View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
12:30 P.M. E.D.T.
May 14, 1990

COOPERATIVE APPROACHES TO REDUCING RISKS
IN GLOBAL FINANCIAL MARKETS

remarks by

Wayne D. Angell
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

at the

Conference on
Regulating International Financial Markets:
Issues and Policies

New York, New York
May 14, 1990

COOPERATIVE APPROACHES TO REDUCING RISKS
IN GLOBAL FINANCIAL MARKETS

Let me begin by thanking Hugh Patrick and Frank Edwards for
providing me an opportunity to participate in this very timely and
important conference.

You who are attending this conference are, of

course, keenly aware of the extent to which economies as well as
particular markets have become increasingly interdependent.

You are

aware also of the benefits we all derive from that integration, such as
enhanced growth, greater efficiency in production decisions, improved
resource allocation, and an expanded range of choices for consumers and
investors.
In my remarks today, I will first describe what I see as two
basic threats to the benefits that flow from an integrated, global
trading order and second identify cooperative efforts that I believe can
address those threats successfully.

I will conclude my remarks on

cooperative efforts by focusing on reduction of credit and liquidity
risks in the foreign exchange markets.
Challenges to the Global Trading Order
One force that quite clearly threatens the global trading order
is protectionism.

I see that threat in the United States, where we have

protectionist policies with respect to some goods and financial services
and where some have argued for more widespread and substantial
protection.

I fear it also in other parts of the world.

World trade

has managed to overcome these threats and has expanded strongly, but I
would be even more comfortable looking to the future if the current
Uruguay Round were to reach a successful conclusion.

Prospects for the

- 2 -

global economy, including those countries seeking to move toward more
market-oriented systems, would be enhanced if all countries pursued
reductions in all forms of barriers to trade.
The other set of challenges is quite different.

It relates to

the volatility and associated risks that arise in international trade
and, especially from the perspective of this conference, in
international financial markets.
varied.

The root causes of volatility are

For example, a good deal of volatility in the past has been

associated with unsound or divergent monetary policies.

Uncertainty

concerning the priority attached to stable prices permeates the market's
determination of exchange rates.
One way to reduce risks in global financial markets involves
international policy coordination aimed at greater macroeconomic
stability in the global economy.
have a clear role to play.

In this policy process, central banks

In particular, their first assignment is to

achieve price stability.
The liberalization that has taken place in individual financial
markets and in international capital flows fosters greater integration
of financial markets around the globe.

Holders of wealth, whether

individuals or official holders of reserves, can diversify more easily
their portfolios across currencies and countries than they could
previously.

New financial instruments in the United States and

developing markets outside the United States have offered increasing
depth and breadth to investors in markets outside their own country that
usually involve the use of another currency.

The opportunity for such

diversification is a desirable consequence of the strengthening of the

-3-

world's financial markets.

It is an irrevocable reality that imposes

new disciplines on market participants as well as on central bank
behavior.

Until market participants expect central banks to be

permanently successful in controlling inflation, we will not have
reached the condition for nominal exchange rates to be stable over the
longer term .

(I am disregarding, because it is unappealing, the

theoretical possibility that exchange rates can be stable in a world of
high inflation rates so long as the rates are the same in all
countries.)
Credit and Liquidity Risks in Foreign Exchange Markets
International diversification of portfolios imposes a second
discipline on central banks—the need for coordinated action to
address the credit and liquidity risks associated with the explosive
growth of foreign exchange transactions.

Participants in foreign

exchange markets have been aware that trading entails significant credit
and liquidity risks since 1974, when the failure of a relatively small
German financial institution, Bankhaus I.D. Herstatt, temporarily caused
substantial disruptions in both the foreign exchange markets and in
national payments systems.

Such risks arise primarily because there has

been no mechanism available to ensure simultaneous settlement of both
legs of a foreign exchange transaction.

During the interval between the

settlement of each leg, the party that has made the first payment risks
losing the full value of the second payment if its counterparty defaults
on its obligation.

In the Herstatt case, it had purchased various

European currencies in exchange for U.S. dollars.

Herstatt's

counterparties paid out the European currencies during European business

-4-

hours.

