View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

A Market-Based View of European Monetary Union

l,{. Lee Hoski ns , pres i dent
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

Conference on
The European Monetary System:

Its

Consequences for the Unity
of Europe and for the
International Monetary System

Organized by

the Instituto

Economia de Mercado
Avi I a, Spal n
March 3l-Apri 'l I I989

,

de

A

MARKET-BASED

VIEI{ OF

EUROPEAN MONETARY T'NION

by

IJ. Lee Hoskins
President

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

April 1,

1989

Relatfvely slow growth and high unemploynent over the past 10 years
suggest thaÈ the European Economic CornurunÍty has noÈ grown

potenÈial.

Many obserr¡ers

at its true

aÈtribute this shortfall--aÈ least ín part--to

restrictions, regulations, subsidies, and income guarantees Ëhat distort
markets and produce
renewed cor¡mitment
economic

inefficiencies wichin Europe.

integration, as Eacit

of restrainÈs in which

Pursue Èhe nost

view Europe,s

to policy coordinaÈion, with its interesc in eventual
acknowledgment

Policy coordinaÈÍon, however, is a
che web

One rnight

r¡e have

of a problen.

Èwo-edged

sword. It can cut

through

tied world markeEs, freeing them to

efficient allocation of resources. Or, it can sever

Ehe

incentive and informatíon,processes thaË markets uniquely possess, killing
hope
how

of maximizing production,

it will wield this

emplo¡rmenE, and

any

exchange. Europe nust choose

sword.

The drive to remove restrainEs on Ehe free flow of products, labor, and

capítal wÍthin the

EEC

is the most important goal. Subject to certain caveats

2

about polÍcy coordinaÈion, the slngle European market pronises exchange,

productÍon, and emplo)rnent opportunitles that are more conslsËent wfth
Europe's

potentÍal.

These gaÍns stem from

free markets and crade, with or

wlthout e monetery union. Nevertheless, a monetary unlon could supplement the
single narkeÈ by providing furrher efffciencies in che use of money.
Unfortunately, a well-known conflict exisËs between monetary union
exisEing European Ínstitutions.
exchange-rate nechanism),

and

Fixed exchange rates (as under the

free capital

movemenÈs

(as under a slngle market)

and national monetery sovereigncy are incompatible. The

EEC

nust then

make a

choÍce: sacrifice one of chese three to protect the other Èwo. My Èask is to
offer the observations of an outsider abouE thfs choíce, about Èhe
alternaÈlves this dlleurma presents, and abouÈ lts irnplications for both the
European l'fonetary Systen and

the international financial

As many European leaders have noted, Europe
degree

of polltÍcal, social, and cultural

monetary sovereignty and

effect a full

will not

communi¡y.

soon achieve the high

1nÈegratÍon necessary

moneËary

union. under

to relingutsh

these

circumstances, floating exchange rates offer the best meens of maximizing

efficfency gains from a single market and free capiÈal movements.
floatíng rates do noE preclude an eventual moneÈary unÍon,

che

Moreover,

UltimaEelY, we will judge the success of any monetary union in Europe by
Èhe

long-term real growth and employment Èhat it fosÈers. As I will

Èhese depend more on Ehe exÈent

labor,

and

argue,

to which Europe liberalizes iÈs product,

capital markets than on the

advantages

of

moneEary union.

3

The European Economic Community

is inltiating

some 300

actlons co

remove

physical, Èechnlcal, and fiscal barriers to freer markets. Ttre removal of
these barrlers Èo the

free flow of products, services, labor,

and capiÈal

pronises enormor¡s gains from speciallzation, conpetiËlon, and economies of

scale. Already firns in

to take

of wíder markets. Nevertheless, the removal of barriers

advantage

member sÈates

These

Europe are consolidating and investing

is not

enough

require thaÈ the

individual

members and

EEC

in itself to

guarantee

go beyond Ehe removal

âmong

overall efficiency gains.

