished by a direct payoff or by transfer of the de­
posits to another bank.
Either approach would solve a number of problems.
We
could continue to arrange mergers for failed banks.
Enough
of the deposits would be made immediately available to
minimize the economic repercussions, but there would be some
risk of loss; we would not provide a complete bailout for
the largest creditors.
Either proposal would eliminate the
competitive inequity between large and small banks and
provide customers an incentive to select the soundest
institutions, not just the largest ones or the ones that pay
the highest interest rates.
C.
Regulatory System.
In addition to this and other
possible reforms in' the insurance system, such as riskrelated premiums, some fundamental changes in our regulatory
system must also be considered.
We believe the current
regulatory system is inefficient and inequitable.
Why, for example, should state banks be burdened by two
layers of regulation while national banks operate with one
layer? How can we continue to justify an entirely different




5
regulatory system for S$Ls now that they have commercial
lending and transaction account authorities? Why should
mergers be subject to antitrust review by both the banking '
agencies and the Justice Department? Why should the banking
agencies enforce the securities laws with respect to banks
when the SEC has responsibility for bank holding companies
and other businesses? Why should the banking agencies
enforce Truth-in-Lending and other consumer laws with
respect to banks, while the FTC oversees nonbank firms?
Does it make any sense to have a parent bank holding company
examined and regulated by the Federal Reserve when the lead
bank is examined and regulated by a different agency? How
can we rationalize different insurance agencies for banks
and S§Ls? How can we justify disparate capital adequacy
standards for S$Ls and banks and for banks of different
sizes? Why should S§Ls and banks operate under different
reporting and disclosure rules? Why should we permit a re­
tailer or a steel company to own a federally-insured S§L
with banking powers while' prohibiting a bank from owning a
steel company or a retailer? Why is it permissible for a
securities firm to own a bank, but not the reverse?
The short answer to these and many other similar
questions is that the current regulatory system is not
rational.
All of the issues I have just raised are in­
extricably intertwined and should be addressed through
comprehensive reform.
Intellectually, this is not nearly as
complicated as it might appear at first blush.
First, we need to redefine the term "bank" and re­
consider the range of activities in which it or its affiliates
may engage.
It may be appropriate to define a bank as any
institution which offers either transaction accounts or any
type of federally-insured deposit.
In our opinion, a bank
should be permitted to engage, either directly or through a
subsidiary, in the full-range of financial services, includ­
ing much broader authority than at present in securities,
real estate, travel agency, insurance and data processing
activities.
It follows that any company engaged in such
activities should be permitted to own or affiliate with a
bank and that any company engaged in impermissible activities
should not.
Nonconforming companies already affiliated with
banks or S$Ls could be given 10 years to either conform or
divest.
Second, the various financial agencies at the federal
level should be consolidated and all regulation should be
organized along functional lines. To be specific, the
regulatory functions of the Federal Home Loan Bank Board,
the Federal Reserve, and the Comptroller of the Currency
should be consolidated into an independent agency headed by




6
a board.
That agency would license and regulate all federallychartered banks and S$Ls and their holding companies.
State-chartered institutions would be licensed and regulated
by their state authority, preserving our dual banking system.
Under this concept, the FDIC would remain as a separate,
independent agency with insurance responsibilities for all
state- and federally-chartered banks and S§Ls.
It would
have the right to examine and take enforcement actions
against any insured institution or its affiliates.
It would
focus its examinations on problem and near-problem institutions
and merely spot check the others.
The FDIC would not be
concerned with branch applications and other types of
regulatory activities.
Some bankers object to the merger of the FDIC and FSLIC
insurance funds because they fear that the cost of resolving
some of the problems in the S$L industry will reduce the
assessment rebates available to banks.
This objection can
be easily met by computing the rebates on a separate basis
for a few years after the merger.
Finally, securities regulation with respect to banks,
S$Ls and holding companies would reside exclusively in the
SEC. Antitrust enforcement would reside exclusively in the
Justice Department, and consumer compliance matters would
reside exclusively in the FTC.
III. CONCLUSION
I have covered a lot of ground today -- perhaps too
much.
To deal with so many major topics in a speech of
reasonable length, I have had to simplify some of the issues
and abbreviate the discussion of our positions on them.
My objective today has not been to convince you that
our insurance and regulatory systems ought to be changed in
precisely the manner I have outlined.
Rather, I hope I have
persuaded you that the systems are inadequate and inequi­
table and that you should actively support major reforms.
All of the issues I have outlined today are under
serious consideration.
The FDIC will soon submit a report
to Congress on the insurance questions.
The Treasury will
likely propose in the not-too-distant future its ideas for
expanded powers for banks or bank affiliates.
The Vice
President's Task Group is reviewing a number of options for
reform or restructuring of the regulatory agencies.
The
Senate Banking Committee plans to conduct hearings this
spring covering all of these subjects.




If we have the wisdom and political courage to tackle
these issues, I believe we can look forward to a strong,
profitable and responsive financial system.
It will be a
system in which well-managed institutions of all sizes will
be able to compete on an equal footing and prosper.
Some people believe we should maintain essentially the
current regulatory structure and eschew increased market
discipline.
Pursuit of this course will inevitably lead to
more and more regulations and bureaucracy.
The largest
institutions will continue to grow larger simply because
they are big. The unregulated will thrive at the expense of
the regulated.
The FDIC is firmly committed to the maintenance of a
strong, dynamic banking system under private ownership and
control.
We believe that advocates of government restric­
tions and controls must be made to bear the burden of proof
that they are necessary.
The decisions we make on these subjects over the
months and years ahead will,have profound effects on the
financial system for decades to come.
The battle lines are
being drawn.
Simply put, the issue is who will control the
destiny of your banks:
you or the government?