View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

The Functions and Policies
of the

Federal Reserve System
W* P* G.




HARDING,

Qovernor

FEDERAL RESERVE BOARD

PUBLISHED BY

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF PHILADELPHIA

The Functions and Policies
of the

Federal Reserve System
oAddress by
W* P. G* HARDING, Qovernor
FEDERAL RESERVE BOARD

Before the Chamber of Commerce
of Cleveland, Ohio




SEPTEMBER 16,

1920

PUBLISHED BY
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF PHILADELPHIA




The Functions and Policies of the
Federal Reserve System
T H E Federal reserve system is now passing through
a crucial stage of its existence. Despite the publicity which has always been given to its operations
from the beginning and the efforts that have been
made to explain the principles and objects of the
Federal Reserve Act, there is still a wide-spread misunderstanding of the functions, policies, powers, and
limitations of the Federal reserve banks and of the
Federal Reserve Board.
The fundamental objects in establishing the Federal reserve banks, as defined in the short title of the
Act, were "to furnish an elastic currency, to afford
means of rediscounting commercial paper, and to establish a more effective supervision of banking in the
United States."
The experience of the past four years has demonstrated the expansive power of the Federal reserve
system, but an elastic system of Federal reserve bank
credit and note issue implies capacity to control and
power to curtail as well as to expand. The ability of
the system to check undue expansion and to induce
normal and healthy liquidation is still on trial.
The enactment of the Federal reserve law and of
its various amendments and the operation of the Federal reserve banks have brought about changes in
our banking structure hardly less marked than the
economic changes that have been caused by the world
war. Cash in vault and balances with banks other
than the Federal reserve banks no longer count as
lawful reserve for the member banks of the Federal
reserve system—their entire reserve must now be
carried with the Federal reserve banks. The lend-




[3]

Functions and Policies of Federal Reserve

System

ing power of the member banks has been greatly increased because of the substantial reduction, in more
than 50 per cent, in the reserve they are required to
carry and because of the phenomenal growth in their
deposits, without taking into account the greatly extended rediscount facilities afforded them by the Federal reserve banks and the power given them in the
Federal Reserve Act to lend their credit by accepting
drafts drawn upon them in domestic transactions involving the shipment of goods and in transactions
growing out of importations and exportations. No
one has denied that our old banking system, with the
rigidity of its currency and with the limitations upon
its rediscount facilities, would have collapsed under
the strain which would have been imposed upon it by
war conditions. Even had there been no war, the old
system would have been unable to respond to the
business requirements of the present day.
The Federal reserve banks, as the custodians of
the ultimate banking reserves of the country, as the
mainstay of the acceptance market, as the agencies of
last resort in the matter of rediscounts, and as the
media through which so large and important a part
of the currency is issued, must always be kept in an
absolutely sound and strong position. Their strength
must be measured by the liquidity and intrinsic value
of their invested assets, which include rediscounts for
member banks, as well as by the proportion of gold
and lawful money to their liabilities. A gold reserve is essential to a sound financial system. This
percentage of reserve ought normally to be considerably higher than the minimum required by law, in
order to provide ample margin for meeting unusually
large seasonal requirements and unexpected emergencies, but even though the reserve should fall temporarily below legal requirements, there would be no
[4]




Functions and Policies of Federal Reserve

System

occasion for uneasiness provided the assets of the
banks are of the self-liquidating character which
would admit of the restoration of the reserve within
a reasonable time. It would be folly to inflict serious
injury upon agriculture, commerce, and industry
merely for the sake of maintaining an arbitrary minimum reserve, but it would be still more consummate
folly to treat a low reserve position, brought about
by an emergency, as a normal baste from which future
emergencie? are to be met.
The average reserve now required of all national
banks is about 8 per cent of their net deposits. As
this reserve must be carried with the Federal reserve
bank, it will amount to 8 per cent in terms of gold and
lawful money, only when the reserve of the Federal
reserve bank is 100 per cent of its liabilities, and it
is reduced pari passu as the reserve of the Federal
reserve bank declines. There are some who believe
that the minimum reserve required by law may be
lightly infringed upon, for they say "what is a reserve
for, if it is not to use." Some who hold these views
are fond of referring to the case of a hospital where
all the beds are occupied except a few which are held
in reserve. The ambulance brings in a badly injured
man, who is denied admission upon the ground that
all the beds are full. The ambulance surgeon points
to two or three unoccupied beds and is met with the
response, "Those are reserve beds and can not be
used." Certainly any hospital under sane management would use those beds in case of real emergency,
but would not permit their use by strangers of sound
and healthy appearance who might have been unable
to obtain hotel accommodations, or by husky hoboes
who find park benches too hard for comfort, nor
would a hospital with the capacity taxed to the limit




[5]

