View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

W. Lee Hoskins, President
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

Center

for
Ge
Septembe

Processes

ty

SOME OBSERVATIONS ON CENTRAL BAÀIK ACCOUNTABILITY

It is not unusual to hear complaints about the performance of the Federal Resen¡e
System. Not surprisingly, sometimes these complaints reflect the System's

performance. In the 1970s the Federal Reserve mistakenly and regrettably paid too

little attention to inflation, a mistake that culminated in the enactntentof theFllt
Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978 (Humphrey-Hawki¡rs), with
provisions for reporting to Congress about economic conditions and monetary
targeting.
Today, even though inflation has hovered in the 4 percent range for the past six
years, the complaint is apt to be that the Federal Reserve System is notsufficien-rJy

sensitive to the Administration's economic priorities. Moreover, grumblings from
some quarters about the System's foreign exchange market operatioru in partnership

with the Treasury and the financial problems in the banking and th¡ift industries have
recently generated criticism of the System's discount window operations.
Today, I would like to disctrss these issues with you, and to do so we must step
back a bit and constnrct a framework for the dÍsctrssion. We must ask ourselves
several questions about central banks: What are thei¡ costs and benefits? Why should

we have them at all? Why do they need realistic and compatible goals? And how can
they be held accountable for achieving these goals without imposing other offsetting
costs upon society?

TheRationale for a C'overnnent-sponsored Central Bank
What is the justification for a central bank? Can some configuration of private

institutions in a so-called "free banking" environment better perform the functions of a
Sovernment-sponsored monetary authority? Are central banks even necessary?

-tA classic statement of the economic rationale for the existence of central banks
was provided by Milton Friedman in his 1959 Millar Lectures at Fordham University,

subsequently published as A Program for Monetary Stability. Professor Friedman,s
argument appealed fundamentally to the costs inherent in a pure commoditystandard system (e.g., gold). These costs arise both from pure resource costs and,
perhaps more significantly, from substantial short'run price variability resulting from

inertia in the adþstment of commodity-money supply to changes in demand. The
inefficiencies represented by these costs are a significant disadvantage of

commodity-money exchange systems.
As a consequence there is a natural tendenry, borne out by history, for pure

comrnodity standa¡ds to be superseded by fiat money. But particrrlar aspects of fiat
money systems

- such as fraudulent banking practices, "natural" monopoly

characteristics, and tendencies for localized banking failures to spread to the financial
system as a whole -- resulted in the active participation of government. We have come
to know this active participation as central banking.
These rationales have not gone unchallenged, not even by Professor Friedman

himself. Disruptions in payments can be costly, but so are the instabilities and
inefficiencies caused by the lack of an effective anchor for the price level in fiat money
systems. Moreover, theoretical discoveries in the area of finance and monetary
economics, closer attention to the lessons of historical banking an¿Lngements, and
advances in information and financial technologies have contributed to a healthy

skepticism about the superiority of central banks and government regulation to

alternative market arangements. For example, some of the financial backstop
functions performed by central banks and banking regulators may have weakened if
private market incentives to control and protect against risk.

-ç
Still, those who would argue for alternative monetary structn¡es must at least
recognize that their case rests on untested propositions. Yes, it would be foolish to
accept unthinkingly our current central banking setup as the best solution to problems

posed by the creation and maintenance of monetary systems in advanced economies.
But it would also be foolish to claim that the current practice of central banking does

not reflect progress in societ¡/s groping for solutions to those problems.

It is not sufficient to argue that market-oriented alternatives to our current central
banking structures functioned better in other times and places; for example, as it did

in eighteenth-cenhrry Scotland. This begs the question of why such a system did not
Prove to be sustainable. Nor is it sufficient to artue that this system would have

prevailed if not for government intervention and interference. This line of debate fails
to consider whether any political equilibrium exists that would support a

market-oriented system in a modern economy.

It is premature to claim that some hypothetical monetary system can, or should,
come to dominate institutional arrangements that have already evolved from

extended political and economic experience. I believe that the prudent first course is
to seriously consider the advantages of improving the performance of the Federal
Reserve System. The benefits of a properly managed fiat ctr¡rency are considerable,

and the issue today is, or should be, how to provide the Federal Reserve System with a

proper charter.

The

Heral

Reserv€ and Its Cha¡ter

Before the creation of the Federal Reserve, the country prospered without a

central bank. Broadly speaking, the historical impulse for the Federal Reserve's
creation in 1913 was a series of banking panics. These panics led to contractions in
money and credit in various regions of the country, often with serious consequences

for economic activity. The nation wanted to improve the functioning of its banking
system by establishing a mearu¡ for providing an "elastic money," but a money which
was, and would remain, fully convertible into gold

until lg3l.

