View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
lOsOO A.M. E.S.T.
December 10, 1987

Paper prepared by

Wayne D. Angell

Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

for

The Lehrman Institute

December 10, 1987
Ne w York, New York

A COMMODITY PRICE GUIDE TO MONETARY AGGREGATE TARGETING

"Few realize . . . that the money price of any commodity has to do not only
with that commodity but also with money, and that, therefore, a monetary ele­
ment enters into every price."
p. vii, MacMillan,

NY

(Irving Fisher, Why the Dollar is Shrinking,

1914)

The ultimate goal of the Federal Reserve must be to stabilize the general
price level.

The success of monetary aggregate targeting in achieving that

goal depends on a predictable income velocity of money and reliable inflation
indicators.

During most of the postwar era, the income velocity of money has

remained fairly predictable, even during periods of high inflation.

However,

since the mid 1970s, income velocity has become much more volatile.

Both

financial market deregulation and unexpectedly large portfolio shifts from
real to financial assets during transition from inflation to disinflation have
contributed to velocity uncertainty.

Given the possible slippage introduced

by shifting velocity, it becomes crucial to have timely and accurate in­
dicators of inflation to guide monetary policy.

The Fed has always tracked the movements in all reliable measures of
economic activity, and will continue to do so.
expanded role for commodity prices.

However, I am suggesting an

I am proposing a commodity price guide to

adjust short run money growth target ranqes.

I believe that commodity prices

-2-

can provide a reliable early signal of inflationary (or deflationary) pres­
sures.

There are two straightforward reasons for using commodity prices as

inflation indicators.

The first is data availability.
basis.

Commodity prices are reported on a daily

Even if inflation pressures affect measures of the general price level

and commodity prices at the same time, the statistics measuring the impact on
the general price level would not be available until three to four weeks
later.

Second, the prices of many commodities fluctuate freely in response to
changing current and expected supply and demand conditions, including the
effect of changed perceptions as to the scarcity of money.

Measures of the

general price level such as the CPI also reflect production costs —
for example —

which adjust only slowly .

wages,

Hence, we would expect current and

anticipated inflation pressures to show up more quickly in commodity prices.

The following chart displays the level and percentage changes in an arith­
metic average of constructions of nine commodity price indexes (Commodity
Research Bureau Spot and Futures, The Economist, Journal of Commerce, World
Bank developing country export weighted index, IMF world trade weighted index,
and three experimental Federal Reserve Board indexes) from 1967 to September
1987.

Peaks and troughs in the consumer price index (CPI) inflation cycle are

identified in the middle panel of the chart.

As the top panel of the chart

shows, commodity price changes precede both peaks and troughs in the inflation

-3-

Average of all Indexes vs. CPI Turning Points
(3-m onth average of 12-month growth rates)
PERCENT

CPI Turning Points
(3-m onth average of 12-month growth rates)

Average of all Indexes (level)

-4-

cycle with remarkable reliability.
about seven and one-half months.

The average lead time of this index is
Work done at the Federal Reserve Board shows

that this leading indicator property depends little on the precise composition
of the index.

The average time lag from a change in Ml to a change in the CPI

is between 15 and 24 months, falling closer to 15 months in the recent past.
Thus commodity prices can provide some of the advance warning needed to adjust
money growth rates in anticipation of general price-destabilizing forces,
rather than after observing the effects on the CPI.

In addition to accurately leading inflation turning points, we would like
the magnitude of changes in the index to bear a consistent relationship to the
magnitude of subsequent changes in the CPI.

The commodity price index in­

creases on average by four times the subsequent change in the CPI.
chart indicates, the variation in that ratio can be quite large.

As the
Its

volatility could change if the private sector's expectations react to the
Fed's monitoring the index more closely.

Since June of 1986, individuals at the Federal Reserve Board have
monitored the indexes summarized in chart one.

I have been particularly in­

terested in (1) whether a commodity price index would serve as a useful
indicator for monetary policy;

(2) whether monetary policy adjustments which

were signaled early by this index would prove to be appropriate ex post in
terms of stabilizing movements in general price level measurements such as the
CPI or the GNP fixed-weight deflator; and (3) whether the monetary policy
actions suggested by this proposal would eliminate trends in commodity prices.

