View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery

10:15 A.M. E.S.T.
November 29, 1988

THE ECONOMIC SITUATION AND THE OUTLOOK

Remarks by
Wayne D. Angel1
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

Presented at
the U.S. Department of Agriculture's
1988 Outlook Conference

November 29, 1988
Washington, D.C.

I

am pleased to have the opportunity to talk with

you today about the current economic situation and the
outlook.

I know it is often the practice on occasions like

this for speakers to lay out in some detail their forecasts
of economic prospects for the coming year.

However, my

approach today is going to be a little different.

I want to

step back from the current situation and take a broad view
of how the economy has evolved over the past several years
and provide— again, in broad terms— my assessment of the
main forces that will be influencing the future course of
the economy.
As you may know, the economic expansion in the
United States turned six years of age this month, and, in
many respects, those six years have witnessed an unusually
successful economic performance.

Real GNP— the total output

of goods and services— has increased nearly 27 percent since
the expansion began in late 1982.

In the labor market,

employment has risen 16 million, and the unemployment rate
has declined to the lowest level in a decade and a half.
However, the most impressive gain of the past few
years— and one that I wish to discuss in some detail— is the
turnabout in inflation.

Inflation had accelerated through

the 1960s and 1970s and moved into the double-digit range by
the end of the last decade.

I believe that acceleration

reflected a monetary accommodation of both the price shocks
that arose in the petroleum and agricultural markets and the

-2-

growth-oriented objectives that gave short shrift to the
goal of price stability.
In the end, of course, we were to have neither
price stability nor strong growth.

As price increases

accelerated, the inflation took on a dynamic of its own.
Businesses increasingly attempted to meet profit rate
objectives by increasing prices.

Workers responded by

demanding big wage increases to stay ahead of inflation,

and

businesses in turn had to raise prices once again to cover
the hike in wage costs.

Asset values,

including the price

of farm land, doubled and even tripled during the decade of
the 1970s reflecting the present value of expected future
commodity prices.

Businesses and consumers began to alter

their real spending and investment plans in anticipation of
rising prices.

And, this acceleration of inflation

expectations reduced the demand for money and raised
velocity,

so that the observed growth rate of the money

stock, in effect, understated the extent of monetary ease—
policy simply was not as tight as policymakers thought it
was at the time.

An observation of auction markets for both

commodities and foreign currencies should have pinpointed
the pervasiveness of monetary ease during this period.
Eventually, the inflation resulted in an impairment
of the allocative function of the price system, as it proved
increasingly difficult to distinguish changes in relative
prices from pure inflation.

Nominal measures of economic

-3-

performance, such as corporate profits, suffered a similar
malfunction.

Inflation, in effect, clouded the very signals

upon which our free market economy depends if it is to
operate efficiently.
As the social and economic costs of inflation
mounted, the goal of price stability came to occupy a more
central place in the public's thinking, and economic
policies shifted accordingly.

At first, policy was

attracted to the misguided view that wage-price guidelines
would contain inflation.

But, eventually, the anti­

inflation effort took the form of a restrictive monetary
policy turnaround in October 1979.

In the ensuing three

years, the nation went through two painful recessions as the
inflationary tendencies that had taken hold over two decades
began to be squeezed out of the economy.

By 1982 the rate

of consumer price inflation had been brought down to under 4
percent,

less than a third of what it had been only two

years before.

The speed with which inflation decelerated in

that period undoubtedly shifted outward the demand for
money, and monetary policy thereby became more restrictive
than suggested by the growth of the monetary aggregates.
Since the recovery began in late 1982, the goal of
price stability has continued to occupy a central place in
economic policy-making, both in the United States and in
other industrial countries; and— at least thus far— the
results have been generally favorable.

Inflation rates in

-4-

the United States remained stable in around the 3 to 4
percent range through the first three years of the expansion
and then dipped further in 1986 when world oil prices
caught up with an earlier and more general collapse of
commodity p r i c e s .
Deflation in key parts of the goods-producing
sector came close to causing a recession in 1986; secondquarter GNP was negative that year, and the average rate of
growth over the second and third quarters was close to zero.
Monetary reflation succeeded in avoiding a recession, but
propelled a rebound in commodity prices,

including oil, and

contributed to an exchange rate adjustment.
This monetary stimulus contributed to both a
reversal of commodity price trends including a partial
rebound in the price of oil, and an exchange rate adjustment
which increased import prices.

Consequently, the CPI

measure of inflation picked up to a 4.4 percent rate in
1987.

Although the exchange value of the dollar is little

changed from its year-ago level, and oil prices have
weakened once again this year, inflation overall has been
maintained at about its 1987 pace.

This plateau in

inflation in 1988 reflected the effects of the drought,
together with higher prices for some imports, and a slight
updrift in the rate of increase in wag e s .