-+
The Federal Reserve was born out of a compromise befween those who would
have kept the banking system entirely private, and those who wanted goverrunent to
assume a prominent role in a rapidly growing economy. Other nations have grappled

with the same problems and created similar institutions. Toda¡ the Soviet Union and
several eastern European nations are facing these same issues. We now have a world

monetary system in which governments monopolize the supply and management of

inconvertible fiat monies. Often using cent¡al banks as their agents, governments also
regulate banking activities.
The displacement of the commodity standard that prevailed at the time our

central bank was founded has exposed problems not otherwise envisioned in

lglg.

For example, we have no anchor for our price level except for that provided by the
Federal Resen¡e. The quadrupling of our price level since 1950 suggests that the
essential mandate of the Federal Reserve to ensure the viability of our monetary
exchange system by the maintenance of price stability is neither as explicit no¡ as

strong as would be desirable for the management of a fiat currency. I will argue that

if

the benefits of a fiat currency are to be achieved without large offsetting costs, the

gradual demise of our convertible monetary standard has brought us to a point that
requires a basic change to the framework within which the Federal Reserve System
functions.
The evolution of the global monetary system reflects a couunon, even if unstated,

acknowledgment that the benefits of a fiat monetary standard are substantial. Wise
administration of that standard requires a central ba¡rk in some capaciry. In this
context, the essential issue is this: How can nations achieve the benefits of a fiat
money standard and simultaneously constrain the exercise of that power to the service
of the public good? To put it another way, how can a nation prevent its central bank

from debasing the monetary standard it is charged to protect, or from undermining
the efficient functioning of the financial system it is charged with strengthening?

-5-

The answers to these questions can be found by giving the central bank clear

obþctives, and independence and accountability for achieving these objectives. The
problems that emanate from multiple and often incompatible objectives are well

known. To contribute to maximum economic growth over time, central banks must
achieve price level stabiliry and financial market efficiency. Achieving these goals

requires central banks to be free from political expediencies -- to have independence

within government. Along with that independence, central

banPis

should be clearly

accountable for attaining their objectives.
The objectives of the central bank are substantially determined by

ib legal

structure. For example, a clear legislative responsibility to achieve price-level goals
above all others would all but eliminate potential conflict with other objectives. The
vexing question of whether, and to what extent, a central bank should compromise the
objective of price stability in order to pursue auxiliary goals such as smoothing real

output fluctuations or stabilizing exchange rates, should be resolved in the legislative
charter.

rrdependence a¡rd Acrcountabilitr The case of Fiscal Domir¡ance
The consequences of concentrating power in a central bank were appreciated, and

much debated, at the time of the Fed's creation. Checlo and balances were woven

deliberately and carefully into the fabric of the Federal Reserve System. A "fi¡e wall',
was constructed between Congress and the executive branch, on one side, and the

monetary authority on the other, in order to diminish both the motive and means to
debase the value of the nation's money. The fire wall was Federal Reserve

accountability for monetary, rather than fiscal policy objectives. It was reinforced by
the Treasury-Federal Reserve Accord of '1957, which served as a clear statement that

the Fed would not be responsible for solving the federal government's debt

management problems. The institutional struch¡re was designed to ensure enough
Federal Reserve independence within the government to carry out this mandate

without interference.

-6-

What is the source of tension between monetary and fiscal authorities? Because
the creation of fiat money involves an implicit tax on money balances, the monetary

authority is one source of government revenues (last year the Federal Reserve System
paid nearly $25 billion to the Treasury). For the most part, the long-run viability of
the government's fiscal operations requires that its real current debt bu¡den plus the
present value of its expenditures equal the present value of revenues. Thus,

if the

path of debt plus expenditures diverges from the path of explicit tax revenues, fiscal

viability requires that the discrepancy be satisfied by seigniorage from monetary

growth. This scenario is typically referred to as "fiscal dominance" over the monetary
authority.
The dramatic increases in federal deficits in the early and mid-1.980s prompted

fiscal dominance believers to predict the impossibility of achieving and maintaining

inflation rates below the disastrous levels of the decade's sta¡t. So far, this prediction
has not come to pass. In 1983, the federal deficit was 3.8 percent of GNP, a level far

above the post-World War II average and nearly equal to the postwar peak realized in
7975. In the same yea\ CPI inflation fell to3.2 percent, a"!.6year

low. As the decade

proceeded, the deficit relative to GNP rose, fell, and rose again. The inflation rate was

impervious to these patterns.
Asttrte observers might question the relevance of this period to the fiscal
dominance proposition, because deficits as they are conventionally measured do not
necessarily reflect the government's long-run fiscal operations. To name just a few of
the problems, the value of long-run government net liabilities is inherently

ambiguous, the path of future revenues is uncertain, and the appropriate method of

discounting future tax and expenditure flows is problematic. Although sympathetic
to this view, I am still left with the very strong suspicion that if any period in our
recent history was ripe for the emergence of fiscal dominance, it was the last ten years.

