View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Reflections on Monetary Policy

Remarks by
Wayne D. Angell
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Downtown Economists Club
New York, New York
October 5, 1993

1

Introduction

It is an honor and a pleasure to have such a distinguished audience; and
I would like to take this opportunity to comment on what remains a critical topic in economic governance—managing the supply of money so as
to eliminate inflation. After a recession that has been long and stubborn,
the economy is showing some gains in output and employment. But these
promising events have also been accompanied by signs that inflation remains
a threat. As you may know, I have consistently argued during my tenure
as a member of the Federal Reserve Board of Governors that inflation is the
enemy of progress. Because it is the very poison that saps our confidence
in the future, I promised at my confirmation hearings, that I would fight to
eliminate it. It is a trust, I hope, I have not broken.
We have achieved much during the past decade in bringing down the rate
of inflation, but we need to persevere; the successes of the past should not
lull us into complacency, into the comfort of acquiescing to the status quo.
Especially in the case of inflation, monetary policy influences as much
a state of mind as the state of affairs: if, by word and deed, the central
bank instills confidence in its actions, and the public comes to believe that
inflation will be conquered, our task will be easier. In practice, this means
that one goal of monetary policy is to stabilize the public's expectation of
future prices, and in order to do this, we need to acquire some measures of
inflation expectations.
In a less complex world than we are faced with, a simple monetary growth
rule might lend credibility to policy, so that expectations would move in
the desired direction, without a need to have them monitored from time to
time to assess the success of policy. In this real and complex world that
lacks the consistent yardstick of an agreed-upon measure of money, reliance
on the behavior of monetary aggregates are not likely to be sufficient for

1

stabilizing price expectations. To take a measure of public expectations of
future inflation, policy makers may monitor several measures of public price
expectations, including surveys of households and professional forecasters of
inflation, or, as I have proposed on other occasions, spot commodity prices—
especially the price of gold—because they reflect the expectations of agents
participating in actual trading activities. I will discuss the importance of
expectations a little later; but first, I want to look back a little.

2

Lessons from International E x p e r i e n c e

Let me begin with some historical background to provide evidence of the
importance that domestic and international communities have attached to
reducing inflation. The experience of the past 25 years also establishes an unambiguous case for the central role played by monetary policy in controlling
inflation. Inflation rose in most industrialized countries over the 1970s after
the removal of the discipline on national monetary policies that had been
imposed by the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates. Although
Federal Reserve accommodation of oil price escalation played an important
role in price developments, the uptrend in inflation was evident in the late
1960s before the first OPEC price shock. By the late 1970s, many observers
had become convinced that inflation was restraining economic growth; and
the past 15 years have witnessed a widespread and concerted effort by central
banks to reduce inflation.
The improvement has been impressive.

Comparing CPIs in 1980 and

1993, the rate of inflation has fallen from 12 percent to 3 percent in the
US. In eighteen industrialized economies, including Western Europe, the US,
Canada, Australia, New Zealand, and Japan, the inflation rate dropped an
average of 8 percentage points during that period to an average of less than
4 percent, a remarkable turnaround achievement!