Functions and Policies of Federal Reserve

System

encourage convalescent patients to remain a day
longer than necessary.
The law fixes the minimum reserve to be carried
by Federal reserve banks against their note issues
at 40 per cent, and against their member banks' deposits at 35 per cent. I t permits temporary suspension by the Federal Reserve Board of these minimum
reserves under certain graduated penalties, but in
order to illustrate the danger of regarding the legal
minimum as the normal base from which to operate,
I would like you to consider what would be the outcome if we had to meet another emergency such as
war, with Federal reserve bank Reserves jat their
present level. When a state of war was declared on
April 6, 1917, the combined reserves against deposits
and note issues of all Federal reserve banks averaged
84.7 per cent. Due to this condition the United
States was able to meet all financial obligations incurred without any impairment of its own ability or
of that of the banks to redeem currency in gold, thus
preserving the parity of all forms of money in circulation. This was an achievement impossible of accomplishment during the Civil War, when current prices
were quoted in terms of irredeemable paper money,
which was not brought back to a parity with gold
until fourteen years after the close of the war.
Early in January, 1919, shortly after the armistice,
the combined reserve of the Federal reserve banks
was 51.3 per cent, showing a diminution of 33.4 per
cent from the date of our country's entry into the war.
The gold embargo was removed in June, 1919, when
large amounts of gold held for foreign account were
released. Even after this the reserves stood at 51
per cent on September 26th, after which date they
showed a steady and continuous decline to 44.8 per
cent at the close of the year.
[6]




Functions and Policies of Federal Reserve

System

During the last six months of the year 1919, tendencies towards unrestrained extravagance and abuse
of credit were manifest all over the country. I t became evident that the rediscount facilities of the Federal reserve banks were being used too freely and
that unless corrective measures were applied the situation would become exceedingly dangerous. The rediscount rates of the Federal reserve banks were
much below the market rates for money, thus affording member banks an opportunity for profit in their
rediscount transactions, and making it exceedingly
difficult to keep in check borrowing demands made
upon them. The Federal Reserve Board and the Federal reserve banks, while recognizing the necessity
of holding these dangerous tendencies in check by
means of a reasonable and effective control of credit
in order that its flow might be once more regulated
and related to the economic welfare of the country
and the needs of its producing industries, were reluctant to take any precipitate action. I t was realized
that productive industries are profoundly affected by
credit conditions, that modern business is done on
credit and that the mood and temper of the business
community are deeply affected by the state of credit
and may be easily disturbed by ill-considered or hasty
action. The test of the functioning of a credit system
must be found in what it does to promote the production and distribution of goods. I t is well understood
that too rapid or too drastic deflation would defeat
the very purpose of a well regulated credit system by
its unsettling effect upon productive industry. On the
other hand, over production at high cost on expanded
credit would be a grave menace. The Federal reserve authorities recognized the importance of avoiding extremes and their energies were therefore directed more particularly to the prevention of further




[7]

Functions and Policies of Federal Reserve

System

expansion for non-essential purposes and to the gradual and orderly liquidation of non-essential loans.
The predominant idea was not necessarily to reduce
the loan accounts of the banks of the country but to
bring about such a readjustment in them as would
ultimately lead to a restoration of a proper balance
between the volume of credit and the volume of concrete things, which credit helps to produce and which
are the normal basis of credit. The Board believes
that this equilibrium can be restored only by speeding
up the processes of production, by the orderly distribution of goods, by the avoidance of excessive consumption and by the increased accumulation of savings.
On several occasions, before changes were made in
the discount rates of the Federal reserve banks, the
Federal Reserve Board brought these matters to the
attention of the public with a view of testing thoroughly the theory that the credit situation could be
controlled without advancing the discount rates of the
Federal reserve banks. But because of the exhaustion
of capital throughout the world and of the universal
demand for credit, it soon developed that this was
impossible. Rates were advanced slightly during November, 1919, and again on January 23,1920, approximately to their present level. The rates established,
however, were still considerably lower than current
market rates. It became evident early in the spring
that no reduction in the total volume of loans was
taking place, and that unless a more discriminating
judgment was used by member banks in granting
accommodations, the country would be confronted
with a real crisis during the crop moving period, into
which we have now entered.
At a conference held last May between members of
the Federal Reserve Board, members of the Federal
[8]




Functions and Policies of Federal Reserve

System

Advisory Council and the Class "A," or banker, directors of the Federal reserve banks, there was an
exhaustive discussion of the banking and financial
situation. In presenting to the conference an outline
of the Board's views, I pointed out that since June 30,
1914, there had been an expansion of banking credit
in the United States, properly attributable to the war,
of $11,000,000,000, and that during the same period
there had been an increase in the volume of money
in actual circulation of about $1,900,000,000. When
it is considered that our Government during a period
of three years floated $26,000,000,000 of securities to
meet war requirements, the credit expansion which
had taken place could not be regarded as excessive or
alarming when viewed from the standpoint of war
necessity. Attention was called, however, to the continued expansion which had taken place since the
flotation of the Victory Loan in May, 1919, in the
face of a decreased production of essentials.
In order that you may understand the Board's
viewpoint of some of our major problems last May,
I shall quote literally from the statement presented
to the conference.
"It is this tendency of production to decline, particularly in some essential lines, which constitutes a
very unsatisfactory element in the present outlook.
It is evident that the country can not continue to
advance prices and wages, to curtail production, to
expand credits and to attempt to enrich itself by nonproductive operations and transactions without fostering discontent and radicalism, and that such a
course, if persisted in, will eventually bring on a real
crisis.
"The fact must be recognized that however desirable on general principles continued expansion of
trade and industry may be, such developments must




[9]