-5-

Monetary policy which successfully uses commodity price signals to remove
trends from the general price level will simultaneously remove monetary trends
from commodity prices.

The flexibility of commodity prices suggests that we

would observe such changes first in commodity prices.

However, these

propositions and questions have not been fully answered and warrant further
examination.

I believe that both the rate of change of commodity prices and the general
level of commodity prices are important guides to policy adjustment.

The

reason is simply that a greater money growth rate adjustment may be necessary
if commodity prices are both high in level and rising, as opposed to rising
from an acceptable base level.

In order to illustrate how both the rate of

change and the general level of commodity prices interrelate in choosing a
policy adjustment, the following matrix of Ml target ranges is suggested.

1
1 Below Lower Limit
1
1
1Rapid
1 Above Top of Ml
% A
1Decrease|
Target Range
in
1
1
Commod. 1Moderate|
Top of Ml
Price 1Change I Target Range
Index 1
1
1Rapid
1 Midpoint of Ml
1Increase|
Target Range

Commodity Price Index Level
I Inside "Normal" Rangel Above Upper Limit
1
1
I
Top of Ml
| Midpoint of Ml
|
Target Range
|
Target Range
1
1
|
Midpoint of Ml
| Bottom of Ml
|
Target Range
| Target Range
1
1
I
Bottom of Ml
| Below Bottom of
|
Target Range
| Ml Target Range

This policy adjustment matrix serves as a means of illustrating the in­
dicator role commodity prices could play in monetary policy.

The actual

implementation of such a plan requires sorting out a good many details. For

|
1
|
|
1
|
|
1
|
|

-6-

example, we must recognize uncertainty as to the scale at which we make ad­
justments.

While we do not wish to "fine-tune,11 it is important to be

prepared to "lean against the wind" so as to prevent significant upward or
downward trends in the general price level.

We need also to develop methods

to discredit "false signals" in the commodity price index —

episodes in which

the index shows a pronounced change which does not appear in subsequent CPI
movements.

The average index shown in the chart gave false signals in only

three episodes in the sixty-seven years from 1920 through 1987, and only once
in the last twenty years.

In addition, constructing an appropriate commodity price index requires
some care,

Ideally, an index to be used as an inflation indicator should

comprise components with the following characteristics:
1. Each component of the index should reliably anticipate general price
level movements.
2. Each component of the index should be storable and thus a potential
store of value.

This allows the commodity price to provide signals of

anticipated inflation over a moderate time horizon.
3. The price of each component should be flexible, responding quickly to
changes in both general price level influences and their specific sup­
ply and demand changes.
4. Components in the index should be free from frequent and severe supply
disruptions.
5. The price of each component should be determined and quoted on a con­
tinuous auction market.

-7-

6. The price of each component should be determined in markets with large
numbers of buyers and sellers, unlikely to be influenced by cartels.
7. The weights of each component in the composite index should correspond
to performance based on the above criteria.
In practice, it is difficult to construct one index which satisfies all these
criteria.

However, as mentioned above, inflation indicator performance

seems robust to fairly wide variations in the commodity composition and
weighting method.

For this reason I use the average index to illustrate the

indicator properties of commodity prices.

I think of this proposal as a means of re-establishing a stable price
level which would be followed by a more stable money-price level relationship.
I think that many of us still feel that money, if properly measured, must have
a reliable link to the price level in the long run.
of Irving Fisher reflects that view.

The "quantity equation"

For the moment, we are in an unusual

period of financial deregulation and inflation uncertainty, both of which make
the definition of money and the predictability of money growth difficult.
Since our primary goal remains price stabilization, I would hope that using
these commodity price indexes to adjust our money targets would help us to
better achieve that goal.

In so doing, we will stabilize the value of money.

Once we have stabilized money's value, and once the financial deregulation has
run its course, I would hope to see again a more stable relationship between
money and the price level, one which the Fed can and will exploit to maintain
price stability.

-8-

Questions and Answers

Are you proposing a commodity price standard?
No.

