View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

W. Braddock Hickman
Panel Discussion
Ohio Association of Economists
and Political Scientists
./•'•.•' Columbus, Ohio
March 28, 1969

"CURRENT MONETARY POLICY"

While I have some fairly close knowledge of monetary policy in recent
months, I cannot help but feel a bit uncomfortable about the topic: first,
because I have had a hand in shaping it as a member of the Federal Open
Market Committee; and secondly, because I am not very proud of the policy
record as it unfolded during the second half of 1968.
What I would like to do in the brief time allowed me is to concentrate
on monetary policy since November 1967. As most of you are aware, in
November the Federal Reserve banks raised the discount rate shortly after
the British devaluation.
restraint.

This action signaled a shift to a policy of greater

Such a policy was believed by almost all of us in the Federal Reserve

to be appropriate in view of the strength in the economy, Congressional delay
in approving an income tax surcharge, and the growing feeling that the Federal
Reserve stood alone in fighting inflation until Congress decided to act.
From then until the middle of 1968 (specifically, December 1967 June 1968) the Federal Reserve earned good marks in achieving moderate and
sustainable rates of growth in bank reserves and most of the monetary aggregates.
Since there is disagreement among the experts about which indicator, or
indicators, are the most appropriate guides to monetary policy, perhaps the
best thing for me to do is to give you a rundown of the behavior of a few of the
key financial variables over this period of monetary restraint.
(more)

Total member

-2-

bank reserves increased at an annual rate (seasonally adjusted) of about 5%
in the first half of 1968, down from an 8-1/2%' rate in the preceding six months.
Nonborrowed reserves (total reserves less borrowed reserves; that is, r e s e r v e s
supplied at the initiative of the Federal Reserve System) increased at a rate of
about 2%, substantially less than the 7% rate of gain recorded in the preceding
six months.
Growth in time deposits slowed markedly in the seven months ended
June 1968, rising at a rate of only 5%. In contrast, the narrowly-defined
money supply increased at an 8% rate - - a development that has evidently
created some confusion among "Fed watchers" and other observers who criticize
Federal Reserve policy on the basis of the erratic behavior of certain monetary
variables over which we have only limited control.

To be specific, it is not

possible to use the rate of growth in the money supply over short periods, or
even reasonably long periods such as December 1967 - June 1968, as an
v

indicator of the thrust of monetary policy.

In that period, there was a massive

shift of funds out of U. S. Government deposits into private hands because of
the budget deficit, thus boosting the money supply in the short run.
Over the long term (in which at least some of us will be dead) such
transfers of funds from Government hands to private accounts tend to wash out
since they are caused by short-term fluctuations in the U. S. Treasury's cash
position.

But within any reasonably short period, these very natural transfers

of funds produce -wide fluctuations in the money supply, particularly in times
of large Federal deficits.

What I am suggesting is that, given our objectives

and our need to pay close attention to current developments, the Federal Reserve

(more)

-3-

System has less control over the money supply in the short run than many of our
critics seem to believe.

In fact, the narrowly-defined money supply (and to a

lesser extent, the broader-defined money supply) is as much a result of Treasury
action, and Congressional appropriations and tax policy, as it is of the Federal
Reserve.
In view of some of these problems, many of us in the Federal Reserve
System prefer to use another monetary variable as a general guide to Federal
Reserve policy.

This is the "bank credit proxy", a series that measures total

member bank deposits against which reserves must be held, including deposits
of the U. S. Treasury.

The deposit side (rather than the asset side) of the

commercial bank balance sheet is used, because reasonably reliable data on
bank deposits are available on a weekly basis, with daily data from large banks.
Thus, on the basis of frequent estimates of total deposits, we can adjust policy
•

actions quickly if we seem to be going wide of the mark.
V

Total bank deposits are a reasonably good short-run proxy for total
bank credit.

The differences between the two sides of the balance sheet

represent bank capital, which does not change frequently or substantially, and
nondeposit liabilities such as borrowings from foreign branches.

Information

on borrowings from branches is also available and can be used to adjust the
credit proxy.

For this reason, many of us have turned toward a measure of

the credit proxy adjusted to include Eurodollar borrowings, which have increased
enormously in recent years, thus adding to the volume of funds available for
banks to loan or invest.

Both of the proxy measures provide more frequent

readings of bank credit developments than does the monthly information on actual

(more)

-4-

bank loans and investments.

Let me hasten to add, however, that the credit

proxies are not foolproof in short-run periods/- For example, on the last day
of February, data became available that indicated the actual annual rates of
growth of the credit proxies were two percentage points over the rates projected
earlier for the month.

By then, it was too late for the System to affect the

figures for the month.
Looking at the two measures of the credit proxy, what was the situation
in the first half of 1968? In 1967 the unadjusted credit proxy increased at a
very rapid pace of more than 11%.

By comparison, in the policy period that

ran from December 1967 through June 1968, the rate of growth in the credit
proxy dropped to 3-1/2%, and even when Eurodollars are included, at an annual
rate of only 5%. In other words, in the first half of 1968 the Federal Reserve
System was successful in holding bank credit expansion to a modest rate.
policy of moderate restraint, in my opinion, was entirely appropriate.
theless,

This

Never-

serious economic imbalances remained that were beyond the reach of

only six months of monetary policy.