of barriers ¡nong its

adopt more general policies that liberalize markets

and

chat aIlow prices Èo convey inforrnation about relative scarcltÍes. Two widely
discussed concerns along these lines have

to

with the "leve1ing up" of

do

regulaËion and the creation of barriers to external Èrade.
Many observers,

especlally the British, have expressed concerrt thaÈ, in

the drive toward a unified Europe, a pattern of supranaÈional regulaclon

and

subsidization will supplant Èhe concept of a single liberalized narket.
InsEead

of breaking

Community

down

barriers, restrictÍons,

and conÈrols, the European

could "leveÌ them up," creating a new bureaucracy

and

competition-sÈifling patronage within the

"o*r,rnicy.l This kind of policy
coordination would limit potential gains in production, employment, and
exchange opporÈunities

in Europe. Replacing 12 individual markets wÍth

a

single rnarket does not, in icself , diminish renÈ-seeking, as r¡¡e have seen with
Europe's

Common

Similarly,
Ehe cornmunity

Agricultural Policy.

some

of us from outside the

European CommuniEy wonder whether

will restricE external competition. Over the pasE 40 years,

Ehe

4

trading world--ofEen led by the EEC--has lorvered Èariffs and removed quotas.
But after substantial gains during the 1950s and 1960s, the progress slowed.
Although Èhe overall level of inport restrainÈ night noÈ be hlgher now Èhan 40
years ago, trade restrainÈs remain an important feaÈure of European and
worldwide trade.

Moreover, these restraints have become nore sophlsticated,

more discreÈionary, less visible,

than the traditional

tariffs

and even less responsive to market forces

that they replaced.

All current rhetoric aside, the Erading world lacks fírm coumitment to the
principles of free trade.

We

live in a neo-mercanÈÍlist environment where

market access ofËen is more a function of bilateral,

product-speclfic

negoÈiating skills than the result of competitive sErengths. Such types of

policy coordÍnation have enormous cosÈs.
A further concern, which has not received enough attention, focuses on

price-level stability.

The EEC could enhance the gains from a single market

if its members adopted a stable-price policy.2

Inflation

itself

involves

costs ln terms of nisallocaEed resources. It adds "noisen to prices, which
distorts the informaEion about relative scarcities conveyed through price
changes. Through interactions v¡ith tax systems, inflation
investment and financial decisions.

inflation

can affect firms,

Ifhile these costs are greatest

is high and variable and difficult

when

to predicÈ, they are presenc at

Ehe moderate levels observed in the united staËes and the EEC today.

Inflation also leads to che creation of socially inefficienc instÍtucions, .
designed to ProtecE individuals against inflation-induced

financial assets.

We

losses on money and

would see far fewer transactions in futures markeÈs for

exchange rates and interest rates in an inflation-free

world.

5

Flnally, evidence froru a large set of countries, wiÈh very dffferent
lnstltutions and econonlc condicions, lndfcaÈes thaE persiscenÈ lnflaclon
erodes long-term econonlc

growth.

The

inefficiencies

and dlsÈorÈfons

wlth inflaclon reduce resources available for capital fornatÍon

associaÈed

encourege investments thaÈ have qulck payback perlods,

and

rather than longer-Èentr

groe¡th poEential.
The creation

of a slngle

European market, together r¡1ch a more general

of a liberal-market philosophy

acceptance

and a commitment Èo zero inflaÈion,

r¡ill confer substantfal gains on Europe, with or without a moneÈary union.

To

be sure, however, a s¡rmbÍotic relationship exists between a single ÍnÈernal
markeÈ and a monetary

union. A monetary union could enhance the beneflÈs of

a

single internal rnarket by providing efficiencÍes in the use of Eoney, and a
single internal narket could strengchen a com¡nÍtment to price stabillty
throughout Europe. Of Èhese two, Èhe creation of a single internal market
undoubtedly

is the

more imporËanÈ. Beyond the

efficiency gains that I

have

descrÍbed, iÈ Ís Èhe sine oua non of monetary union.
rndencifying rhe potenËial gains from nonecary union ls easy,

buÈ

achieving them--if they are at all achievable--is quite a different matter.
The

EEC

heads

of

sËaÈe charged

the Delors

examining and proposing sËeps Èolrard a
Commission

wíll reporc its findings in

importance and the urgency

of

Commission r.¡ith

co¡nmon moneËary

June

1989.

the arduous task of

polÍcy in Europe.