2

3

T h e Current S t a t e of Inflation in t h e U S

While it is tempting to say that the current rate of inflation is relatively
harmless, the purchasing power of the dollar would fall by 50 percent in the
next 20 years if prices were to continue to rise 3 1/2 percent per year. Do we
know for sure that there will not be losers in this process?
Let me mention some salient recent events that lead to concerns—hopefully
unnecessarily—that inflation is no longer falling.
A commonly cited measure of the core rate of inflation, the CPI excluding
food and energy, has grown at a 3-1/2 percent annual rate during the first 9
months of this year, compared with with an identical increase of 3-1/2 percent
over the 12 months ending in December 1992. The most recent Employment
Cost Index reports are showing some firming of labor costs. Of course, prices
are subject to transitory fluctuations, and so it is hard to say for sure that
the core inflation has not just been temporarily stalled. Nonetheless, I think
that there is cause for concern whenever an attitude of complacency toward
a non-zero rate of inflation arises. At a minimum, these signs on the wage
and price front indicate that we cannot ignore the potentially significant
risk of losing much of the hard-earned, disinflationary momentum we have
established during the past years.
On the positive side, some signs during the first half of this year suggesting
a reemergence of worrisome inflation have faded as the price of gold has
fallen back to $350 after running from $327 to $403 per ounce. Likewise, the
experimental Federal Reserve commodity price index, which is dominated
by the price of oil, peaked in March at 116 percent of the 1986 first-quarter
average and has recently dropped back to a range between 100 and 105
percent of that base. However, in 1991 and 1992, the core component of
commodity prices, excluding food, fiber, and energy components, stayed in
a range between 116 and 126 percent of the base in the first quarter of 1986.

3

It shot up to 148 in March of 1993 before falling back to 135 during the
last week of September. Should we be complacent? While the annualized
inflation rates of gold and energy-weighted commodities have been zero, the
core commodity inflation rate has been 4 percent per annum over a 7 1/2
year period.
A second item on the positive side of continued disinflation has been the
restoration of corporate profitability in the United States that took place
through restructuring rather than a reliance on price increases.
Among the world's 100 largest public companies reported by the September 24, 1993 Wall Street Journal "World Business" supplement, eight of the
top ten largest fiscal profit totals in 1992 were attained by US firms. A continuing, firm monetary policy assuring stable gold prices and, consequently, a
stable exchange value of the dollar, will assure a path toward a stable general
price level.

4

T h e Goals of M o n e t a r y Policy

Before we consider how price stabilization is to be achieved, it is perhaps
well to reconsider why we would want stability in the first place. A monetary
exchange mechanism, being an information-efficient substitute for the barter
system it replaced, derives its strength from the trust people have in the
currency. For this reason, stabilization of the purchasing power of a country's
currency must be a primary goal of the central bank. Thanks to the foresight
of the founding fathers, the constitution instructs the Congress, of which the
Federal Reserve is an agency, to coin money and regulate its value—clearly
a mandate for price stability. The Full Employment Act of 1948 and the
Humphrey-Hawkins Act of 1978 expanded the set of Congressional monetary
policy mandates to include annual goals for employment and the growth of
income.
4

These goals are, in my view, not inconsistent. Growth and stable prices
stand in symbiotic relationship; and if we maintain the latter, the better it
will be for the former.
Evidence that output growth tends to be greater at low inflation in the
United States, especially when viewed over longer horizons, can be adduced
from correlations between output growth and inflation at varying horizons.
Correlation is, of course, not causality. One cannot be entirely sure if episodic
declines in productivity did not cause observed run-ups in inflation; but eventually, wages should have fallen, so that over longer periods, the observed
negative relation would have weakened, contrary to our observation. Some
observers believe the negative correlation to have been the joint outcome of
the energy shocks in the seventies, whereas it is my view that it was monetary
policy that permitted these shocks to increase the price level permanently.
In the 1970s, the Federal Reserve was faced with the choice of either accommodating energy price increases or accepting a temporary cessation of
growth. Choosing the former was, in my judgment, responsible for both a
higher subsequent inflation and lagging growth.
Real activity may be inhibited for the simple reason that people are not
perfectly informed or are committed to predetermined contracts, because
in such instances, absolute price level changes can have effects on relative
price changes. For example, real wages often fall during periods of price
increases because indexation never truly catches up with inflation, even if
well predicted, which it rarely is.
Indexation of contracts in goods and labor markets is one way that individuals and firms attempt to minimize the cost of inflation; however, the lack
of perfect indexation schemes in labor and goods markets suggests that real
costs prevent such contracts and implies that, even with indexing, inflation
arbitrarily creates winners and losers. One obstacle to attaining satisfactory
indexing schemes is the difficulty of writing simple indexing provisions that
5