When Herstatt subsequently failed to meet its obligations to

deliver dollars, its counterparties were left with unsecured claims on a
bankrupt institution.
Since Herstatt's failure, the foreign exchange markets have
expanded enormously.

A survey conducted by central banks and released

recently by the Bank for International Settlements revealed that average
daily foreign exchange trading volume had reached at least $640 billion
in April 1989.

Moreover, trading had doubled during the previous three

years in the United Kingdom, the United States, Japan, and Canada, the
four major centers for which comparable data are available. This
surge will undoubtedly continue as exchange and capital controls are
eliminated in Europe and are generally reduced worldwide.
The credit and liquidity risks associated with foreign exchange
activities may have outpaced the growth of trading volume.

Given the

time differences between the Tokyo and New York business days,
settlement risks in foreign exchange trading—now commonly termed
Herstatt risks—are perhaps greatest for trades of Japanese yen against
U.S. dollars.

A party that sells yen in exchange for dollars must

irrevocably pay out the yen at least eight hours and most often fourteen
hours before it receives payment in U.S. dollars.

With the removal of

capital controls in Japan and its emergence as a major economic player,
yen-dollar trading activity now accounts for an important share of
overall activity in the foreign exchange markets.

Indeed, the BIS

survey revealed that yen-dollar trades account for 75 percent of foreign
exchange volume in Tokyo, which has emerged as the third largest center
for foreign exchange trading, after London and New York.

- 5 -

Cooperative Efforts by the Private Sector to Reduce Risks
During the past several years, market participants have begun
to focus on the credit and liquidity risks they face in existing
bilateral trading relationships.

Along with central banks, they are

considering legal arrangements that are designed to reduce these credit
and liquidity risks in the foreign exchange markets, as well as to
reduce transactions costs.

Market participants and central banks now

understand their mutual vulnerability to these risks, which can strain
national payment systems.
Dealers in foreign exchange typically enter into successive
contracts to pay or receive a particular currency, often for the same
delivery date and with the same counterparty.

The legal arrangements

that are being developed are designed to net out the amounts due between
counterparties by currency and delivery date.

If a market participant

defaults, these agreements are designed to ensure that the credit
exposure to any of its counterparties on unmatured contracts is the net
of unrealized gains and losses on those contracts rather than the gross
value of unrealized gains.
Existing arrangements for netting operate bilaterally, that is,
between a single pair of counterparties.

They are designed to reduce

risks by pulling together all contracts, whether spot or forward, into a
new agreement.

For example, FXnet, a London-based partnership formed by

several major international banks, has developed an agreement under
which trade confirmations for transactions between two banks are matched
and netted into a running account maintained between them for each
currency and delivery date.

Payments are to be made for the net

-6-

balances, due to or from each participant, in each currency on each
delivery date.

Twenty banks from four different countries are either

currently participating in FXnet or will begin to soon.

The benefits of

participation reportedly have been substantial—payment obligations and
associated credit exposures reportedly have been reduced by 50 to 60
percent.
Market participants and G-10 central banks currently are
studying the feasibility of multilateral netting arrangements for
foreign exchange contracts.

The proposals under consideration achieve

multilateral netting through creation of a central counterparty or
clearing house, whose legal structure is similar to existing clearing
houses affiliated with futures and options exchanges.

For each contract

submitted by a pair of participants, the central party would be
substituted as the counterparty to each participant.

The central

counterparty would maintain a running, legally binding net position visa-vis each participant for each currency and delivery date.

For a given

set of contracts, this process would leave each participant with net
amounts due to or due from the central counterparty that equalled its
multilateral net positions vis-a-vis the other participants in the
system as a group.
Specific proposals for such clearing houses currently are under
development by three groups of bankers in Canada, the United States, and
Europe.

At the moment, none of these proposals is fully developed and

implementation appears at least a year away.

Nonetheless, important

progress appears to have been made during the last year by each group of
bankers.

Moreover, I am pleased to note that a dialogue has been

- 7 -

established among the three groups and, as a result, certain key
features of the proposals have converged.

These bankers have recognized

that international cooperation in this area is essential.

