View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

THE SHIFTING FOCUS OF MONETARY POLICY
Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer
to the Harry J. Loman Foundation
of the Society of Chartered Property and Casualty Underwriters
Mariott Pavilion Hotel, St. Louis
October 14, 1985

Good afternoon.

I am delighted to be with you and appreciate the

opportunity to make some remarks about monetary policy.

As you could

tell from the introductory remarks, it was not too long ago that I was an

outside observer of policy as head of Morgan Stanley's U.S. Government

Securities department.

One comment I would hear from time to time from

other securities traders was how boring the Government bond business must

be in comparison to stocks or even corporate bonds. After all, they
would say, you are dealing with straight-forward securities and only one
credit, that of the U.S. Government. My response, while these were
undeniable facts, was that the main event was not the specific securities,
but rather the market.

The fascinating thing to me about the market is

that it would behave quite differently over time with apparently similar
sets of inputs. I think the same thing might be said about monetary
policy, and what I would like to talk about today is the shifting focus

of policy, particularly as it relates to how the rate of growth of money
is viewed.




- 2 -

Late this Spring, as we all know, monetary policy was eased.

In

May and June adjusted monetary base grew at a 14.6 percent annual rate

compared to a 6.3 percent rate from January through April.

Ml, which had

grown at about a 10 percent rate from the beginning of the year, grew at

a 16.0 percent rate from May to the present.

The discount rate was cut

50 basis points, and market interest rates, from mid-April through

mid-June, declined by approximately 100 basis points.

What factors were associated with this easing?

First, GNP growth

was at an anemic 0.3 percent annual rate in the first quarter, and more

current indicators pointed to continued weakness in the second quarter.

In addition, the dollar was still strong, having just reached its highs

in March.

Inflation continued to be well behaved, and in fact with talk

of lower oil prices there was even a whiff of deflation in the air.

Finally, there was evidence of strains in the financial system with the

Ohio thrift crisis and mounting numbers of bank failures.

factors pointed in the direction of monetary ease.

All of these

A further confirming

note was struck in mid-May when there was a breakthrough in the Federal

budget impasse which would apparently lead to reduced government spending

and deficits.




- 3 -

The only factor which seemed to point in the opposite direction was

the rapid rate of growth in Ml (currency and checkable deposits), which

at about 10 percent was well in excess of the Fedfs 4-7 percent target

range.

However, because of the weight of the other factors and certain

special considerations relating to Ml, which I will discuss later, rapid

Ml growth did not act as a constraint to easing.

Now, as we enter the fourth quarter, there continue to be

occasional calls for further easing and certainly is no anticipation of

tightening.

The economy, while growing at a stronger 2.8 percent rate in

the third quarter, is still thought by some to be too sluggish.

The

dollar, although lower by 6-7 percent since the recent G5 accord and by

20 percent from its March highs, is still not down enough, some would

say, to reduce the trade imbalances that have developed, particularly in

manufacturing and agriculture.

behaved.

Inflation certainly continues to be well

And there are still strains in the financial system, as the

number of bank failures through September had already reached the total

for all of last year and will probably exceed 100 by year-end.

Finally,

while Ml growth continues to be rapid, in fact more rapid than earlier in

the year, it was ignored then and presumably can be now.




- 4 -

Or can it?

The ultimate goal of monetary policy is to supply, at

some given rate of inflation and growth of real output, that amount of

money that people are willing to hold in the form of cash and checkable

deposits.

demand.

In economic jargon, to supply that amount of money that people

If more money than that is provided, according to monetarist

theories, people attempt to get rid of excess money balances by

increasing their spending on goods, services, and securities, thus

temporarily increasing economic activity and ultimately causing an

increase in the rate of inflation.

If less money is supplied, people try

to conserve money balances by reducing their spending, and thus reducing

output and eventually the rate of inflation.

Monetary authorities, in

most cases, do not wish to accelerate inflation; nor do they wish to

produce a recession.

It sounds simple, but, unfortunately, there are no

precise measures or estimates of how much money people desire to hold.

Consequently, monetary policy can be frustrated by the public's changing

desires.




- 5 -

There is substantial evidence that the public's demand for money
may have increased in 1985, with the result that more money was required
to sustain an acceptable level of economic activity.

Four major reasons

have been put forth.
The first one is the declining rate of inflation since 1980. When
people observe lower rates of inflation and expect inflation to decline
further, they are more willing to hold noninterest-bearing, or
less-than-market-bearing deposits. The value of those assets declines
more slowly than during periods of higher inflation.