Functions and Policies of Federal Reserve

System

accommodate themselves to the actual supply of capital and credit available.
"Every effort should be made to stimulate necessary production, and to avoid waste. W a r waste and
war financing result inevitably in diminished supplies
of goods and increased volume of credits. The normal relationship between the volume of goods and the
volume of money and credits thus unsettled can be
restored in either of two ways; one, the drastic method
of contraction of credit, and the other, by far the more
desirable way, increased production. I n the same
way progress towards the restoration of the normal
relationship between goods and credit may be made
by reducing credit more rapidly than production is
diminished, or by increasing production at a greater
rate than credit is expanded. If it should prove impracticable in the existing circumstances to increase
essential production, then we must through economy
in consumption and through moderation in the use
of credit check the tendency towards a further widening of the margin between goods and credit.
"Our problem, therefore, is to check further expansion and to bring about a normal and healthy
liquidation without curtailing essential production
and without shock to industry, and, as far as possible,
without any disturbance to legitimate commerce and
business.
"Regardless of the extent of its legal powers, it
would be a most difficult task for the Federal Reserve
Board to attempt by general rule of country-wide
application to distinguish between 'essential' and 'nonessential' loans. During the war there was a broad
underlying principle that essentials must be 'necessary
or contributory to the conduct of the war,' but notwithstanding the sharp outline of this principle much
difficulty was experienced by the various war boards
[10]




Functions and Policies of Federal Reserve

System

in defining essentials and non-essentials. I t would
be all the more difficult for the Federal Reserve Board
to make such a general definition now when there is
no longer that purpose as a guide.
"Section 13 of the Federal Reserve Act in defining
the eligibility of paper for discount by Federal reserve
banks lays down the general rule that any paper maturing within the time prescribed, and issued or drawn
for commercial, agricultural or industrial purposes,
or the proceeds of which have been used or are to be
used for such purposes, is eligible. No express condition is made regarding the essential or non-essential
character of the transaction giving rise to a note
which may be offered for discount, and the Federal
Reserve Board is not required and properly could not
be expected generally to adopt such a criterion of
eligibility. I t is too much a matter of local conditions
and local knowledge to justify at this time any general country-wide ruling by the Board even if such
a ruling were deemed helpful.
"On the other hand, there is nothing in the Federal
Reserve Act which requires a Federal reserve bank
to make any investment or to rediscount any particular paper or class of paper. The directors of a
Federal reserve bank are, however, required by law
to administer its affairs 'fairly and impartially and
without discrimination in favor of or against any
member bank/ and subject to the provisions of law
and the orders of the Federal Reserve Board to extend 'to each member bank such discounts, advancements and accommodations as may be safely and reasonably made with due regard for the claims and
demands of other member banks.' Thus the directors
of a Federal reserve bank have the power to limit
the volume and character of loans which in their judg-




en]

Functions and Policies of Federal Reserve

System

ment may be safely and reasonably made to any member bank.
"It is the view of the Board, however, that while
Federal reserve banks might properly undertake in
their transactions with member banks to discriminate
between essential and non-essential loans, nevertheless that discrimination could much better be made at
the source by the member banks themselves. The individual banker comes in direct contact with his customer; he is better qualified than anyone else to advise him because of his familiarity, not only with the
customer's business but with general business conditions and needs in his immediate locality. H e is
entirely free to exercise discretion and can make one
loan and decline another as his judgment may dictate.
H e can estimate with a fair degree of accuracy the
legitimate demands for credit which are liable to be
made upon him, as well as the fluctuations in the volume of his deposits. He knows what industries sustain his community, and is thus qualified to pass upon
the essential and non-essential character of loans
offered him. H e knows, or should know, what rediscount line he may reasonably expect of his Federal
reserve bank, and he ought not to regard this line
as a permanent addition to his capital. With knowledge of the limitations or penalties put upon his borrowings from the Federal reserve bank the banker
must be depended upon to use a more discriminating
judgment in granting credit accommodations to his
customers.
"It is true that under existing conditions the volume of credit required in any transaction is much
greater than was the case in pre-war times, but it is
also true that the resources of the member and nonmember banks would be ample to take care of the
essential business of the country and to a large extent
[12]




Functions and Policies of Federal Reserve

System

of non-essentials as well if there were a freer flow of
goods and credit. If 'frozen loans' were liquified,
and if commodities which are held back either for
speculative purposes or because of lack of transportation facilities should go to the markets, and if large
stocks of merchandise should be reduced, the resultant release of credit would have a most beneficial
effect upon the general situation. I n the meantime
everything must be done to expedite the release of
these credits and to restrict non-essential credits in
future.
"While the problem of credit regulation and control is national and even international in its scope, yet
in the last analysis it is merely an aggregation of individual problems, and the proper working out of the
situation must depend upon the public and upon the
banks which deal with the public. The public should
realize the necessity of economy in expenditures and
in consequent demands for banking credit. The banks
themselves are best able to impress the importance
of this policy upon the public, and both must do their
part in accelerating the processes of production and
distribution and in restricting waste and extravagance."
The policies outlined by the Board have, generally
speaking, met with the approval of solid banking and
business sentiment, and there has been since last
spring a marked improvement in the credit situation.
This is due to the better character and greater liquidity of bank credits rather than to any actual decrease
in the volume of credit. As a matter of fact, the expansion in loans and currency during the past twelve
months has been greater than for any like period in
the history of the country with the single exception
of the period between September, 1917, and September, 1918, when we were in the midst of the war.