distinguish between relative and nominal price changes. Taking labor contracts as an example, if output and consumption goods prices always moved
together, firms and workers would be happy to agree on an indexing formula
based on either price. This is not the case; the difference between product
and consumer prices is neither certain nor stable over time. The choice of
price on which to index in each instance will depend on relative bargaining
powers, where firms prefer product prices and workers prefer consumption
prices.
But even more important, although indexation has marginally protected
labor costs, it has missed protecting the return to capital. The failure to index
capital gains before applying marginal tax rates has, in many cases, been
tantamount to the confiscation of capital. The adverse impact on savings and
investment of these iniquitous tax provisions are doubtless reflected in the
performance of equity markets during the disinflationary 1980s and 1990s as
compared with market performance while inflation accelerated in the 1970s.
The variability of inflation, often associated with high inflation, is of
equally important concern for the policy maker. Again, historical evidence
points to a positive association between the variabilities of output growth and
inflation over various horizons, suggesting that periods of volatile inflation are
also periods of uncertain real growth, especially over extended horizons. High
inflation volatility may in some sense reduce people's ability to make longrun plans. One plausible explanation for the positive correlation between the
volatilities in inflation and output growth is based on a theory in economics
according to which changes in the general price level mask changes in relative
prices that people need to know to make intelligent decisions in the market
place. If true, the theory suggests that highly variable inflation could act
to limit people's ability to distinguish relative price changes and price level
changes, possibly inhibiting decisions that foster economic growth.
Without exagerating the import of the empirical findings to which I have
6

alluded, it seems evident that they cannot lead to the conclusion that high
or volatile inflation has been good for the US economy.

5

T h e i m p o r t a n c e of credibility

How monetary policy plays itself out has as much to do with what the Fed
does as with how its actions are perceived. For this reason, a steady hand in
reducing inflation is of utmost importance. Let me elaborate a little here.
It is well known that output losses accompanying disinflation arise if wage
and price setting behavior in the private sector does not fully reflect monetary
policy. Rigidities in prices and wages, often institutionalized in contracts with
varying durations, contribute to delays in the impact of monetary policy. A
reduction in the growth of money will have greater negative employment consequences if it is not accompanied by a commensurate reduction in inflation
expectations.
For this reason, the Fed's greatest asset is its credibility. The faith and
trust a public has in the ability and willingness of the monetary authority to
carry out policy can reduce the costs to society if a decision has been made
to reduce inflation within a given period of time. The costs of incredulity
are real.

If the public does not believe that a policy of disinflation will

be pursued, it will pay a higher price in unemployment for every point of
inflation reduction.
Of course, credibility must be earned and takes time to build; and being
intangible, credibility is easily squandered. From a current perspective, a
short-term deviation from the disinflationary course may be well-intentioned.
But if the public perceives such hesitation as a weakening of resolve, it will
react by building its raised expectations of inflation into long-term wage and
price contracts with effects that will take longer to undo, requiring future
doses of anti-inflationary steps and output losses that may exceed current

7

gains.
Is it b e t t e r to act slowly rather t h a n quickly? Perhaps we cannot say
for sure.

