View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

EMBARGOED UNTIL 11:00 a.m., CST
October 28, 1997




PRICE STABILITY POLICIES FOR GROWTH"

Remarks by
Thomas C. Melzer
President, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

"Professor For A Day" Program
School of Business Administration
The University of Tennessee at Martin

October 28, 1997

The U.S. economy is doing exceptionally well this year, with low inflation and an
average unemployment rate of only 5 percent. Economic growth continues to be robust in
this, the seventh year of the current expansion, which started in March 1991. Since that time,
the economy has created 14 million new jobs, and inflation has been comparatively low and
stable. In the first nine months of this year, the CPI was running at an annual rate of only
1.8 percent, which is as close to a stable price environment as we've seen in decades. That
said, private sector forecasts indicate that inflation, as measured by the CPI, is expected to
return to its trend level of roughly 3 percent in the next year.
High employment today means that many workers are acquiring skills and experience
that will yield benefits for the rest of their careers. But the best thing about the current
economic good news is that it has not been created by artificial demands stemming from
excessive money creation. On the contrary, the low money growth and low inflation of the
current expansion mean that future prospects are not being jeopardized for the sake of today's
prosperity.
In response to such good news, some observers—especially those prone to hyperbolehave proclaimed a "new economic paradigm" in which the U.S. economy has become both
recession-proof and inflation-proof. In this view, policymakers need not worry about demand
or inflation because markets will keep growth strong and inflation in check. However, history
suggests caution with respect to such notions that "all is for the best in this best of all possible
worlds."




2

We must not ignore the lessons of the past by adopting inflationary policies that have
consistently culminated in slowed growth and higher unemployment.

The fact is that,

throughout history, efforts to use expansionary monetary policy to squeeze more real growth
out of the economy than can be sustained have always led to increases in the misery index.
What is the misery index? It is the sum of the inflation, unemployment and long-term interest
rates. This index was at an all-time high in the early 1980s, when each of these three rates
soared into the double digits. By comparison, the index is very low today, registering less
than half the "misery" of the early 1980s.
The purpose of my remarks today is to address the following issues: Why low and
stable inflation has been good for economic growth; how inflation uncertainty hurts our
economy; and what steps the Fed can take to make its price stability policies credible. The
appropriate monetary policy response to today's environment of comparatively low inflation,
low unemployment and low interest rates is to nurture it with a credible commitment to price
stability-an inflation rate so close to zero that it ceases to be a significant factor in long-term
planning. Only in this way can the Fed reconcile its potentially conflicting statutory objectives
of "maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates" and realize
its ultimate goal of a rising U.S. standard of living. Let me begin by considering the first
issue I posed earlier.
Why has low inflation been good for the economy? Under the successful disinflation
policies of the past 15 years, the U.S. economy has enjoyed its most cyclically stable period
ever. Since 1982, the economy has had positive growth in all but three quarters out of 59.




3

By comparison, between 1969 and 1982, when inflation was trending upward, there were
20 recession quarters out of 56. The current stable growth experience is the best evidence that
the Fed's choice to fight the double-digit inflation of the late 1970s and early 1980s has been
good for the economy. Even though we haven't yet achieved price stability as I've defined
it, the current 3 percent inflation trend is the best record we've had since the early 1960s.
Let me briefly review the fundamental arguments as to why low inflation is good for
the economy. First, a stable price backdrop enables the price system to work more efficiently
than it would with high and variable inflation.

By working efficiently, I mean that the

economy is not wasting resources. When the general level of prices is comparatively stable,
decision makers can interpret changes in dollar prices as accurate signals on which to base
decisions. In free economies, clear, reliable signals from prices help people make the choices
that are best for them. And, the best way to keep price signals clear is to keep inflation low
and, in principle, eliminate it.
Second, inflation distorts decisions because it is a hidden tax on the private sector borne
by holders of money and government securities. Even at today's 3 percent inflation trend, the
real value of a dollar is cut in half in less than 25 years. Although the government admittedly
has to collect taxes, the inflation tax generates incentives for wasteful efforts to reduce money
holdings, like currency, which depreciate through inflation. Inflation also distorts decisions
to save and invest, since inflation-compensating interest payments and inflation-induced capital
gains are taxed as ordinary income. The tax on the portion of interest payments that is
intended to adjust for inflation inadvertently enlarges the wedge between the value of the




4

interest paid by the borrower and the after-tax value of interest received by the lender. In the
case of capital gains, significant tax burdens can Ml on transactions that haven't generated any
real income—for example, when an asset is sold at a price that increased only at the rate of
inflation. These inflation-induced tax distortions decrease planned savings and reduce capital
formation. The best way to reduce the inflation tax is to keep inflation low and, in principle,
eliminate it.
A third reason why low inflation is good for the economy is that an inflationary
monetary regime boosts nominal interest rates by the amount of the expected inflation rate,
plus an inflation risk premium. I'll discuss inflation risks later, but at this point, let me note
that a major determinant of nominal interest rates is expected inflation. We had double-digit
interest rates in the late 1970s and early 1980s because we had expectations of double-digit
inflation.