[13]

Functions and Policies of Federal Reserve

System

I wish to call your attention to a comparative statement showing certain items of resources and liabilities
of the Federal reserve banks as of the last Friday in
August, 1918, 1919, and 1920.
August 29,1919

August 27,1920

Total Gold Reserves .$2,013,794,000
Legal Tender Notes,
Silver, etc
53,168,000

August, 30,1918

$2,066,788,000

$1,971,825,000

69,188,000

156,002,000

Total Cash Reserves.. $2,066,962,000
Bills discounted secured by Government
War obligations . . .
896,333,000
All others
531,862,000
Bills bought in open
market
232,603,000

$2,135,976,000

$2,127,827,000

1,609,296,000
205,838,000

1,314,830,000
1,352,297,000

363,138,000

321,965,000

Total bills on hand... 1,660,798,000
(Long-term Securities)
United States Government Bonds
30,350,000
Victory Notes
T?rea.surv
Certificates
of Indebtedness . . .
25,772,000
All other earning assets
67,000

2,178,272,000

2,989,092,000

27,096,000
198,000

26,810,000
69,000

243,411,000

273,701,000

Total earning assets .. 1,716,987,000
Government Deposits.
104,729,000
Due to Member Banks
(Reserve Acct.) . . . 1,478,639,000
F. R. Notes in actual
circulation
2,092,708,000
Federal Reserve Bank
notes
20,687,000

2,448,977,000
54,494,000

3,289,672,000
43,510,000

1,729,950,000

1,818,502,000

2,580,629,000

3,203,637,000

219,815,000

200,793,000

These figures show that the banks of the country
and the Federal reserve banks have functioned well
in meeting business requirements. While the process
of bond distribution and liquidation of loans secured
by Government obligations has proceeded steadily,
there has been a large expansion of commercial loans.
This expansion would be disquieting if the character
of the loans was not understood, but as long as the
advances are made on short time and for essential
[14]




Functions

and Policies of Federal

Reserve

System

purposes in connection with the processes of production and distribution of goods, there is no reason for
apprehension. There has been little change in the
actual reserve held by the Federal reserve banks
during the past two years, but the total amount of
bills held by them has increased from $1,660,798,000
on A u g u s t 30, 1918, to $2,178,272,000 on A u g u s t 29,
1919, and $2,989,092,000 on A u g u s t 27, 1920, the increase from A u g u s t 30, 1918, to A u g u s t 29, 1919,
having been $517,474,000, and from A u g u s t 29, 1919,
to A u g u s t 27, 1920, $810,820,000. T h e total amount
of bills held by the Federal reserve banks on J a n uary 23,1920, the date when the present rate schedule
became effective, was $2,729,247,000 so that the increase from that date to A u g u s t 27, 1920, has been
$259,845,000.
This increase in loans of the Federal reserve banks
during the past year is a net increase despite a reduction in bills secured by Government war obligations
of $294,466,000 and of bills bought in open market
of $41,173,000, the increase in all other bills, including
commercial rediscounts, having been $1,146,459,000.
On A u g u s t 30, 1918, Federal reserve notes in
actual circulation amounted to $2,092,708,000, on
A u g u s t 29, 1919, to $2,580,629,000 an increase of
$487,921,000, and on A u g u s t 27, 1920, to $3,203,637,000, an increase during the past year of $623,008,000. Since the end of August, this year, the crop
moving demands have accelerated, and Federal reserve note issues have increased at the rate of from
$30,000,000 to $40,000,000 a week, and bills discounted and bought by Federal reserve banks at the
rate of about $50,000,000 a week. T h e increase in
the volume of Federal reserve notes outstanding
from J a n u a r y 23, 1920, to August 27, 1920, was
$360,000,000.




[15]

Functions and Policies of Federal Reserve

System

Your attention is also invited to the following statement giving some of the figures furnished by a number of banks, including all of the more important
member banks in the Federal reserve and branch bank
cities and clearing house cities throughout the country.
For convenience they are designated as "reporting
member banks." Their resources are estimated to be
between 65 and 70 per cent of the resources of all
member banks and between 35 and 40 per cent of all
commercial banks in the country.
REPORTING MEMBER BANKS
Number of Reporting m e m b e r
banks
Liberty Bonds
Victory Notes
Certificates of indebtedness
U. S. Bonds securing circulation...

September 5,1919

September 3,1920

774
$636,804,000
316,489,000
1,334,416,000
269,393,000

819
$604,105,000
192,778,000
422,050,000
268,906,000

Total United States securities
owned
$2,557,102,000
Loans secured by Government obligations (x)
1,294,285,000
Loans secured by stocks and bonds
other than United States securities 2,956,596,000
All other loans and investments (x) 8,425,179,000

$1,487,839,000
695,291,000
3,044,120,000
10,286,315,000

Total loans and investments, exclusive of rediscounts
$15,233,162,000 $15,513,565,000
Total loans and investments, including rediscounts with F . R.
Banks
15,530,967,000
16,927,978,000
Reserve balances with F . R. Banks 1,342,058,000
1,394,957,000
Cash in vault
365,330,000
349,505,000
Net demand deposits
10,901,999,000
11,252,334,000
Time deposits
1,921,549,000
2,767,782,000
Government deposits
686,443,000
61,755,000
Bills payable with F. R. Banks
1,147,401,000
786,692,000
Bills discounted with F . R. Banks..
297,805,000
1,414,413,000
(x) Exclusive of bills rediscounted with other banks, including
Federal Reserve Banks.