One can

appreciate

Ehe

Èhe Commission's work by considering.the dilenna

Èhat a single European markeË poses under existing European institutions.
Illany economists have noËed,

The

the objectives of free capital

by the single market, of relatiwely fixed

exchange

movements

rates as provided

As

as sought
Èhrough

6

Èhe exlsElng exchange-rate mechanism (ER.}{), end

of

moneÈary lndependence among

sovereign nations are mutually lncompaÈlble. Hlscory suggescs that caplCal

flows usually bear the burden of resolvtng thfs incompatibilicy.

l{ill che indfvfdual

mernber counÈries

of the

EEc gfve up

thelr natl.onal

sovereignty over Donetary policy? My guess 1s not ln the foreseeable future.

llhat then are

Èhe

alternatives for the

Can Eurooe Afford the
One

European Economíc conmunlty?

EMS?

alternative ls to go forward with the El,fS. However, Ëhe present EìMS

policy of attempting to maintain fixed central
flexibility

around them

will prove

more

exchange

dífficult as

rates with lirnited

Europe

liberalizes

capital flows. Theory Èells us that indívidual countries cannot conduct
ÍndependenÈ monetary policies under a system of rlgfdly held exchange races
wich free capital urobility. Countries that inflate their economies above the
average leveI

deficit

of their tradÍng partners wÍ11 incur a balance-of-payrnents

will tend to lose reserves. Countries wÍth relatively low
inflation rates will tend to gain reserves. The inflacion-prone countries
and

will experience a subsequent monetary contraction, while

Èhe

laËter will

experience a monetary expansÍon.

AIso, as this discussion suggests, a system rvith nobile capiÈal and fixed
exchange

rates leaves countrÍes vulnerable to external rnonetary shocks.

Èhe Bretton l.Ioods

fixed-rate

sysÈem, many countries--notably Gerrnany and

France-'complained about importing

late

1960s and

Under

inflation from the United

Stat.es during the

early 1970s. Only as long as member countries have similar

preferences for inflacion are fixed exchange-rate mechanisms sustainable.

7

Most observers would agree Èhat European pollclmakers do not give

sinilar

weight to inflatÍon in formulating Èheir monetary policies. Overall,

Germany

sErives for a lower rate of inflation than
Alchough

fnflatlon differentials

other European

mosÈ

governmencs.

anong Èhe European countries have narrowed

since the early 1980s, thís developmenÈ does not represent a convergence
European policymakers Èo

a similar enphasls on Ínflatlon.

Inconpatible

inflacion obJecclves often contribute to substanÈlal capical flows
participants and to rearignments of the ERM. Moreover, inflaÈfon
differentials

seem

to

prevenË more European countries from

to resolve this incompatibÍlity

AttemPts

between

among

arnong

joining the

ERM

ERM.

liberal capital

national monetary sovereigntT, and fixed exchange rates through
more policy coordination can add to market distortions ËhaE lower enplo¡rment
movemenÈs,

and

outPut.

The

desire co limit exchange-raÈe fluccuatlons and simulÈaneously

Èo maintain monetary independence,

for

countries to restrict the cross-border

example,

hisÈorically has encouraged

novemenEs

of capital. Capical concrols

played an integral role in the functioning of the Bretton Lloods exchange-raÈe
sysËem;

in fact,

Èhe rMF encouraged

balance-of-payments problems.

for the oPeration of the
'snake."
ERM

of

One

ceurporary

Similarly, capital controls

European Comrnunity's ERI'! and

have been inporÈant

ics predecessor,

the

recent study credits the stability of exchange retes under the

primarily to

monetary

their use in cases of

Èhe use

of capiÈal controls, raËher than

polÍcÍ"".3 Th""e capital conÈtols introduce

chey raise the cosÈs

of

invescmenE

capital

Eo

firms,

Èo the coordinaËion

nany distorEions:

reduce hedging

possibilities, lower returns to savers, induce undesirable
financial srructures, and encourage rent-seeking.4

changes

in natíons,

8

CounEries also have resorted

wey

to

exchange-market intervention as a possible

to resolve the problems thaÈ fixed

exchange reÈes

pose. In

Èheory,

nations could achieve fixed exchange retes, capiÈal nobility, and monetary
auÈonomy