Some t e n t a t i v e evidence f r o m past experience as well as across

industrialized economies suggests t h a t the o u t p u t losses per unit of reduced
inflation tend to be smaller if disinflation is pursued quickly rather t h a n
slowly. If true, it suggests in part t h a t a vigorous stance in m o n e t a r y policy
contributes to credibility which lowers the cost of disinflation. And, to t h e
extent t h a t lack of action, or stop-go action wears on credibility, t h e empirical
lesson would seem to be t h a t a steady pursuit of the goal of price stabilization
presents t h e best hope for achieving such a goal.
In establishing and maintaining credibility, a purpose and focus of policy is t a n t a m o u n t . While circumstances sometimes dictate deliberation in
action—for example, allowing t h e m o n e t a r y instruments to adjust at a moderate pace—incrementalism for its own sake is to b e avoided. In considering
t h e appropriate actions for m o n e t a r y policy in the near t e r m , we must resist
t h a t h u m a n tendency in the face of uncertainty to take small steps for their
own sake.
Historically, whenever the central bank appeared t o b e engaged in pegging t h e change in the Federal funds rate, this exclusive preoccupation with
choosing t h e next increment left the public, especially holders of bonds, confused and apprehensive about the intentions of m o n e t a r y policy. W i t h o u t an
anchor, without a clearly understood goal of where policy is going, a sequence
of incremental changes can actually lead to a spiralling inflation if maintained
for any lengthy period. And, referring back to m y previous point, a policy
of this kind would rattle public confidence.

8

6

A n Appropriate M e a s u r e of Inflation

Unfortunately, and in contrast to the pure imaginings of economic theory,
policy making is not endowed with the luxury of simplicity: we have not been
favored with a single variable called "the price." In its stead we must look
at a set of price indexes, each serving a purpose, with possibly no clear-cut
candidate having the perfect profile of "the price level." The consumer price
index (CPI), the producer price indexes (PPI) for finished goods and crude
materials, and the gross domestic product (GDP) deflator have generally
risen over the post-war period, but there are marked divergences, not all of
which appear to have been predictable. All of these prices are important in
the sense of determining the general climate of inflation. If they diverge from
each other in the long run, a policy that focuses on any one of them alone
may, at the very least, lead to problems of credibility, especially if the selected
price index happens to be the one with the lowest trend. As a case in point,
consider the GDP deflator which, in contrast to the CPI deflator, excludes
prices of imported goods. As the economy opens, a focus on a stable GDP
deflator may become less relevant; and the public would soon come to learn
that the prices it pays for goods and services do not reflect the presumably
stable price level.
To appreciate the problem further, consider, for example, that the Producer Price Index for crude materials, essentially measuring the prices manufacturers pay for the intermediate goods and commodities that become transformed into final consumption goods, rose less than 3/4 percent between 1982
and 1987. The P P I for finished goods rose by more, but not nearly as much
as the CPI. While we made significant gains on inflation during that period, clearly no one viewed inflation as defeated, as one might have deduced
from the behavior of the P P I for crude materials. One culprit is the cost of
services—medical care stands out—that are not measured by the Producer

9

Price Index and that were not as well restrained as were the prices of finished
goods and materials.
Given that various plausible measures of the price level have been observed to diverge from each other in the long run, the inherent danger of
choosing an index that does not capture the purchasing power of the domestic currency for most people is that the error between the selected index and
the "correct" measure may accumulate over time. From year to year, this
may or may not be perceived as a problem. For example, for most of the
post-War period, it would have made little difference if the Fed had chosen
the GDP deflator when the CPI was the true measure of the general price
level; the error—the incremental uncertainty about what next quarter's CPI
inflation rate will be—would have been small in the short as well as in the
long term. Had the Fed, instead, targeted the P P I for crude materials, this
uncertainty would have been 9 times as great after the first year; and after 10
years, the incremental uncertainty would have been nearly 30 times as high!
All this begs the question: what is the "right" index? Consumers presumably want consumer prices stabilized while firms prefer stable producer
prices. Being a social, possibly zero-sum, issue to which there are no hard
answers, its resolution may require the political forum.

7

T h e Art of R e a d i n g Inflation E x p e c t a t i o n s

Whatever measure of agregate prices is chosen to be stabilized—and for the
moment that seems to be the consumer price index—the public will, as a
whole, react to policy and form attitudes and expectations that are influential
in the outcome of policy. The public's expectations of inflation can thus serve
as an indicator of policy: if policy is stabilizing, inflationary expectations
should be stable.

In a sense, then, the primary goal of monetary policy

is to stabilize expectations.