Unit labor costs

have picked up in the nonfarm business sector, despite a

-5-

continuation of remarkably good performance in the
manufacturing sector.
Mindful of the experience of the 1970s, the Federal
Reserve began a shift toward gradual restraint in 1987 and
1988 in order to ensure that the runup in commodity prices
that accompanied the decline in the exchange value of the
dollar would not lead to a more deeply rooted pick-up in
inflation.

Growth in the money supply has been restrained,

with the M2 measure of money restricted to an annual rate of
4.8 percent over the two years ended in October of this
year.

This is the slowest growth of M2 over a two-year

period since 1961, and compares to a 9-1/2 percent rate of
growth over the first four years of the expansion.
On the whole,

I would view the shift to slower

money growth rates these past two years as a measured
response to limit the step-up in the price level to a one­
time occurrence.

This action, if maintained,

should

forestall embedding inflation into the wage structure and
should enable us to continue the disinflation process to
achieve our goal of price level stability.
In assessing whether these policies will be
successful in extinguishing inflation,

I am encouraged by

some important changes that have occurred in the United
States and world economies since the 1970s.

These changes,

in my view, are likely to work in the direction of
reinforcing anti-inflation policies.

First, many other

-6-

industrial countries also were deeply scarred by the
inflation of the 1970s, and these countries,

like the United

States, are giving greater weight to the goal of price
stability than was previously the case.

Thus, if these

policies remain intact, a worldwide surge of inflation would
seem less likely than in the 1970s.
Second, the world has become a far more competitive
place than it was a decade ago.

Our trade sectors now face

competition not only from Japan and the European Community
but also from the newly industrialized economies of the
Pacific Rim.

And,

if third-world countries, as well as

China and the Soviet Union continue to move toward more
market-oriented economies, then those countries probably
also will gradually become more important competitors in the
world marketplace.
Third, the deregulation of markets in the United
States, accompanied by a reduction in the real minimum wage,
has dramatically improved the competitive position of the
United States in a more competitive world economy.
All told, these changes in the world and U.S.
economies have important implications for the processes of
wage and price determination.

Profit rates in U.S.

manufacturing are increasingly dependent on the success in
cutting costs, due to an inability to pass price increases
forward.

In this environment,

any forward-looking labor

union or business that is exposed to export or import

-7-

competition has to recognize that pushing hard for wage or
price increases may be a disastrously counterproductive
action if such increases result in a loss of markets and a
loss of jobs.
I

feel that this shift toward a more flexible wage

and price structure presents an unusual opportunity to
continue to restrain monetary growth to a level consistent
with price stability, without engendering an increase in
unemployment.
Indeed,

I hope that we can seize that opportunity.

I believe that a reasonable goal over the medium

term would be to reduce inflation by about 1/2 to 1
percentage point per year, and I believe that this can be
done while unemployment remains in the 5 to 6 percent range.

Let me now turn from inflation to a discussion of
some other issues that bear upon the outlook.

As I noted at

the start of my talk, the expansion now is six years old.
All forecasters are asking:

How long can it continue?

To provide some basis for comparison, the current
expansion is more than two years longer than the average
expansion of the postwar period.

It also is the third

longest expansion of this century, and the two that were
longer owed their longevity partly to wartime demands during
World War II period and during the Vietnam period,
respectively.

-8-

However, merely because the expansion has become
relatively long does not mean that it is "old" in a
biological sense or that it necessarily will.end soon.
Indeed, this expansion is quite different in that the
unprecedented rise in exchange value of the dollar in the
first two years of expansion served to keep some industries,
including agriculture,

in a depressed condition while other

sectors were growing vigorously.

The combination of slower

money growth served to provide a soft landing for the
downward adjustment of U.S. exchange rates and resulted in a
less than robust expansion in some sectors.

But now that

the exchange value of the dollar is in the approximate range
that prevailed in 1980, a new rapid recovery is underway in
manufacturing, particularly the capital goods sector.

This

expansion is not going to wither away by itself; rather, the
expansion will end only if economic imbalances of one sort
or another cause it to be cut short.
The two imbalances that are attracting attention
currently— as they have almost since the start of the
expansion— are, of course, the trade deficit and the federal
budget deficit.

In the remainder of my talk this morning,

would like to lay out my own views of the risks that these
imbalances pose for the economic outlook.

As you will see,

I view the trade and budget deficit problems as being
important but by no means insurmountable obstacles; and I

I

-9-

therefore am relatively optimistic about the prospects for
the economy.
The trade imbalance,

it seems to me, posed its most

serious threat to the economy back in 1986.

At that time,

exports were still lagging from the dollar appreciation that
also was contributing to a surge in imports.
Since 1986, however, the trade situation has begun
to turn around,

in a fairly dramatic way.

