View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
2:45 P.M.(Tokyo time); 12:45 A.M. (E.S.T)
April 22, 1986

Remarks by
Wayne D. Angel1
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Chicago Board of Trade's
International Economic Outlook Symposium
Tokyo, Japan
April 22, 1986

During the last few months we have seen some dramatic
developments in the international oil market.

Spot market prices have

plunged since reaching their December peak of nearly $30 per barrel for
West Texas intermediate crude oil.
than half the December peak.

Last week, the spot price was less

Contract prices have followed suit,

although somewhat less sharply.

There is, of course, no certainty about

how long oil prices will remain at their present levels, but it is
useful, I think, to examine the outlook for the world economy assuming
the price of oil remains more-or-less unchanged from current levels for
the next year or two.
This examination must be placed in the context of other
important developments in the world economy during the past few years.
One of these developments that we all find most heartening is the
progress that has been made in bringing down price inflation rates in
the major industrial countries.

The weighted average inflation rate in

all the industrial countries as a group is now running at about
3 percent; just a few years ago -- in 1981 —

it was some 9 percent.

The U.S. inflation rate is now less than 3 percent.

Inflation rates in

Germany and Japan are now near zero, with the underlying rates —
abstracting from one-time price level effects caused by the dollar's
depreciation and the oil price drop —

also very low.

Another feature of the world economic environment is the
strengthening of fiscal positions attained over the past few years in
several industrial countries, particularly Japan and Germany.

The

general government fiscal deficit as a percentage of GNP is on the order
of 1 percent in these two key countries; on a "structural" or full
employment basis these balances are almost surely in surplus.

As is

-

2

-

widely recognized, the U.S. fiscal situation is not as strong as that in
Japan and Germany, with the actual U.S. deficit on a comparable basis
equal to about 3 - 3-1/2 percent of GNP.

However, some progress toward

fiscal balance has been already registered in the United States, and the
trends —

particularly in light of the Gramm-Rudman-Hoilings Act —

appear to indicate that further substantial progress can be expected.
Nominal interest rates in the major industrial countries have
declined.

Between March 1985 and last month, U.S. short-term interest

rates fell some 200 basis points; broadly similar declines were recorded
in most of the major industrial countries.

Long-term interest rates have

fallen as well, with the declines -- about 400 basis points in some
cases —
to

in U.S. rates being particularly dramatic.

These declines seem

reflect economic fundamentals like lower inflation and inflation

expectations and a perception of a change in U.S. fiscal trends rather
than overly expansionary monetary policies.
Another positive development, of course, is the ongoing recovery
in world economic activity.

The U.S. recovery, now in its fourth year,

seems set to continue for the foreseeable future.

Europe appears to have

embarked on renewed economic growth, although in some countries the pace
of expected activity still may not be sufficient to lower their
exceptionally high unemployment rates.

In Japan, policymakers are taking

some steps to encourage domestic sources of economic strength to replace
the diminishing external stimulus expected as a result of the yen's
appreciation.
All is not rosy, however.

The fiscal and external imbalances

in the U.S. economy, although on improving trends, are still large.

The

-

3

-

United States' new position as a net international debtor will make it
more difficult to achieve current account balance or surplus since the
services account has been weakened by the accumulated effects of past
foreign investment in the United States.

The U.S. current account

deficit is not the only disturbing external imbalance in the industrial
world, however.

Of particular concern are the substantial and growing

current account surpluses being recorded by Japan and Germany.

Another

concern is the high unemployment rates prevailing in many of the
industrial countries, especially Germany.

The final problem facing the

international community that I want to highlight is the debt-servicing
difficulties of many key developing countries.
The first oil price shock
It is useful to look back at the first oil price shock of the
early 1970s.

At that time, after the first big increase in oil prices,

questions were raised about the import capacity of major oil producers
and the ability of the international financial system to intermediate
large flows of savings from oil producers to ultimate investors.

As a

matter of fact, the system worked better than the pessimists expected,
although not without a world recession, a marked slowing of subsequent
industrial country growth, and perhaps too much reliance on bank
intermediation of capital flows to developing countries.

After a while,

oil exporters showed a remarkable ability to consume imports.

Oil

producers' savings were channeled to industrial countries and, mostly
indirectly, to developing countries in order to finance investment and
consumption.
shock —

Moreover, one of the apparent after-effects of the oil

the slowing of industrial country growth even after the initial

-

recession —

4

-

probably also reflected other structural problems as much

as the new, much higher, world oil prices.

Another crucial element in

the reaction of the world economy to the shock was the supply and demand
response -- delayed in some countries by price controls on petroleum and
petroleum products —

to the new relative price of oil.

Eventually, as

a result of the new market prices, new sources of oil were discovered
and developed all over the globe and conservation efforts over time
economized on the use of petroleum products.
Today we are faced with the opposite of the situation that we
faced in the early 1970s —

a major decline in the price of oil.

questions that must be answered are equally challenging.

The

In particular,

what can we expect from the international "recycling" process in
response to the decline in oil prices?