The central bank has available two kinds of
10

information that, in principle, reveal something about the public's frame of
mind. The first originates in surveys that ask people to say what they expect
inflation to be a year ahead or later; the second derives from asset markets,
such as commodity prices. Let me discuss their uses and limitations in turn.

7.1

H o u s e h o l d inflation e x p e c t a t i o n s

Consumers, that is, all of us, make decisions in the market place, implicitly
expressing our expectations of future inflation that affect purchases in goods
markets and wages in labor markets. A widely quoted survey of household
inflation expectations is the the Michigan Survey of 500 households taken
monthly by telephone. Because wages and prices together manifest the inflationary environment of the economy, there is an apparent presumption that
this survey should perhaps not be ignored. Let us examine this question.
For quarterly averages, Chart 1 shows how Michigan Survey expectations
of CPI inflation one year ahead are related to actual inflation in the CPI.
T h e p i c t u r e shows t w o series t h a t are highly coordinated. It also shows t h a t

households are myopic, believing that inflation in the coming year will be
the same as inflation in the preceding quarter: household expectations more
or less mimick the path of the inertial inflation rate itself. For this reason,
they would not be useful as a guide for policy.

7.2

Inflation e x p e c t a t i o n s held by professional forecasters

A second potential source revealing inflationary expectations is based on a
survey of 30 professional forecasters. Chart 2 shows the CPI inflation rate
and the inflation rate professional forecasters predicted a year earlier. It appears that households and professional forecasters have very different views
of monetary policy and the prospect of inflation. Between 1982 and 1993,
11

the professional forecast corresponds in its general pattern to the shape of
CPI inflation over this period; however, unlike the household forecast, the
professional forecast does not follow actual inflation myopically. I am not
really sure how much the one-year inflation forecast by professionals really
tells us. Its movements over the years seem to lag those of actual inflation,
providing little advance warning even over periods longer than one year. It
appears to be a fairly slugish variable, like inflation itself, and thus lacks
that characteristic property of a true expectations variable, which is to be
instantaneously adaptable to new information, as we observe, for example, in
the case of commodity prices. The deviations of professional forecasts from
subsequent outcomes in inflation suggests that considerations like unemployment events enter the calculations, but in ways that are not readily discerned
by the policy maker. My preferred indicators for market-oriented price expectations remain commodity prices, which, if judiciously interpreted, can
tell us much about the prospective impact of monetary policy.

7.3

Expectations revealed in c o m m o d i t y prices

As you may know, I have long advocated using commodity prices as indicators
in monetary policy. Indeed, in December 1987, I proposed in a speech to
the Lehrman Institute that the Federal Reserve give commodity prices an
expanded role as a price guide to adjust the target ranges for short-run
money growth. A look at Charts 3-6 is revealing. They show that the cycles
of CPI inflation and moving averages of the inflation rates of the commodity
price indexes of industrial materials, industrial metals, food, and of an index
combining prices from all three groups, except oil, are remarkably similar
between 1962 and 1993. Especially interesting is the apparent fact that the
turning points in commodity price inflation generally lead the turning points
in CPI inflation by three quarters to a year. Commodity prices are telling us

12

something that we may want to exploit. Why is that the case?
Commodity spot prices are, by definition, the market-clearing prices of
storable goods in speculative trade wherein players have indirectly revealed
their attitudes towards economic opportunities that depend a great deal on
future inflation. If commodity price inflation is rising, it is possible that
it does so because trading agents predominantly expect higher inflation in
the future, although other influences, such as excess demand, supply shocks,
strained capacity, and so on, may play a role in such a process. Properly
interpreted, movements in commodity prices may reveal the expectations
that agents hold about future inflation. Since inflation expectations reflect
expectations about monetary policy, commodity prices can tell us something
about how well policy is doing.
Two examples of the usefulness of short-term commodity price guides may
be helpful. First, consider a hypothetical event, an event that is presumably
not observed or properly understood by the policy maker, and that will
cause the price level to rise in the future. If goods prices are temporarily
sticky, asset traders who expect future increases in the price level will demand
more commodities. If goods prices could rise immediately, asset prices would
not need to rise by as much.