Banks

participating in more than one of these systems obviously would prefer
to avoid maintaining multiple communications, confirmation, and other
back-office systems.

Preliminary studies by these groups of banks

suggest that multilateral netting could reduce gross payment obligations
by 80 percent or more.
Cooperative Efforts by Central Banks
The central banks of the G-10 countries have been studying

the

public policy implications of netting arrangements for foreign exchange
as well as other types of financial obligations and for payments.

Early

last year the BIS released a preliminary report by a working party of
payment experts, which I had the privilege of chairing.

That report

confirmed that netting arrangements have the potential to reduce
significantly the credit and liquidity risks in foreign exchange
markets.

However, it cautioned that the legal effectiveness of netting

agreements required careful study.

If participants should come to rely

on a netting arrangement that is not legally valid, they might allow the
true gross credit and liquidity exposures to exceed prudent levels.
Also, multilateral netting arrangements, in particular, require the
development of risk management systems that protect the financial
integrity of the clearing house.

Should the financial condition of a

clearing house become impaired, the report warned, serious systemic
credit and liquidity problems could develop.

Finally, the report also

identified a range of broader financial policy issues that would be

- 8 -

raised by implementation of foreign exchange clearing houses, including
the appropriate approach to their oversight by central banks and
supervisory authorities.
For the past year another G-10 committee has been thoroughly
reviewing the legal and risk management issues raised by netting
arrangements.

These studies should make possible a cooperative approach

to oversight of multilateral foreign exchange netting systems by central
banks and national bank supervisory authorities.

Cooperation in this

area clearly is critical, since both the host central bank for such a
system and each of the central banks whose currencies are accepted for
netting would have a vital interest in its operations.
For my part, I believe central banks should seriously consider
taking additional steps to facilitate the reduction of risks in the
foreign exchange markets.

The private sector, through well-designed

netting systems, can greatly reduce the risks associated with
settlements of foreign exchange obligations.

Central banks could

facilitate implementation of such systems by providing accounts through
which final, irrevocable settlements could be completed.

Central banks

also should consider more fundamental changes in central bank operations
that would allow simultaneous final settlement of both legs of a foreign
exchange transaction and thereby eliminate Herstatt risks.
There are a variety of measures that central banks could adopt
that would allow creation of such a delivery-against-payment mechanism.
One possibility is for central banks to extend their hours of operation
in their domestic currency.

Participants in the foreign exchange

markets could then discharge their payment obligations through

-9-

synchronized transfers of central bank balances.

Another possibility is

for a single central bank to offer accounts in multiple currencies.
Both legs of a foreign exchange transaction could then be discharged
through simultaneous transfers of credit on that central bank's books.
The offering of such services by central banks raises a number
of important issues, including the potential impact on the operation of
national money markets and the conduct of monetary policy.

In my view,

in considering any of these changes, coordination and cooperation among
central banks are essential.

With regard to those options that involve

one central bank offering accounts denominated in the currency of
another central bank, I feel that due consideration needs to be given to
the views of the central bank of issue.

Implementation of such options

should be considered only after thorough consultations.
As many of you may know, my preference is for central banks to
extend their hours of operation.

Indeed, I have already proposed that

the Federal Reserve operate its Fedwire system 24 hours a day.

Some

have felt that extended hours would require further extensions of
daylight credit by the Federal Reserve.

However, I see no reason why an

active intraday market in federal funds would not develop that would
allow participants to meet their intraday credit needs without resort to
the central bank.

The pricing of federal reserve credit should induce

netting arrangements to develop that would privatize the risks currently
borne by the Federal Reserve.

If netting arrangements adopt loss

sharing agreements that create appropriate incentives for participants
to manage their counterparty risks, a far more efficient allocation of
intraday credit should result.

-10-

Not only would 24-hour operation of Fedwire allow Herstatt
risks to be eliminated for foreign exchange transactions involving the
dollar, but it also would allow timely final and irrevocable settlement
of other dollar-denominated obligations.

With financial markets moving

rapidly in the direction of round-the-clock trading, the availability of
a mechanism to achieve final settlement promptly has, in my view, become
increasingly urgent.