The figures given in the foregoing table for September 5, 1919, were furnished by 774 member banks,
and those for September 3, 1920, by 819 member
[16]




Functions and Policies of Federal Reserve

System

banks. United States securities owned by all reporting member banks on September 5, 1919, amounted
to $2,557,102,000 against $1,487,839,000 on September 3, 1920, a decrease of $1,069,263,000, of which
$156,410,000 represents the permanent distribution
of Liberty Bonds and Victory Notes to the investing
public and $912,366,000 the decrease in the amount
of Treasury certificates held by the reporting banks.
During the same period the loans of these banks secured by Government obligations (exclusive of rediscounts) declined from $1,294,285,000 to $695,291,000, a decrease of $598,994,000. An increase of
$87,524,000 in loans secured by stocks and bonds other
than United States securities is not significant, but
all oth^r loans and investments, which include commercial loans (exclusive of rediscounts), increased
from $8,425,179,000 to $10,286,315,000 an increase of
$1,861,136,000, or 22.1 per cent. On January 23,
1920, the loans and investments (less rediscounts) of
the reporting member banks, exclusive of loans secured by Government obligations and by other stocks
and bonds, amounted to $9,505,927,000. The increase in these loans from that date up to September
3, 1920, has been $780,388,000, being an increase of
8.2 per cent for the period. If the increase is figured
on the amounts of loans, inclusive of rediscounts with
the Federal reserve banks, the increase since that date
works out at $1,252,379,000, or 12.3 per cent.
As shown in the table, total loans and investments
(exclusive of rediscounts) of these reporting member
banks show a net increase for the annual period covered from $15,233,162,000 to $15,513,565,000, or
$280,403,000. If the larger amounts of rediscounts
with the Federal reserve banks on the more recent
date are taken into account, an increase of $1,397,011,000 from $15,530,967,000 to $16,927,978,000 is shown.




[17]

Functions

and Policies of Federal

Reserve

System

Reserve * balances with Federal reserve banks and
cash in vault show a negligible increase of but $37,074,000, on the two items combined, while net demand
deposits of these reporting banks increased from
$10,901,999,000 to $11,252,334,000 or $350,335,000.
(Note:—Increase of time deposits due to a very large
extent to admission of California state banks and
trust companies with large savings deposits.)
D u r i n g the same time Government deposits held
by them declined from $686,443,000 to $61,755,000,
a loss of $624,688,000. Bills payable with F e d e r a l
reserve banks, consisting principally of member
banks' collateral notes secured by Government obligations, amounted on September 5, 1919, to $1,147,401,000, while on September 3, 1920, they had declined to $786,692,000, a decrease of $360,709,000.
O n September 5, 1919, the reporting member banks
showed bills discounted with Federal reserve banks
(this item includes commercial paper of various
types) amounting to $297,805,000, and on September 3, 1920, $1,414,413,000, an increase of $1,116,608,000. T h e total accommodation received by these
member banks from Federal reserve banks, being
the sum total of bills payable and bills rediscounted,
amounted on September 5, 1919, to $1,445,206,000,
and on September 3, 1920, to $2,201,105,000, an increase of $755,899,000.
I t is known that as a direct result of the discount
policy of the Federal reserve banks there has been a
very large decrease in the amount of speculative and
non-essential loans, and it is believed that the increase
in the loan account of these reporting member banks
has been due largely to a response to legitimate agricultural, commercial and industrial requirements.

[18]




Functions and Policies of Federal Reserve

System

The rapid expansion in loans which is just now
taking place is due, undoubtedly, to crop moving requirements. Seven Federal reserve banks are now
rediscounting paper with three other Federal reserve
banks, and at the close of business on September 9,
1920, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York had
rediscounted with other Federal reserve banks bills
receivable amounting to $35,250,000. The Federal
Reserve Rank of Richmond has rediscounted $20,
000,000; Atlanta, $30,200,000; St. Louis, $27,422,000; Minneapolis, $21,293,000; Kansas City, $18,902,000; and Dallas, $37,618,000; making a total of
rediscount transactions of $190,685,000. Of this
amount the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston advanced $76,195,000; the Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia, $4,000,000 and the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland, $110,490,000.
With the exception of New York all of the borrowing Federal reserve banks are located in agricultural
sections. The Federal Reserve Bank of New York
is the greatest single supporter of the acceptance
market and it is known that member banks in New
York City are lending heavily just now to country
banks in the farming sections. Consequently it is not
overstating the case to say that all of the Federal
reserve banks inter-bank borrowing is for crop moving purposes.
Your attention is called to a statement of bills discounted by Federal reserve banks in the South and
West which represent advances in support, directly
and indirectly, of agricultural and live stock interests.
Of the total amount of bills under discount as of
September 3, 1920, the Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond estimates that 27.3 per cent were in support of agricultural and live stock interests. The
Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta estimates its per-




[19]

rj
£
L J
~"

BILLS DISCOUNTED BY FEDERAL RESERVE BANKS IN THE SOUTH AND WEST WHICH
REPRESENT ADVANCES IN SUPPORT DIRECTLY OR INDIRECTLY
OF AGRICULTURAL AND LIVE STOCK INTERESTS
1
v*
, *
Federal Reserve
Bank

Richmond
Atlanta
Chicago
St. L o u i s
Minneapolis
Kansas City
Dallas
San Francisco

2

3

I ^
|
I 3.