Given price-level inertia, the signal power

of commodity prices is actually enhanced, because the latter can and will
rise more than proportionately, overshooting to compensate for the lack of
flexibility in goods markets. It is in this manner that commodity prices may
be able to present clear and highly visible signals of future price events—
essentially the future impact of current monetary policy.
The second example illustrates how commodity prices, including, very
importantly, the price of gold, may serve as a handy thermometer of the
Fed's credibility. Suppose the Fed has settled on a short-term indicator of
policy, such as M2 money supply. A surprise increase in money growth may
be followed by a decrease or an increase in short-term interest rates. Suppose
13

the latter happens.

What are we to make of it?

Are markets expecting

the Fed to maintain its target and tighten by selling Treasury bills? Or is
it that markets are beginning to believe the Fed is flagging in its resolve?
One answer is provided by the behavior of commodity prices: if they fall,
then surely one interpretation is that commodity markets expect the Fed
to tighten; conversely, if commodity prices rise, markets expect the general
price level to increase.
To those who are concerned that I propose a commodity price targeting
rule, let me reiterate that I consider commodity prices as purely short-term
indicators of the unobserved future price level, a signal that must be evaluated
in light of other information. Commodity prices contain information about
the price level, but they are not themselves the price level. Since commodity
prices depend on the behavior of the real rate of interest, an observed change
in a commodity price may signal either a change in the expected rate of
inflation or in the interest rate. If the Fed were to target a commodity price,
it would, in effect, constrain movements in the real rate. The true target of
monetary policy is and always should be the behavior over the long term of
prices the public understands and deals with every day.

8

Summary

I believe that adherence to the principles I have laid out should help us
move toward price stability, higher labor productivity, a permanently higher
savings rate, and a prolonged period of economic expansion.
I believe that most of us abhor inflation and what it can do to society. The
concerted actions by central banks in the early and mid eighties to overcome
inflation is testimony to the universality of this sentiment. Inflation is not
the lubricant of progress, as some may claim. To the contrary, it is the enemy
of sustained growth.
14

In guiding the monetary ship through uncertain waters, we are not alone.
There is a public that watches us and reacts. The outcome of monetary policy
will depend on how it is perceived as reflected in the expectations that we
foster. Unable to read minds, we can nonetheless gain indirect measures that
may help us maintain the course. To reach the calm waters of stable and
predictable prices, we would not be remiss in letting commodity prices be
the sextant readings of the stars that guide us to our destination.
For the sake of the future of this great country and with clarity of purpose,
let us recommit ourselves here and resolve to continue this good fight.

15

Chart 1
Household Inflation Expectations
Michigan Survey: 1-year-ahead forecast of CPI inflation lagged 1 year
Core Inflation

Chart 2
Professional Inflation Expectations
1-year-ahead forecast of CPI inflation lagged 1 year
Core Inflation

- /

1982

1983

1984

• • >I
1985 1986

1 1I <
1987 1988

±

J L
1989

J L j. _L
1990 1991

j.
1992

j
1993

±

Chart 3
Commodity Prices
4-qtr Moving Average of Industrial Materials Price Index
Core Inflation

20

15

10

5

0

•5

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

Chart 4
Commodity Prices
4-qtr Moving Average of Industrial Metals Price Index
Core Inflation

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

Chart 5
Commodity Prices
4-qtr Moving Average of Agricultural Commodities Price Index
Core Inflation

5

4

3

2

1

0

1

•2

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

Chart 6
Commodity Prices
4-qtr Moving Average of FRB Experimental Index (excluding oil)
Core Inflation

1950

1955

1960

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990