Ëhey do

lf they had additional

independent

policy instrunents, but of

course

not. In practice, countries have used exchange-narket intervention

believing that it affords--at least Èemporarily--an extra degree of
UnfortunaÈ.e1y, available research sÈrongly suggests Èhat

freedom.

sterilized

inEerrrention (ÈhaÈ is, intervention with no monetery consequences) does not

provlde counËries with an addicional policy lever through which to pursue
exchange-rate

target. Intervention can alter

sterilized, but such lntervention Írnplies
Èo exchange-race

objectlves.

Some

exchange

races, if lt ls not

sorne subjugation

of inflation

goals

observers even contend chat interventlon

creates uncerÈaÍncy in the market Èo the exEent that it raises doubts
Èhe

an

future course of monetary policies or that iÈ eÈtenpts co offset

abouÈ

market

fundamentals.
The
dilernma

ability to realign central parities allows a possible solution to

that capital mobility

and naÈional sovereignty pose,

but

1È

also

Ehe

can

introduce new problems to the systern. Realigrunents of fixed exchange raËes

imply that countries know che correct, or equilibriun, values ac which to
Usually the

ERM members

have resorted

to realignments broadly designed to

correcc for exiscing ínfIaÈion differentials.
enjoyed little

success

UnfortunaÈely, economists have

in speclfying the relaÈlonship

beÈween

the so-called

market fundamentals (including inflation differenÈials, real interest-rate

differentials,

and currenE accounts) and spoÈ exchange raEes.5

occasion--mosc notably

peg.

in January L987 --the

realignmenÈs seemed

On

to be the

9

of lntensive negotlations, especfally

producE

between France and Germany,

rather than che result of an "arm's length" reading of narkeE fundamentals.
Because such renegotiations cannot promise

to

produce a market equilibrfi.un

value for exchange reEes, they can inÈroduce real-resource

In addition, a co-'nitment to

defend exchange raÈes

cosÈs.

risks the

danger of

what I call monetary protectionlsr¡. As proEectionist measures against trade

capital flows

and

co¡ne down, does Èhe

temptatlon to protect home markeEs

through moneÈary manipulations noÈ groer stronger? Under a commiÈment to

maintain a peg, counEries with relatively low inflation races night accumulate
Èhe currency

of high-inflaÈion councries. Obviously, low-inflation countries

linic the extent to which chey will do Èhis, slnce inflatÍon erodes
purchasing power

of these reserves. At

some

Èhe

point, countries acctrmulatÍng

reserves will exchange them back with the more inflacionery countries,

resulcing ln eicher a change ln policy wlthÍn the more lnflatfonary countrÍes

or an alceration of
My

does

exchange rates.

point, however, is thaÈ such a sysÈem--unlike floating

not

embody any smooth

or

auÈomatic rnechanisms Èo assure

exchange rates--

adjustment. At

leasÈ in the interin period, the coordinated efforts to fix exchange rates

wíll insulate
insEead

exchange raEes from

reflecting underlying market pressures

and,

of boctling up inflation within the more inflationary countries, will

Èransmít

it to others. Under these circurnstances, fixed

ProtecË Èhe claf.ms

imports.

Because

of high-Ínflation count.ries Eo world resources

it

prevenEs an automaEic depreciation

countries' currency, maintaining

uhe peg keeps

cheap.

some Èime,

The

exchange rates

result, at least for

through

of the inflating

foreign goods artificially

is a disruption of trade

and

10

invest¡nent across countries from what the market ocherwise would have
produced.

Consequently, any economic comrnunity chat wishes co
Èrade and

capital

movements can maintain

policy

benefit fron free

independence

the adjusÈments co occur through exchange reces. If

only tf lt allows

Germany and France adopc

policíes that create a 10 percentage-point differential

beÈween

their

lnflation rates, the ERM nusE allow for exchange-rate adjustnents of
comparable magnitude. Barring

costs that the

CommunÍÈy

this, the EMS has the pocenÈial to inpose real

cannot afford.