4

Bills discounted
Discounts
^f^^"
^Sffl*
for members
* » ^ i W "
W
«S5Ji
outstanding
!L"MJ?2SS
in support of
In support of
w?™w^ioc>n an i^JJ/ a 0ck
aericuituraiand
agricultural and
September 3,1920
interests
live stock Interests live stock interests
Amounts in thousands of dollars
128,411
16,000
19,000
35,000
150,612
17,508 (a) 18,213
35,721
448,855
(b) 142,000 ( c ) 75,000
217,000
(d) 131,900
29,000
103,618
58,000 ( e ) 10,000
68,000
131,238
78,500
112,280
33,452
22,688
56,140
162,559
38,300
(f) 57,200
95,500

Ri

p„,«
"°of

R,

P,H«
"°of

P,H«
H *of

2 to 1

3 to 1

4 to 1

Per cent
12.5
11.6
31.6

Per cent
14.8
12.1
16.7

56.0

9.6

29.8
23.5

20.2
35.2

Per cent
27.3
23.7
48.3
22.0
65.6
59.8
50.0
58.7

I »
§
^i
.
^
©

|

2.
3

|

^
^
§

" £a
(a) Includes $13,200,000 advanced against Government war securities to banks in strictly agricultural
^
sections.
| §
(b) Includes loans made directly or indirectly to banks in strictly agricultural sections.
~
(c) Loans to industries directly allied with agriculture.
I ^
(d) Figures for August 13 to which date estimate of $29,000,000 of loans for agricultural and live CQ
stock purposes applies.
^
(e) Advances against Government war securities.
g*"
(f) Includes $24,300,000 advanced against Government war securities.



Functions and Policies of Federal Reserve

System

centage of agricultural and live stock bills to be 23,7
per cent, and this does not include the large amount
of export bills discounted by the New Orleans Branch
of the Federal Reserve Bank. At Chicago the percentage of paper rediscounted in support of agricultural and live stock interests to total bills held was 48.3
per cent; at St. Louis, 22 per cent; at Minneapolis,
65.6 per cent; Kansas City, 59.8 per cent; Dallas, 50
per cent, and at San Francisco, 58.7 per cent. The
total of bills discounted for member banks by these
eight Federal reserve banks on September 3rd was
$1,369,673,000.
As non-member banks cannot rediscount with Federal reserve banks and as by far the larger part of
the loans of member banks are made out of their own
resources, it is evident that the total of bank accommodations to agriculture and live stock interests are far
greater than the amounts rediscounted at the Federal
reserve banks. As a majority of these loans are
seasonal in their character, it is evident also that their
liquidation will do more than any other single factor
towards strengthening the banking position.
Speaking for myself personally, I desire to say,
however, that I am a firm believer in gradual and
orderly methods of marketing our great agricultural
staples. Agriculture is the most important of all industries, for upon its fruits depend the lives of those
engaged in all other industries. The farmer is a great
consumer of manufactured products and anything
that affects his buying power is soon reflected in the
business of the merchant and the manufacturer. While
the individual farmer may be just as well off with
small production and high prices, the mass of the
population is far better off with full production and
moderate prices. But farming as a business must be
remunerative or production will languish. I t is,




[21]

Functions and Policies of Federal Reserve

System

therefore, important that the efforts of the farmer be
supported and stimulated, that he be aided in preserving the full measure of his harvest and that he be
afforded an opportunity of marketing his products
on terms sufficiently profitable to warrant his staying
in the business of farming.
Great staple crops, the production of which extends
over a period of several months, must meet the requirements of consumption for a full year and in
order to prevent possibility of shortage it is desirable
that there be a reasonable surplus held over from one
crop pending the marketing of the next. The gradual
and orderly marketing of our great staple orops is,
therefore, a matter of importance both to producers
and consumers. The dumping upon the market within
a short period of time of a large part of a crop, consumption of which extends throughout the year,
means not only a loss to the producers, often to those
who can least afford it, but involves also a great strain
upon our transportation facilities and upon the banks
in providing the funds necessary for large purchases
in advance of actual requirements for consumption.
Dumping of farm products promotes speculation and
usually results in higher prices to the ultimate consumer. Farm products, however should not be
hoarded or held back from the market by the use of
credit merely in the hope of forcing prices up to an
artificial level. I t is estimated by some that the value
of this year's staple crops will be around $22,000,000,000, and it is manifestly impossible for any banking
system to provide funds to withhold these staples entirely from the market. There is no occasion to discuss the questions of public policy involved for it is
clear that the volume of our great staple crops is so
large and the value so enormous, that any efforts to
valorize them by means of bank credits would inevit[22]




Functions and Policies of Federal Reserve

System

ably result in disaster by the operation of economic
law. But I think that all reasonable assistance should
be given producers to enable them to market their
crops in an orderly way provided they are willing to
sell enough to meet current requirements and that
consumers should concede to the farmer reasonable
profits in order that future production may be adequate.
What is needed is an open market in which the law
of supply and demand is given free play and in which
buyer and seller may meet on equal terms. Theoretically at least it is possible, if adequate warehousing facilities are provided, for the farmer to obtain the benefit of the average price for the year without any increase in cost to the consumer and with lessened strain
upon transportation lines and banks by distributing
the marketing process over a reasonable period.
I have called your attention to figures which should
convince anyone that there has been no restriction
of credit for legitimate business but on the other
hand an unusually large expansion of credit. Exception is frequently taken, however, to the discount
rates now prevailing at the Federal reserve banks.
There lias been some criticism of the Federal reserve
banks' percentage of profits as related to their paid-in
capital. As is the case with other banking institutions, the earnings of the Federal reserve banks are
derived principally from interest on their loans and
investments. Their earnings vary according to the
volume of loans and with the rate of discount. The
return from $3,000,000,000 of invested assets at 6
per cent is exactly the same as that from $4,500,000,000 of loans at 4 per cent. While the Federal reserve
banks were not organized for the purpose of making
money, their present high rate of earning is unavoidable and would not be reduced by a reduction in the