The foreign

exchange value of the dollar, after peaking in 1985, has
fallen substantially over most of the subsequent period; and
U.S. industry, with the benefit of continued restraint on
wages and costs, has regained much of the competitiveness
that had been lost during the period of dollar appreciation.
As the effects of this depreciation took hold, U.S. exports
began to strengthen, and by 1987 a major export boom was
underway.

Real exports of goods and services rose 18-1/2

percent over the four quarters of last year.
brought further strong gains.

This year has

In September, for example,

merchandise exports, in nominal terms, were up nearly 30
percent from a year earlier.
With this rise in exports, the prospects in many of
our tradeable goods sectors have taken a strong turn for the
better.

Agricultural exports have risen markedly, both in

volume and in value.

Industrial production began

strengthening in late 1986 and has surged more recently,
rising nearly 6 percent over the four quarters of 1987 and

-10-

at close to a 5 percent rate so far this year.

Growth of

GNP, which had slowed below 2 percent in 1986, has averaged
4 percent over the 1987-88 period.
In the period ahead, I think that we shall see
further substantial growth in real exports of goods and
services and a slower rate of growth of real imports than in
the early years of the expansion.

Overall, the external

sector should be making a significant positive contribution
to the growth of real GNP, maintaining the pattern of the
last two years.

The tradeable goods sectors should benefit

significantly from this trend, and over time, the trade
balance should continue to narrow from the still substantial
deficit position of today.
The federal budget deficit is the other imbalance
that remains an issue of much concern.
issue,

In approaching this

I think it is first important to try to identify more

precisely the nature of the threat that the budget deficit
poses, as well as some areas in which the potential effects
of budget deficits have been misconstrued by many analysts.
For example,

I believe that the deficit is

inflationary only if the Federal Reserve tries to monetize
it; and I want to assure you that we at the Federal Reserve
have no intention of following such a course.

This does not

mean, however, that the deficit is unimportant.
contrary, there are two significant consequences.

To the
First,

the U.S. budget deficit serves to lessen the economic power

-11-

of the congressional and executive branches of our
government.

As interest on the debt rises as a percent of

federal tax receipts, these interest payments crowd out
discretionary spending options.

This does not mean that the

U.S. economy suffers a restraint, only that the government
sector is restrained.
Second, the deficit does have an effect on interest
rates:

it causes the level of rates to be higher than would

otherwise be the case and thereby causes a capital inflow or
squeezes out private investment.

However, in thinking about

how the deficit might affect the future course of interest
rates, it is important to take account of market
expectations.

I would argue, for example, that the current

structure of interest rates already incorporates the
market's expectations of how the budget deficit is going to
evolve over time.

Budgetary developments would therefore

cause rates to change only if those developments were to
alter expectations in an important way.

A failure to move

the deficit down as fast as the markets are expecting would
likely result in higher rates, but a faster-than-expected
reduction of the deficit would more than likely lead to
lower rates than would otherwise be the case.
It will not be possible for Congress and the new
administration to eliminate the deficit in one swift stroke.
No one expects that.

What the financial markets do need to

see is some convincing evidence that the government still is

-12-

on a course that will take it, over time, back toward
budgetary balance.

My own hunch is that signs of progress

along the lines laid out in the Gramm-Rudman-Hollings
legislation would be viewed in the markets as an acceptably
rapid pace of deficit reduction.

To the extent that the

progress is faster than the markets might be anticipating,

I

believe that we would see interest rates lower than would
otherwise be the case, with accompanying benefits for
capital spending and other interest-sensitive sectors.

The

key question for our future is the decision to stay with
Gramm-Rudman-Hollings, to continue plausible efforts to
bring the 1990 budget deficit down to the $100 billion
requirement and, failing to reach a compromise, to leave the
sequester law intact.
In summary,

I personally do not believe that the

imbalances that we see currently will necessarily derail the
expansion.

Rather,

I see the period ahead as an opportunity

for a combination of monetary discipline and continued
progress in reducing the federal budget deficit.

Together

they can provide the necessary underpinnings for a continued
healthy economic performance with strong export growth.
Monetary discipline will continue to be required to ensure
that inflation is squeezed out of our economy.
context of moderately restrictive fiscal policy,

And,

in the

restrained

money growth will still provide ample resources for a

-13-

continued improvement in net exports, and continue the
impetus to keep the expansion on track.
Granted, the course ahead may not work out smoothly
at every point in time.

But, if policymakers will continue

to monitor auction market signals, the rough spots should be
surmountable and a year from now, when another Agricultural
Outlook Conference convenes,

I rather expect that we shall

be looking back at a year in which some further progress has
been made in reducing the current imbalances, that we shall
be looking back at the successful conclusion of a seventh
year of economic expansion, and that we shall see inflation
somewhat below its pace of the past two y e a r s .