Will everything just "work in

reverse" as an econometric model might suggest?

That is,

Will industrial country domestic demand replace oil-producer
import demand?
Will industrial country saving replace oil-producer financial
flows?
Will oil-producing countries adjust smoothly to their new,
lower, standard of living?
Will developing countries, particularly those that have been
dependent on oil as their principal source of export revenues,
reorient their export efforts?
Even if these questions can be answered confidently, or at
least bravely, in the affirmative, there remains the question of the
transition period involved.

That is,

-

5

-

How long will the transition period be?
What are the economic, social, and political costs involved?
What are the responsibilities of policymakers in this process?
Near-term outlook
I would like now to sketch out in broad terms the contours of
the world economic outlook in light of the oil price decline.

For the

United States, the longer-term impact of the drop in oil prices on
economic growth and inflation should be favorable, although there will
be -- indeed we are already seeing —

important short-term adverse

effects on the U.S. oil industry and related activities.

The correction

in the dollar exchange rate that began last year can be expected to lead
to a reduction in the U.S. current account deficit; the oil price
developments, by reducing the oil import bill, will accelerate this
improvement.

As I have mentioned, significant progress is being made in

the fiscal area.

Reflecting the improved fiscal position as well as

better price performance and subdued inflation expectations, U.S.
interest rates have eased, thereby reinforcing the positive effect the
oil market developments are likely to exert on U.S. economic activity.
Also working to boost economic activity will be the stronger business
profits that can be expected in most of U.S. industry after a decline in
the price of a major input like energy.
Turning to the other industrial countries as a group, and
abstracting from the exceptional circumstances of major oil exporters
like the United Kingdom, one can expect more-or-less the same kind of
scenario as I have just described for the United States, with the
differential impact dependent on the degree of importance of net oil

-

6

imports for a particular country.

-

There is, however, one noteworthy

difference between the U.S. and non-U.S. cases.

The ups and downs of

the dollar alter the effective price of oil in foreign countries even
when the dollar price of oil is constant.

Thus, the dollar's climb

tended to strengthen oil prices in Japan and Europe up through February
of last year, when the dollar hit its peak.

Since then, the effective

oil price in, for example, yen has been falling.

Since December the

decline has been exceedingly sharp.
With regard to external balances, the drop in oil prices will
lead to stronger net exports and current accounts than would have been
expected otherwise for most industrial countries.

These expected gains

will be offset somewhat by oil producers' cutbacks in their demands for
industrial country exports.

A countervailing pressure on the current

account position in many industrial countries, particularly Japan, is
the appreciation of exchange rates against the dollar, which, if
sustained, will tend to reduce their current account surpluses while
strengthening the U.S. current account position.

I should point out

here that there is no particular virtue in running persistent current
account surpluses; belief to the contrary is just a legacy of
mercantilism.
Even when the dust is settled and these various developments
have worked themselves out, current accounts in the major industrial
countries are likely still to be markedly uneven and unsustainable for
the next few years.

The U.S. current account deficit, although

apparently in the process of narrowing, is still expected to be quite
large both this year and next.

The mirror image of the U.S. deficit is

-

7

-

the large and unsustainable Japanese and German surpluses, totaling some
$65 billion last year and expected to increase by perhaps $30 billion
this year.

The international recycling of the financial flows and

aggregate demand shifts caused by the oil price decline must take place
in this context of a fundamental disequilibrium in the global balance of
payments pattern.
Turning briefly to the situation facing the developing
countries, the decline in oil prices has a differential impact depending
on whether a country is a net oil exporter.

The benefits of the oil

price decline are diffuse, while the costs to oil-exporting developing
countries are large and immediate, especially if a country has few
international reserves and a limited international borrowing capacity.
Several of the key heavily indebted countries will De hurt badly by the
oil price drop, if it persists.
will be particularly hard hit.

Mexico, Venezuela, Ecuador, and Nigeria
On the other hand, there are big

"winners," although there are fewer such winners than one might expect
because of the development of energy resources, including alternative
energy sources, in recent years.

Some of the major beneficiaries of

lower oil prices are Brazil, Korea, the Philippines, Taiwan, and
Yugoslavia.
Regardless of a country's status as an oil exporter or as a
debtor, all developing countries stand eventually to gain from two
factors related to the oil price movements.

The expected increased

growth in industrial countries can be expected to boost developing
country exports, and lower U.S. dollar interest rates will ease
developing countries' debt-service burdens.

-

8

-

Recycling
In general terms, policymakers have two main responsibilities
in the recycling process.

First, the fiscal and monetary authorities in

the industrial countries should be mindful of the need to replace the
world macroeconomic stimulus lost by the prospective reductions in
demand emanating from the oil-producing countries.

Second, policymakers

should try to ensure that the resulting new pattern of international
capital flows ends up financing worthwhile investment opportunities.

As

a practical matter, this means that market mechanisms should be relied
upon as the primary means of intermediating international capital flows.
In the United States, given the substantial fiscal and
external imbalances, care must be taken as to how to maintain aggregate
demand sufficient for non-inflationary growth.