-7-

Indeed, as the decade progressed and the predictions of the fiscal dominance
theory failed to materialize, more sophisticated variants of the relationship between
fiscal and monetary policy began to find their way into economic research. The fiscal

authorit¡/s reign over the subservient monetary authority was replaced by a more
subtle and complicated instihrtional structure, a world in which fiscal and monetary

authorities engaged in a "chicken game" whose outcome left both parties less than

tully satisfied.
Fortunately, if this analytical framework is acct¡rate, the outcome of such a contest
between monetary and fiscal policymakers has not yet proven to be detrimental to the
U.S. economy. The Federal Reserve's ability to resist monetizing the 1980s federal

debt buildup resulted in both lower inflation and, to some extent, the fiscal reforms
that started with the Gramm-Rudman-Hollings legislation and continued through last
year's budget agreement.

I am not suggesting that we should be satisfied by the present situation. Inflation
is still too high, and whatever progress has been made rests on a fragile commitment
to preserving

it.

about as high as

We should not ignore the fact that inflation in the past year was

inl97l, when President Nixon imposed

wage and price controls to

force the rate down. Reform of the process for setting fiscat priorities is still evolving,

and has been largely untested. Considering recent budget outcomes and projections,

it is not easy to find sigru of success. But inrportant lessoru were learned in the

1980s:

Lower inflation means better economic performance, and better inflation results can
be achieved almost regardless of fiscal

policy. There is every reason to believe that

the Treasury-Federal Reserve Accord was a prerequisite for this outcome.

-8-

Clear Obiectiv€s and WhereWe

LackThør

The fiscal dominance ctule provides an important lesson about the need for clear
objectives, accountability, and independence if our cenhal bank is to be successful at

achieving price stabilify and maintaining the integrity of our financial system.

Currently there is some measure of support for reducing inflation from its current
level. But what can explain a period such as the 1970s, when inflation spun out of
control? The story of that period is one of mistakes and wishful thinking by
economists and policyrrakers alike, acting on the view that the Federal Reserve could

manipulate the nonfinancial economy in predictable ways to soften or offset the oil
price shocks and to control the business cycle. This decade of unfortunate economic
performance would not have been possible with clear and realistic objectives and

priorities for the Federal Reserve. The Federal Reserve was not held sufficiently
accountable for achieving price stabilify.
Some of the ctrrrent discussions about monetary policy and the Federal Reserve

suggest that the lessons of the 7970s may be fading from. our memories. Calls for

lower interest rates or more rapid money growth are not at all unusual. More often
than not, those suggestions seem impelled by desires for more growtþ or to offset the
problems of partictrlar sectors of the economy. Th"y seem based on the notion that
there is a tradeoff between inflation and output or employment which may be

exploited by the actions of the central bank. We learned from the experience in the
'l'970s that such a
hradeoff does not exist. Instead higher

inflation only added to

uncertainty, distorted resource allocation, and reduced economic performance below
the maximum sustainable level possible with price stabilify.

-9The System's mandate for financial stability is also vague, raising some questioru

about the role played by discount window lending in recent bank failures. The

original intent of discount window lending,
which the Federal Reserve served

as the

as

I interpret history, was a mechanism by

lender of last resort. Such lending was

understood to apply to solvent institutions in temporary need of

liquidiÇ.

Recall that

at the time of the System's founding, there was not much of an interbank market for
banks to tap when

liquidity problems arose. Neither were national or international

capital markets very well developed. Today, by comparison, open market operations

in well developed national capital markets have much greater capability than in 1913
for providing adequate financial market liquidity.
As the role of the Fed in the economic policy arena evolved, so did the use of the
discount window. Until recently, discount window lending primarily functioned for
so-called "adjustment assistance," a technical operation associated with satis$""g

required reserve positions. The recent use of discount window lending in conþnction

with FDlC-directed operations at failing institutions is more troubling. By enabling
the FDIC to keep an insolvent bank open, the Federal Reserve makes it easier for the

regulators to avoid prompt closure of insolvent banks, thereby both adding to the
tendency for banks to take on risk and increasing the ultimate cost of bank failures to
the taxpayer.
Use of the discount window for temporary support of insolvent banks has

resulted in a situation that, at least in retrospect, appears outside the scope of the
Federal Reserve's intended responsibility. The impulse for these activities has almost

certainly been the belief that they were necessary to avoid systemic banking failures.