Flexible Rates and the Ouestion of Volarílity
Another

flexible

alternative, as inplied above, Ís to

exchange

move

rates, or to a regime of floating

to a sysËen of

exchange

rates.

alternatlve reduces the poËential disruptions to markeE-driwen

more

This

ouÈcomes and

therefore seens more compatible with che single-market goal.

Critics of floating (or

more

flexible)

exchange

rates, however, argue that

the resulËing exchange-race volatility reduces the free flow of resources
,moDE

different countries in a single narket. Th"y concend Èhat exchange-reÈe

volatility creates uncertaintsy.

Greacer uncertainty

buslness and the required reÈurn

for undertaking rísky investments.

raises the costs of doing
The the

higher cosËs and riskiness of business reduce international trade, investment,
and emplo)rmenÈ.

This criticism seems flawed. Firsc, exchange raEes are

endogenous

variables, which are ultimaEely responsive Èo naÈions' policies.

Much

of

the

11

volací1ity of

exchange raÈes

reflects the volatiliÈy

and

lncompatiblllty of

underlying policies. UncerÈaínty created on this accounÈ is a by-product of

policy

and would

exist under fixed

economists regard exchange-rate

exchange

rates. Nevertheless,

many

volaclllty as excessive--the result of

overshooÈing, bubbles, and destabÍlizing speculation. Although

volatility

may

creace some ÍnefficiencÍes, these inefficiencies pale in comparison to the
market distortlons that could resulE from an aÈtempt Èo peg

at

en

inappropriace exchange rate, or from attempts Èo maíntain fixed exchange rates
through capital controls. Markets for other assets exhibit slmilar

volatilÍty, yet
Second,

we do not peg

volatility is not

their prices.
synonymous

wich uncertaincy, although observers

often use the terms interchangeably. Under floating exchange rates, firms

can

hedge, alÈhough not conpletely, against the risks imposed by this volacÍllcy.
Under

flxed

and Èiming
These

exchange raÈes,

of

risks

the market can become uncercain of the

adjustments when

seem more

rnagnitude

it judges existÍng rates to be inappropriate.

difficult to

hedge and can

result in inefficient

resource allocaËions. Ironically, speculators usually are more cercain about

the direcÈion of change and are often assured of profits.

of no concrete

evidence

Finally, I

that links exchange-rate volacility, as I

have

described it, l"tith a reduction in trade, investmenE, or emplo¡rm.nt.6

On Nat.iona1 SovereÍsntv and

a European Central

Bank

As the last alternative, I wish to observe thaE European Economic
Community could maintain Ehe

current ERlf structure with an increased

am aware

L2

liberallzation of capital flows, lf individual counËries
national monetary sovereignty.

to

Peg

One way

dominanÈ-currency country uhen would detemine the

lts

monetary

policy, and the

EEC

such as Germany. lhe

overall lnflation rate

oEher countries would maintain the

exchange-race pegs through cheÍr moneEary

the

thelr

to achleve chis requÍres all countries

their currencies Èo a domÍnant-currency country,

Èhrough

gave up

policies. I doubt, however, that

partlcipants would acquiesce Èo such a commitment, at least in the

near future.
Some

counEries could

economies thac are

benefit from such an arrangement. For small,

open

heavíly dependent on trade wlth the donLnant country,

such

an arrangemenÈ uríght create more stability in Èrade volumes and príces. It

could reduce their vulnerability to speculation and limit the need for forward

cover. All of thÍs
game, and a

assu¡nes, however,

willingness to accept the

Many observers argue Èhat

a sÈrict adherence to the rules of the
moneÈary

disinflaÈion efforÈs. Under fíxed
most sEable values tends

inflating countries,

dominanÈ country.

a fixed-exchange-rete system exercíses

disclpline on Ínflation-prone councries
with the

policy of the

and enhances

exchange

to

asstrming again

e

the credíbility of their

rates, currencíes compete.

dominaEe and extend

a discipline

on

that the inflation-prone counEries

to the rules of the game. Typically,

however, the

Those

adhere

rules are broken.