For example, the fiscal situation was still

highly expansionary, and price inflation continued at an excessively rapid pace.
But I think an unbiased appraisal would give us good marks on the period;
monetary policy was appropriately restrictive in a period of growing inflationary
pressures.
I wish that I could say the same for the second half of 1968. Early in
July, monetary policy was reversed abruptly, as has been done too often, and in
my view, became inappropriately easy.
policy w e r e put forth at that time.

Two justifications for this change in

For one, the 10% income tax surcharge was

(more)

-5-

enacted in June, and a limit on Federal expenditures was proposed.

The long-

awaited fiscal action immediately led to impr,o.yed expectations in the money and
capital markets, and the Federal R e s e r v e attempted to accommodate this improved
climate, signaling a shift in policy by a reduction in the discount rate in August.
(The Cleveland bank, I might add, reluctantly reduced its discount rate after a
delay of several days. ) The second and related factor influencing monetary
policy in the last half of 1968 was a widely-shared forecast suggesting that the
combination of monetary restraint and the income tax surcharge would produce
a substantial slowdown in the U. S. economy in a few months.

Of chief importance

was an expected shrinkage in consumer spending, resulting from a reduced level
of disposable income caused by the surtax.

The majority in the Federal Reserve

accepted this standard forecast and monetary policy was designed accordingly,
with minor reservations expressed by some of us.
For the second half of 1968 as a whole, the rate of growth in both total
bank reserves and nonborrowed reserves increased sharply, exceeding 8%.
There •was an explosive expansion in time deposits at commercial banks,
reflecting bank intermediation, as short-term rates on Treasury bills fell below
Regulation Q ceilings.

As a result, the rate of growth in time deposits more

than tripled from the first half to the second half of the year.

But when we look

at the money supply, the old problem of short-term erratic variation shows up
again.

In the second half of 1968, when monetary policy became easier, the

rate of growth in the narrowly-defined money supply decreased sharply, dropping
from 8% to about 3-1/2%.

The chief reason for this was a r e v e r s e shift of funds

from private hands to public accounts.
*

(more)

-6T h e r e f o r e , once again, I p r e f e r to look at the credit proxy.

The behavior

of this measure between July and mid-December last year unfortunately reveals
only too clearly that monetary policy was inappropriately easy.

The credit proxy

.increased at an annual rate of 14% in this period, when measured both with and
without Eurodollar borrowing.

(Eurodollar borrowing leveled off in the second

half of the year as interest rate differentials shifted and the pull on the Eurodollar market decreased. ) This is not just my judgment after the fact, for the
record will show that I dissented from the majority policy decision of the Federal
*
Open Market Committee in October and again in November. More recently,
there has been wider acknowledgment of the e r r o r s of our ways in the second
half of 1968, expressed, for example, in the testimony of Chairman Martin
before the Joint Economic Committee.

In b r i e f , the System was too much

concerned with the possibility of "over-kill", to such an extent that other
business and financial developments were overlooked.

Prices were continuing
t

to increase at a rapid rate, and consumer spending was supported at a very
high level by increased borrowing and decreased saving.
Of course, a policy of monetary ease, however modest the ease was
intended to be, could only go on so long against the emerging interplay of
economic events.

In December, the Open Market Committee finally voted for

a more restrictive monetary policy, and the discount rate simultaneously was
moved up again to 5-1/2%.

Since then, there has been a contraction in the credit

proxy and a decline in the rate of expansion of bank r e s e r v e s .

The rate of growth

in the narrowly-defined money supply declined f u r t h e r from its already low rate
of the preceding policy period, but I must add that this was not primarily caused
by Federal Reserve action; it was chiefly the result of a f u r t h e r build-up in
Treasury deposits in January and February.
(more)

-7-

While the massive CD runoff has served the useful purpose of reducing
bank liquidity, a certain amount of deposit and' credit expansion is vital to insure
sustainable economic growth.

I confess that I am concerned about achieving

sufficient bank credit growth in the balance of the year, particularly if the Treasury
has any success at all in moving to a budget surplus in the second half.

This means

that once again the monetary policymakers are facing a difficult decision. We
are worried about sufficient economic growth and the effect on unemployment,
but at the same time we must cope with inflation.

Price inflation in this country

is not yet under control, and the recently-released plans for plant and equipment
spending in 1969 da not suggest any relaxation in the business sector of the economy.
Earlier in the year, a credibility gap seemed to have developed between
Federal R e s e r v e intentions and the acceptance of these intentions by the market
place, but recent developments in capital markets indicate that this gap now has
been closed.

We would all agree that a policy change toward restraint in the
•v

growth of money and credit was needed, but I would suggest (and I may again be
in the minority on this) that the severity of the restraint that has developed in
the past three months may have gone on long enough. My objective is to cool
the economy, which means that I favor moderate credit restraint, not a crunch.
To sum up, then, there are those who believe that monetary policy will
have to get tighter before we can loosen the screws, and there are those who
believe that we have already gone far enough.

I happen to be among the latter

group; but of course I could be wrong. Hopefully, some light will be thrown on
this difficult question by the discussion here tonight.

#

#

#