For the world economy's

long-term health, emphasis must be on continuing to reduce the
structural fiscal deficit, which remains much too high, while main­
taining a responsible monetary policy that does not regenerate inflation
expectations.

At the same time, private sector demand can be expected

to be bolstered by the oil price decline.

Moreover, there are policy

steps that can be taken to encourage private investment and productivity
by making the economy more efficient through such measures as altering
the tax code in order to foster more reliance on market allocation of
resources.

Continued progress in keeping wage increases in line with

changes in productivity and the demand for labor will also be helpful.
The recent declines in U.S. interest rates have eased the
debt-servicing burdens of the indebted developing countries.

An

important responsibility of the U.S. economy, indeed all economies, is

-

9

-

to maintain open and growing markets for other countries' exports of
goods and services.

This, of course, is particularly important for the

heavily indebted developing countries.

In order to service their debts

they must be able to sell their exports, and growth in exports is the
best way of reducing these countries' debt burdens over time.

I

personally hope, and expect, the United States to pursue a strong
posture against trade protectionism —

including so-called "voluntary"

import quotas.
Japan and Germany do not face the constraints that we have in
the United States.

Their fiscal positions leave room for more economic

stimulus; on a structural basis, their fiscal balances are probably in
surplus.

Also, each is registering a strong and increasing current

account surplus, and there is virtually no inflation in either country.
Moreover, in Germany at least, there appears to be a great deal of labor
market slack.

Clearly there is scope for macroeconomic expansion in

both Japan and Germany.

Increasing domestic demand —

expansionary fiscal policy measures —

including

in these two key industrial

countries in order to correct their external imbalances as well as to
maintain world demand would seem to be useful.

Such measures would

represent not so much a change in Japanese and German long-term economic
policy strategy, but rather an alteration of the timing of policy steps
already envisioned.

For example, the recently released Maekawa Report,

endorsed by Prime Minister Nakasone, details ways in which Japan can
reduce its dependence on export-led growth.

The measures include

stimulating domestic demand and opening the economy to imports.

All I

am advocating is that these and similar moves be accelerated in light of

-

10

-

recent oil market developments, and that increases in Japanese imports
include products of developing countries as well as those of industrial
countries.

In Germany, the second stage of the long planned tax cut,

now scheduled for 1988, could be brought forward.
Given their current account surpluses, Japan and Germany by
definition

have to export capital.

How can the Japanese and German

governments ensure that their countries' considerable capital exports go
ultimately to worthwhile investments throughout the world, not just U.S.
government securities?

In this regard, closing the U.S. fiscal deficit

is important in order to help redirect these capital flows.

The

authorities could also encourage increased purchases of such alternative
securities as World Bank bonds, but the scope for actual governmental
direction of the capital outflows is, as it should be, limited.
In general, the industrial countries should be prepared to
support the International Monetary Fund, the World Bank, and the other
multilateral development banks in their efforts to aid the process of
economic adjustment to the new, lower, world oil price.

As I mentioned

before, it is imperative that the industrial countries maintain open
markets for goods, services, and capital flows.

Countries hard hit by

the oil price developments must be able to increase their sales of
non-oil exports.

In addition, financial intermediaries in the

industrial countries must continue to channel funds between surplus and
deficit countries in a sound and responsible manner, taking a
longer-term view of profitability.
As for the developing countries —
importers —

both oil exporters and oil

the Plan for Sustained Growth put forward last October by

-

11

-

U.S. Treasury Secretary Baker remains valid.

Policy emphasis in these

countries must continue to be on the structural and macroeconomic
adjustments that will establish the conditions necessary for sustainable
growth.

This approach obviously has been made easier for some countries

by the drop in oil prices, while for some other countries it has been
made more difficult.

Oil exporters with sufficient international

reserves and access to credit can take a longer adjustment period.
Those with very limited reserves or credit must adjust more quickly,
although international capital flows that finance suitable adjustment
programs can ease the transition.
Recycling will be as important with oil prices in sharp
decline as it was when oil prices were sharply rising.

Aggregate demand

must be recycled in order to maintain world economic activity.

Equally

important, capital flows must be recycled in order to support worthwhile
investment projects worldwide, to cushion declines in levels of
consumption (where appropriate), and to support suitable developing
country adjustment efforts directly and through multilateral
institutions.
The correction of the current account imbalances in the
industrial countries is an essential part of this recycling process.
Large current account surpluses or deficits can be manageable, and even
useful, as temporary buffers.

However, they seldom make sense

economically as a long-term policy.
The challenges presented to the world economy by the break in
oil prices are difficult, but I think they can be met successfully.
outcome depends on responsible policies in the industrial countries.

The

-

12

-

The aggregate demand measures that I have outlined would help the
individual industrial countries as well as the international economy.
Open markets for goods, services, and capital benefit the entire world
community.

Adjustment in the developing countries, where necessary, is

again constructive for both the individual countries involved as well as
the global economy.

I am hopeful that policymakers will have the vision to

meet these challenges constructively.