The second one is declining interest rates since the 1981-82
peaks. With lower and declining interest rates, the holding of cash
becomes less costly because the return on alternative assets is smaller.

The third one is the rising international value of the dollar.
Even though there are industries and sectors of the economy which
stagnate because of the high value of the dollar, it raises the perceived
wealth of society as a whole because of the increased purchasing power.
Such an increase in wealth also acts to increase cash holdings.




- 6 -

And, finally, the introduction of NOW and Super NOW accounts has

probably shifted some savings deposits into what is now defined as Ml.

With cash assets including some features of savings deposits, one would

expect that these assets would not all be held for spending purposes, and

thus increases in these assets may not be immediately translated into

additional spending.

While some of these pieces of evidence, individually, may not

produce a large increase in money demand, all of them together have had a

significant effect.

The bottom line of this analysis is that the rapid

growth of the money stock in 1985 may not necessarily have had the same

impact on economic activity and the rate of inflation as it has had in

the past.

Typically, such increases in the rate of growth of money have

resulted in increased economic activity with a one to two quarter lag and

higher inflation with an 18-month lag.

However, there is a question as to whether such rapid growth can

continue without adverse side-effects given some changes occurring in the

past six months.

In terms of the factors that I have enumerated as

affecting money demand, we are beginning to observe the following.




- 7 -

The inflation rate is not declining—it stabilized at around

4 percent in the past three years.

While people's expectations may have

changed with a lag, thus inducing larger cash holdings for the past three

years, it is unlikely that they will continue to do so.

Interest rates

have leveled off, and given our tax structure and four percent

inflationary expectations in the short run, and somewhat higher in the

long run, it is doubtful that we would see further significant declines.

The international value of the dollar, as mentioned earlier, has declined

significantly from its highs, presumably contributing to a leveling off,

if not a decrease, in perceptions of wealth.

And finally, barring some

new innovations in cash-holding instruments, a significant reduction in

the growth of savings components of Ml should be occurring.

Again, adding all these factors together, it is reasonable to

expect that people's desire to hold higher cash balances will begin to

decrease.

Accordingly, much lower rates of money growth than we have

been experiencing may be sufficient to sustain economic growth.

Continuation of current double-digit rates of money growth could well

contribute to an outburst of new inflation down the road.




- 8 -

There is another aspect of our current situation that I would like

to comment on—namely, we are particularly vulnerable to changes in

inflationary psychology at the present time.

This has developed as a

result of our large current account deficits and the resulting increase

in foreign holdings of dollars which must be invested in dollar assets.

Because of the magnitude of these deficits, we have become quite

dependent on foreign capital flows in meeting our domestic financing

requirements, which include the large budget deficits.

The ability to attract these flows at current interest rate levels

is very dependent on the inflationary outlook in the U.S. relative to

other countries.

Were inflationary psychology here to revive—and this

might very likely be associated with overly-stimulative monetary policy

and excessive rates of money growth—the dollar would decline, perhaps

precipitously, as foreign investors sell dollar assets to preserve their

future purchasing power.

While the trade imbalances would improve with a

lower dollar, less net foreign investment would be available, and there

would be upward pressures on interest rates.

In addition, a lower dollar

would increase the price level simply because imported goods would become




- 9 -

more expensive, reinforcing the inflationary psychology.

Therefore, we

must be especially mindful of not only inflationary performance in the

short run, but also long-run inflationary expectations, which are

influenced by monetary growth rates.

To sum up, then, I would argue that monetary policy has less

latitude in the direction of ease than it did earlier in the year,

despite many similarities between the two periods.

Economic activity has

improved, and in fact some observers are predicting third quarter GNP

will be revised upwards to the 3-3.5 percent area.

below the economy's long-run potential.

This is not much

As to the dollar, while further

downward adjustment over time would be desirable, if anything, we need to

be more concerned in the short-run with too rapid a decline because of

implications for foreign capital flows.

Finally, as to Ml growth, while

special factors may have justified higher growth for a time, it is

questionable whether that will continue to be the case.

On the other hand, a sharp slowing in money growth would be

counter-productive.

Sharp declines in such growth have resulted in

recessions in the past.




The Fed's fundamental objective is to foster a

- 10 -

financial environment conducive to sustained growth of the economy

consistent with progress over time toward price stability.

Sustained

growth has assumed a high priority in view of the strains in our

financial system and appropriately so.

However, price stability and

expectations as to such stability in the future, particularly when

dealing with markets as large and as volatile as the foreign exchange

market, must have a high priority as well.