I am proposing to use the information contained in commodity price

movements as an indicator of inflationary and deflationary pressures, to aid
the Fed in implementing monetary aggregate targeting.

With this information,

it can more appropriately adjust its monetary growth targets to ward off in­
flation in its early stages.

How will monitoring a general level of commodity prices work to control infla­
tion?
The answer is simply this: I believe that monetarism is correct
in insisting that controlling inflation requires monetary restraint.

This

proposal helps us to implement the stable money-price level relationship which
underlies the monetarist prescription.

The proposal is designed to make

monetary targeting more effective.

Can monetary policy control the general level of commodity prices?
The chart displayed above seems to indicate that commodity price movements
reflect inflationary and deflationary pressures.

To the extent that

these pressures are due to changes in the scarcity of money, commodity prices
are already affected by monetary policy.

The question of how that relation­

ship might change as agents become aware that the Fed more closely monitors
commodity prices is the subject of ongoing research at the Board.

-9-

Can inflation continue without a general rise in commodity prices?
I don't believe so.

Since general price level inflation is fundamentally

a monetary phenomenon, and part of any commodity price is determined by
monetary forces, commodity prices will rise or fall along with, or prior to,
all prices in a monetary inflation.

As the preceding chart shows, the period

of near-zero trend in commodity prices in the 1980s has been followed by a
zero trend in producer and consumer goods prices.

I believe that inflation in

the service sector cannot persist if we continue to avoid inflation in the
goods producing sector.

Why would we expect commodity prices to reflect anticipatory inflation infor­
mation?
First, since commodities are used as inputs to final manufactured goods,
the price paid for them today will subsequently be reflected in the final
goods price.

I should note that the magnitude of the contribution of com­

modity prices to the final price level is small as compared with the
contribution of other production costs.

More important is the reflective, or

indirect inflation signal provided by commodity prices.

Firms purchase com­

modities in part as reservoir for input to production, and in part as a good
investment when commodity prices are expected to rise.

If they are to hold

inventories in excess of normal production needs, they must on average earn an
inflation-adjusted, after-tax return which compares well with their alterna­
tive investments.

When investors expect inflation or deflation over the

investment period for a commodity, their demand for commodities will change
commodity prices today in order to maintain a competitive real return on the

-10-

investment.

An appreciation in commodity prices can therefore be expected to

precede general price inflation.

Aren't there other auction market prices which might serve the function that
you propose for commodity prices?
Yes, there are.

Both foreign exchange and treasury security auction

markets can play such a role, and of course do to a certain extent now.

These

auction markets can provide us with information which will either confirm or
contradict the information in commodity prices.

When we observe reinforcing

signals in all auction markets, we can be fairly sure that a significant price
level change will occur, and adjust money growth accordingly.

How do you distinguish between monetary and non-monetary shocks in the com­
modity price index?
In essence, monitoring an index, rather than specific components, aids
greatly in making the distinction.

If the general level of commodity prices

is rising, this is far more likely due to a monetary shock than to a set of
coinciding, reinforcing shocks to the specific commodity markets in the index.

Some claim that any attempt to stabilize commodity prices would increase the
volatility of real activity.

Do you believe this?

I believe just the opposite.

I feel that excess inventory accumulation

in anticipation of inventory profits magnifies the amplitude of the normal
recession cycle.

If the Federal Reserve is successful in curtailing inflation

-11-

at its early stages, much of the incentive for building up speculative inven­
tory stocks will be removed.

This may help to reduce the magnitude of

inventory related business cycles.

Exchange rates also indicate the relative scarcity of U.S. money.

Why should

commodity prices be a more appropriate guide to monetary policy than exchange
rates?
Exchange rates move as a result of both U.S. and foreign policy actions.
For example, an appreciation in the dollar-yen exchange rate may reflect per­
ceived tight U.S. monetary policy or loose Japanese monetary policy.

Certain

commodities that are not readily transportable will primarily reflect effects
of current and expected U.S. monetary policy.

Their prices may be better

indicators of the appropriateness of current U.S. monetary policy independent
of foreign policy actions.

######