Inflation-prone countries alter exchange rates and restrict the free flow of

capital to avoid adjustments. Moreover, experience suggesÈs that the world
tends to view the rapid depreciaÈion of a country's currency as an indicator

13

of inappropriate policy.

ConsequenÈly, t,o

the

exEenË

that world opinlon ever

constrains the economic policies of sovereÍgn states, inflation disclpline can

exist under floating

exchange rates.

"AdJustment as)mmetrÍes" are another source

of

European reluctance

to tie

to a domlnant currency. Fixed raËes--if maintained r¡itìout capital
controls--would force high-inflation counEries to adjust to Èhe lower

inflation rates of their crading partners. this ofÈen proves politically
difficult,

which

is

why

inflation-prone countries do nor adopt them to begin

wich. Fears that these so-calIed

adjusÈment asymmeÈries

will

become more

Pronounced as che EEC loosens capiEal resÈraints have prompted

creation of a

EuroPean currency issued through

a central bank implÍes thaÈ all

governments

calls for

a European central bank.

the
Such

relinquish their sovereignty over

policy, but thaÈ each would maintain a voíce in establÍshing a common
European monetary polícy. Some weighted-average inflation preference would

monetary

prevail.

Such compromises

in

Ehe

pursuit of economic policy coordination

the essence of politics, but the bane of

economic

efficÍency and stability.

I do not wÍsh to argue that a European central bank--or any central
for that matter- -could not successfully
opportunities, but its ability

Eo do

are

bank

maximize produc:ion and employment

so rests on the acÈainment of

conditions. First, the EEC must give its central bank

two

compleÈe autonomy from

financing the fiscal policies of the individual European scates and of the
community

in general. A large

governments sPend Eoo much,
The reasons

body

of research strongh'

particularly relative

suggesËs that

Èo gheir

ability t.o tax.

relate to the nature of publicly supplied goods,

Ëo

the incentives

wichin bureaucracies, and to the nature of poliEical conpromise. The benefÍcs

L4

of

goverrunent expenditures tend

polfcically
aÈ

asÈute groups,

to be concentraEed on indentifiable,

while the costs are dÍffused throughout the public

large. By financing expenditures through che sale of chelr debt to central

banks, governmencs can reduce che real value of their outscandlng debts
through subsequent Ínflation.

ThÍs inflatlon tax, although highly fnefflcient

and distorËional, nevertheless

is relatively lnvisible

hence

Èo

the elecÈoraEe;

its aÈtractiveness.

Ihe second condition for the successful creation of a
bank requires

stability.

European cenÈral

that it maintain the value of lts currency by promoting price

Governments

often

demand

too much of monetary policy. I have

already referred to problems of atÈempting Èo stabíl-íze exchange rates 4g!
conduct domestic monetary policy. A more common, yet less recognized, problern
occurs when countries attempt Èo sÈabilize the business cycle. Sometímes
policymakers balk

at eli¡ninaÈing inflation

because they believe

that a

Èrade-

off exísts

beÈween

policy

the evidence supporting its effecciveness are weak. Nevertheless,

and

even granting

inflation

and unemployment. The

theoretical basls for

such

that nore inflaEion could lead to a tenporary increase in

employment, there seems

to be a

Eendency

for such policies to ratchet

inflacion upward. In the 1970s, the rate of inflaÈion at the business-cycle
crough tended

to rise with

each

cycle.

The resulËlng reductions

growth probably outweighed any short-term gains
Under conditions

of

auEonomy and

in

in long-term

emplo)rment.

price stabilicy, a European central barrk

could be a useful and natural extension of che single European market.
many European leaders have

complete economic and

As

pointed out, however, monetary union presupposes

political integration of Europe.

Europe

is not likely

a

15

Èo achieve such a close degree of inËegration in che near future.

Perhaps the

long run holds more promise, if Lord Keynes' famous dictun does not crap

us

first.

Eurooe anrl the Tnternetíonn'l Fínnncíe'l Commrrnltv

I

have previously expressed concerns about att.empcs by the G7 councries to

coordínate macroeconomlc policy and to create exchange-rate carget zones for

yen-dollar exchange rates.T The creation of a

Èhe mark-dollar and

monetary union could have the unforÈunate consequence

for these polÍcies.