[23]

Functions and Policies of Federal Reserve

System

discount rate, which would merely attract a larger
volume of rediscounts and involve a reduction in reserve already nearly at the legal minimum.
The law allows Federal reserve banks to retain
for distribution annually to their stockholding member banks, out of their net earnings, only an amount
equal to 6 per cent of their paid-in capital stock. The
remainder of their net earnings goes to the Government, either indirectly in the shape of additions to
surplus or directly as a franchise tax. Very large
payments will be made to the Treasury by the Federal
reserve banks next January which can be used in the
discretion of the Secretary of the Treasury either to
supplement the gold reserve held against outstanding
United States notes or they can be applied to the
reduction of the outstanding bonded indebtedness of
the United States.
Discount rates of a Federal reserve bank are established from time to time by the directors of the
bank, subject to the review and determination of the
Federal Reserve Board. The law provides further
that these rates shall be fixed with a view of "accommodating commerce and business." Section 13 of the
Federal Reserve Act provides that "nothing in this
Act contained shall be construed to prohibit notes,
drafts and bills of exchange, secured by staple agricultural products or other goods, wares or merchandise from being eligible for discount; but such definition shall not include notes, drafts or bills covering
merely investments, or issued or drawn for the purpose of carrying or trading in stocks, bonds or other
investment securities, except bonds and notes of the
Government of the United States."
There is a world wide demand for credit. There
are nearly $25,000,000,000 of Liberty Bonds, Victory
Notes and Treasury Certificates outstanding. Prom[24]




Functions and Policies of Federal Reserve

System

issory notes secured by any of these bonds or notes
of the United States are eligible for discount at the
Federal reserve banks. A low rate of discount at
the Federal reserve banks would attract heavy offerings of paper secured by these obligations, the proceeds of which could be used for any purpose and the
result would be that pressure on member banks for
loans of this character would be greatly increased,
and the lending power of the Federal reserve banks
absorbed by non-liquid loans in a very short time. The
Federal reserve banks would then lose their ability
to accommodate commerce and business.
As I have already pointed out, a thorough test was
made last year of the theory that the credit situation
could be controlled without advancing discount rates,
but it was found that control could not be effected by
an appeal to reason alone. As long as the customers
of banks were aware of the fact that the member banks
with which they dealt could lend them money and discount with the Federal reserve banks at a profit, it
was much more difficult for the member banks to refuse accommodations than is the case when they can
point out to would-be borrowers that member banks
can rediscount with Federal reserve banks only on
even terms or at a loss.
Interest rates at the Bank of England and other
central banks are higher than the current market
rates; for instance, the Bank of England rate is 7
per cent while current market rates in London range
from 6-% to 6-% per cent.
Interest rates are, in the last analysis, governed by
the time honored law of supply and demand. As the
demand for credit becomes less acute and as the supply of loanable funds increases, interest rates will fall.
Do not understand me, however, as attempting to
justify any effort to keep the general level of rates




[25]

Functions and Policies of Federal Reserve

System

above the Federal reserve bank discount rates, for
when our banking system reaches the point where
it can function normally the Federal reserve discount
rates ought always to be somewhat higher than the
current market rates.
If a member bank or a group of member banks
have been in the habit of charging customers interest
at the rate of, say, 6 per cent per annum, the mere
fact that these banks may be rediscounting 4 or 5
per cent of their total loans with the Federal reserve
bank at 6 or 7 per cent does not, in my judgment,
justify a corresponding increase in the member bank's
rate on all loans. However, this is a matter which the
member banks must settle with their own customers,
with the Comptroller of the Currency or the state
superintendent of banks as the case may be.
I n view, however, of the present insistent demand
for credit accommodations, I can appreciate the fact
that the pathway of the average member bank is not
strewn with roses. Our money market at present is
distinctly a lenders' and not a borrowers' market, and
banks all over the country are having applications for
loans which they cannot make and many of which they
would not care to make even during a period of extreme ease in the money market. However, I do not
think it altogether fair for any bank to say to an
applicant that it cannot make a loan because the Federal Reserve Board or the Federal reserve bank will
not permit it to do so. The Federal reserve authorities have no jurisdiction whatever over the loans which
the directors and officers of a member or non-member
bank may deem it expedient to make or to decline.
The Board's function is to define eligible paper under
the terms of the law and the managements of the Federal reserve banks use their judgment in discounting
offerings of eligible paper as defined by the Board.
[26]