It also makes sense to me that, if both the FDIC and the Treasury seek the Federal
Reserye's help, then there are incentives to be a "team player."

-10-

The irony is that, lacking a clear set of rules and objectives, the Federal Resen¡e's

discount window activities can interfere with its mandate to protect the efficient and
safe functioning of the payments system. Findings in academic researcþ

supplemented by some bitter real-world experience, have brought into focus the
Perverse incentives created by regulatory policies that shift risk from individual

depositors to the public at large. By foctrsing on the fortunes of individual institutions
rather than the liquidify of the financial system as a whole, the lender of last resort
Process may very well have become distorted in a way that undermines what I believe

is the appropriate object of the Federal Rese¡ve or any central

bank

To promote the

stability and the efficiency of financial markets.
Another area in which accountabilify and clear objectives remain disturbingly
absent is the relationship between the Federal Reserve and the Treasury in the realm

of exchange-rate policy. Three of the past five administrations have, at various times,
chosen extensive direct intervention in foreign exchange markets to influence the

value of the dollar. Because direct intervention cannot be effective without basic
changes in monetary

policn the Federal Reserve, on these occasions, risked both its

credibility and loss to its own portfolio by participating with the Treasury in foreign
currency purchases and sales.
The Federal Reserve almost always "sterilizes" its exchange rate interventions

through offsetting domestic open market operations that leave the net money supply
unchanged. These foreign exchange tra¡rsactions do not compromise the integrity of
the Federal Reserve's price level objective precisely because they are sterilized or
offset.

-11-

Unsterilized interventio¡rs are nothing more than open market operations
conducted through the foreign exchange market rather than th¡ough the U.S.
government securities market. Unsterilized interventio¡rs in support of the Treasur¡/s
exchange-rate objective could work at cross-purposes to the pursuit of the System's

price stability objective. Subordinating the goal of price stability to the Treasur¡/s
desi¡ed exchange-rate poliry is unlikely to irnprove economic welfa¡e. But in the
absence of a clear statement of

priority for monetary policy objectives, the possibility

of such a sacrifice cannot be dismissed.

$¡nmary
As I have argued, the institutional design of the Fed has served the useful
PurPose of insulating monetary policy from the federal governmenfs debt policy.
Recent studies suggest that greater degrees of central bank independence from the

political Process lead to better inflation performance. In this regard, recent legislative
attempts to strengthen the role of the Treasury in the formulation of monetary policy
seem to me to work in the wrong direction.

The tire wall between monetary and fiscal policy, capped in 1951

by

the

Treasury-Federal Reserve Accord, should be strengthened by releasing the System

from responsibility for supporting the Treasur¡/s exchange-rate policies. We need a
Treasury-Federal Reserve Accord amendment for the twenfy-first century, one that
releases the latter from responsibility for supporting the formey's exchange-rate

policies.

Finally, presenration of the Federal Reserve's role in maintaining financial market

stability requires that we develop clearer guidelines for discount window activity.
Discount window lending must be confined to solvent institutions for the purpose of

forestalling systemic, rather than bank-specific, risk. To do otherwise can seriously
undermine the discipline provided by market mechanisms, and in so doing hamper
the Federal Reserve's stewardship of those very markets.

-72-

The precise features of changes to the Federal Reserve System can and should be

debated. Unfortunatel¡ much of the crrrrent discussion over Federal Reserve
independence, by foctrssing on the process of selecting System officials, falls wide of
the mark. Holding the institution accountable for an explicit objective lessens the

importance of how system officials are selected. For a nation to capture the
advantages proffered by central bank management of fiat money, the central bank

must be held accountable for achieving price stabiliry. The Neal Resolution, which
mandates that price stability should be the highest priority of the Federal Reserve and
sets

forth a specific time frame for achieving that goal, is a good approach. Attaining

price stabilify is essential for the economy to achieve its maximtun long-run growth.
Experience around the world and through time repeatedly demonstrate that

central ban-ks require independence from day-to-day political life to perform their
price stability role. If legal and ctrlhrral conditions could be created that tnrly fixed a
central bank with accountabilify for anchoring the price level, the structure of the
central bank itself would become a less important issue. Those circumstances would
be a joy to behold,

butl

am afraid they

will

be some time in coming.