Even when sovereign

of increasing

interrelationships

among

policies?
but

policy levers

and economic

variables, are almost

economy

works, can r{re expect

to agree on and implement coordinated, effective

One

macroeconomic

also mighc wonder about the outcome if the world cooperated,

of

how Ëhe world

works. This of course is

at the naËional level,

buE the cosÈs

of an error increase sharply

adopted the wrong model

problem

The sharp differences

true state of the economy, and about the

legendary. If economists cannot a9tee on how the
governments

support

countries q.g Èo coordinate

policies, they night not be able to do so effeccively.
¡moîB economisÈs about Èhe

European

we ext.end the scope

of coordination to

fínancial

in general.8

Many

communicy

Europe and

to the

a

as

inEernaÈional

of these proposals call for a deÈailed harmonization--a fine tuning

on a grand scale--of monetary, fiscal and regulatory powers. It remínds

me

of

policymakers'efforts aE "fine truning" in the 1960s and 1970s, when they
aËcempted

to achieve

shifted frequently,

many

targecs simultaneously. The thrust of polÍcies

and those

policies generally

missed on

all accouncs.

The

16

Earkets' mistrust of polÍc¡rmakers was reflected In an inflationary psychology
ÈhaÈ complicated and extended

the fight againsÈ inflacion.

subordinaÈe donesÈic objectives

to lnternatlonal targeÈs

If ne now

and evenÈs, econonfc

agents once again could lose confidence Ín the wlllingness and the ablliÈy of

to pursue important

polÍeyurakers

domestlc goals.

Conclusion

Policy coordínatlon must play an essentlal role in process of

unification. In developing proposals for a single market

and

European

for a monetary

union, I urge coordination of efforts to free markeÈs and Èo expand
and productÍon

exchange

opportunities. That these markets extend across European

boundarles only serves to enhance the galns from such coordfnaÈed polfcies.
We

should slmilarly explore opportunitfes for internaÈional coordination that

enhance the performance

againsË forms

of free,

compeËiÈive

markets. I caution,

of policy coordination, both in

however,

Europe and throughout the

internaÈional community, thaÈ strive Èo supplant markeÈs and limic Èheir

discipline.

l.Ie simply cannot

afford

them.

T7

I fhÍ" view is found in Nigel Lawson's speech at
Incernatlonal Affairs on January 25, 1989, entitled

Financial

Arena?"

t

'See

Èhe Royal. InsÈiÈure for
"Whac SorÈ of European

t{illian T. Gavin and Alan C. Scockman, "The Case for Zero
Economic Conmentary, Federal Resen¡e Bank of C1eveland, Septenber

Inflation,
15, 1988.

"

a

'Miche1e Fratiannf, "Îhe European Monetary SysÈen: Horr Well Has It l.Iorked?"
The Cato Journal, Vol.8 No.2 (Fal1 1988): 477 -501. See especially page 483.
4see
Jacob A. Frenkel and l'lorris Goldstein, nThe International MoneEary
Systexû: Developments and Prospects, " The Cato Journal, Vo1.8, No.2 (FatI
1988):285-306.

5 S"" Richard A.

Meese and Kenneth Rogoff, nEmpirical Exchange Rate Models of
Seventies:
Èhe
Do They Fit Out of Sample?" Journal of International Economics L4

(1983)

i

3-24.

6 sa"

and llorld Trade," A Srudy by the Research
"Exchange Rate Volatility
DeparEmenu of the International MoneÈary Fund, Occasional Papers No.28, July
1984.

7". L""

Hoskins, "International Pollcy Coordinauion: Can f.Ie Afford It?'
Economíc Commentary, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, January 1, 1989.
SSee

Jeffery A. Frankel and KaÈherine RockeCt, "InÈernaÈional Macroeconomic
Policy Coordination l.Ihen Policymakers Do Not Agree on the True Model, " AEC-fu_
Economic Review, VoI.78, No.3 (June 1988) :318-40.