Functions and Policies of Federal Reserve

System

All banks have perfectly good paper which is not
eligible for discount at the Federal reserve bank
under the terms of the law and it does not follow,
merely from the fact that any particular loan is technically eligible that it must necessarily be intrinsically
good.
The limitations upon the lending power of national
banks are defined in those sections of the Revised
Statutes of the United States known as the "National
Bank Act," and the banking departments of the respective states administer the laws applying to banking institutions operating under state charters. I
would like to have it distinctly understood that the
Federal Reserve Board has never sought to influence
a bank either to make or to decline a loan.
The Federal reserve banks are authorized to purchase in the open market bankers' acceptances and bills
of exchange of the kinds and maturities made eligible
for rediscount, but with this exception they have no
authority to deal directly with the public in their discount transactions; they are limited to eligible paper
endorsed by a member bank. The extent, however,
to which their discount facilities are now being used
shows that through the medium of member banks the
Federal reserve banks are participating actively in
extending credits.
I n order to show the tendency of the banks of the
country to lean more and more upon the Federal reserve banks, I would ask your attention to some
figures showing the amount of net deposits, loans and
discounts, and bills payable and rediscounts of national banks at corresponding periods during a series
of years, the figures being compiled from reports
made to the Comptroller of the Currency in response
to calls sent out by this office. I t is impossible to give
the exact figures for the state banks and trust compa-




[2T]

Functions and Policies of Federal Reserve

System

nies but the tendencies manifested in the national bank
figures relate also to other banks*
STATEMENT SHOWING NET (DEMAND PLUS GOVERNMENT
AND TIME) DEPOSITS, LOANS AND DISCOUNTS, ALSO
REDISCOUNTS AND BILLS PAYABLE OF NATIONAL
BANKS ON DATES OF COMPTROLLER'S
CALLS SPECIFIED BELOW
(In thousands of dollars)
Net demand
Loans and disTotal
JSHBLJ!
^
plus time
counts, gross, Rediscounts j l f f J H B E
Dates
and
i. e., including
and *%%*%?*
Government
rediscounts
Bills
.nSffiXJInj
deposits
and overdrafts
Payable toSS5SSr
September 4, 1906
5,024,641
4,331,459
48,842
1.13
August 22, 1907
5,399,367
4,709,027
59,177
1.26
September 23, 1908
5,809,887
4,781,522
53,285
1.11
September 4, 1912
7,140,596
6,061,009
82,375
1.36
September 12, 1914
7,362,621
6,417,910
150,071 2.34
September 12, 1916
10,247,920
7,921,070
91,893
1.16
September 11, 1917
11,676,340 9,234,289
285,104 3.09
August 31, 1918
12,412,213 10,111,113 1,294,005 12.8
September 12, 1919
14,561,218 11,541,503 1,505,516 13.04
June 30, 1920
15,008,567 13,623,892 2,205,633 16.2

The latest figures available at the Comptroller's
office are taken from the statements of June 30,192(h
On that date the net deposits of all national banks
were three times what they were on September 4,
1906, while loans and discounts had increased to the
same extent. Their investments, however, which include bonds and securities, more than make up the difference. Figures are given for ten years, between
1906 and 1920, and show an unbroken gain in deposits
as well as continuous increase in loans.
Your attention is directed particularly, however, to
the proportion of bills payable and rediscounts of all
national banks to their total volume of loans and discounts. On August 22, 1907, just before the panic
of that year, bills payable and rediscounts of all national banks amounted to $59,177,000 against total
loans and discounts of $4,709,027,000. The percent[28]




Functions and Policies of Federal Reserve

System

age of bills payable and rediscounts to total loans was
1.26 per cent- On September 23, 1908, the percentage was 1.11 per cent, on September 12, 1914, total
bills payable and rediscounts had increased to the unprecedented amount of $150,071,000 or 2.34 per cent
of the total loans which amounted to $6,417,910,000.
This increase was due to the disturbance incident to
the outbreak of the European war. On September
12, 1916, bills payable and rediscounts had fallen to
$91,893,000, or 1.16 per cent of the total of loans of
all national banks. On September 11, 1917 (the
first year of our participation in the war), bills payable and rediscounts amounted to $285,104,000, or
3.09 per cent of the total loans, which amounted to
$9,234,289,000. These figures, of course, reflect war
financing. The same observation will apply to figures
for August 31, 1918, and September 12, 1919, when
the percentages to total loans were 12.8 and 13.04
per cent respectively.
But there has been no new financing by the Government since the flotation of the Victory Loan; the total
volume of Government obligations outstanding has
decreased since September 12, 1919, when rediscounts
and bills payable of all national banks amounted to
$1,505,516,000, while on June 30, 1920, the national
banks' liability for money borrowed in this way
amounted to $2,205,633,000, or 16.2 per cent of their
total loans of $13,623,892,000.
In conclusion I would say that the Federal reserve
system is still confronted with conditions more or less
abnormal, but we have passed through the period of
exhilaration or intoxication which characterized
American business activities several months ago, and
notwithstanding the gloomy predictions which were
frequently made at that time the transition to a more
normal basis is proceeding quietly and without alarm-




[29]

Functions and Policies of Federal Reserve

System

ing features. Credit which is required for seasonal
needs is being granted, and business generally is looking forward to a fall and winter of at least average
activity. Sentiment is being helped by the bountiful
harvests, by the better outlook for the railroads and
by the knowledge that many highly essential developments which have been long deferred by force of circumstances, such as enlargement of our transportation
facilities and additions to housing accommodations
throughout the country, must soon be undertaken. A
broad demand, which will probably extend over a
period of years, is opening up for the products of our
basic industries, and if in the readjustments ahead of
us, any lines of business should prove to be overdone,
there is every assurance that any surplus of brains
and energy now engaged in such lines can be readily
utilized in other fields of activity.
We have problems confronting us and we shall always have them—but, as always in the past, we can
cope with them successfully if we approach them with
a spirit of confidence and self-reliance tempered with
common sense.

[30]