Lenders demanded to be compensated for expected inflation, and borrowers

expected that subsequent inflation would validate their decisions to borrow at high interest
rates. Thus, a non-inflationary monetary regime delivers the lowest sustainable borrowing
costs for investment in new capital, which will lead to future growth. True to form, the Fed's
low-inflation regime of recent years has brought down borrowing costs. The market interest
rate on 10-year government securities—which today is about 6 percent—is less than half what
it was in the early 1980s. The best way to stamp out inflation expectations and reduce
nominal interest rates is to keep inflation low and, in principle, eliminate it.
Fourth, recent business cycle research suggests that a stable, non-inflationary
environment, rather than one in which monetary policy is directed at fine-tuning real growth,




5

may be the best contribution monetary policy can make toward sustaining real growth. Behind
the premise of fine-tuning lies the notion of a trade-off between inflation variability and output
variability—that higher inflation can buy more real growth in the short run. The contemporary
thinking, however, is that inflationary variability threatens, rather than prolongs, economic
expansions. Recessions are often the product of particular inflationary imbalances, instead of
expansions that have simply "run out of steam." An example of an inflationary imbalance
from the mid-1980s is the excessive investment in commercial real estate that eventually
depressed the market, taking years to unwind. Because inflation has been shown to be more
volatile at higher levels, the best way to reduce its variability is to keep inflation low and, in
principle, eliminate it.
In general, U.S. monetary policy has succeeded in capturing many of these four
benefits of low inflation during the past 15 years. I'd further argue that this success has not
been an accident, but instead a deliberate policy choice. The policy shift since the early 1980s
to a low-inflation regime has required a commensurate reduction in the rate of monetary
expansion. Growth in the M2 aggregate averaged nearly 10 percent from 1968 to 1983, but
only 4.6 percent from 1984 to 1997. This experience demonstrates that the Federal Reserve
can restrain excessive money growth and bring down the inflation rate. Inflation control is
undeniably the Fed's responsibility because it alone has the tools to determine the long-run rate
of monetary expansion needed to keep inflation low. Even though the inflation rate so far this
year is running at less than a 2 percent rate, there remains a good deal of uncertainty as to
whether inflation is down for the count. Until price stability becomes the explicit, publicly




6
recognized, and sole objective of monetary policy, a degree of inflation uncertainty is bound
to persist. Let me now turn to the second of my three questions.
Why is inflation uncertainty bad for the economy? In addition to expected inflation,
inflation uncertainty increases nominal interest rates because lenders demand compensation
for the risk that inflation might end up higher than they expected. The inflation risk premium,
which effectively raises real borrowing costs, arises in policy regimes in which lenders judge
that inflation will almost certainly not be less than expected, but could quite possibly be more
than expected. This asymmetry leads to a market-determined inflation risk premium in
nominal interest rates. Only a non-inflationary monetary regime can eradicate the inflation
risk premium, thereby delivering the lowest sustainable real borrowing costs, which stimulate
capital formation and lead to future growth.
International evidence suggests that investors often require substantial inflation risk
premiums. After they have been burned by inflation once, investors typically need years of
solid inflation performance to convince them that the risk of inflation has subsided. For the
past four years or so, almost all major industrial countries have had inflation rates well below
5 percent.

Yet, the real borrowing costs on government securities differ widely across

countries because of the substantial inflation risk premiums in those that have a long history
of inflation. Borrowers persistently face higher real borrowing costs in these countries, even
long after inflation has been brought down. Indeed, the prospect of reducing the inflation risk
premium in their interest rates strongly motivates Italy, Portugal and Spain, for example, to
join the European Monetary Union.




7

Much of the inflation risk premium in interest rates stems from the experience that once
inflation is unleashed, the process of bringing it back down is long and painful.

As a

consequence, it is even more important for the Fed to convince the public of its intentions to
contain inflation. Reductions in the inflation risk premium are possible if the Fed follows a
disciplined and credible policy to move inflation lower and keep it that way. This brings me
to the last of my three questions.
How can the Fed make price stability policies credible? The persistence of inflation
risk premiums in nominal interest rates—even with inflation as low as it has been in recent
years—is an indication of imperfect inflation credibility. A policy is credible when it can be
counted on. And, a credible non-inflationary monetary policy is one that can be counted on
to keep inflation low. Credibility is an essential element of a price stability policy for the
simple reason that only then can the full range of price stability benefits begin to accrue.
Otherwise, interest rates will remain elevated by an inflation risk premium.
New Zealand is one country in which the central bank appears to have rapidly acquired
credibility for its new, low-inflation policies. In that country, a legislative mandate calling
for price stability through inflation targets has convinced investors that the country's imperfect
past inflation record is not likely to recur. Without this newly created credibility—even with
low current inflation—long-term interest rates in New Zealand could easily be 3 or
4 percentage points higher than they are. By achieving a degree of credibility through
inflation targets and a legislative mandate that makes price stability the monetary policy
objective, New Zealand has been able to substantially reduce real borrowing costs.




8
I am concerned, however, that in the United States, 3 percent inflation has become too
entrenched in people's expectations. One argument against a move to lower inflation is that,
because of these entrenched expectations, the transition would be too disruptive. Indeed, a
surprise attack on inflation could well lead to a regrettable loss in output. A sound way to
change these entrenched expectations, however, would be to adopt an approach similar to that
of New Zealand and several other countries. This approach involves setting a precise inflation
goal and a timetable for achieving it. At the semiannual congressional hearings on monetary
policy, the Fed could announce a set of multiyear inflation targets. These annual targets
would then define a course by which inflation could gradually be reduced. Policy actions
would correspondingly be geared both to place inflation within that year's target range and to
set the stage for the following year's target.
A well-publicized and fully expected program to lower inflation—and keep it lowwould give consumers and businesses confidence in a stable price environment. These groups
could count on stable prices even more if the United States followed the lead of countries like
New Zealand in legislating a framework for setting a specific price stability goal and a
timetable for achieving it. When inflation is too high-and I think even 3 percent is too high—
a specific inflation target and stated timetable would make it easy to see if policymakers were
in fact carrying out their responsibilities.
I would argue that announced policy objectives in the form of inflation targets would
enhance the Fed's credibility, because its policy actions would be easier to interpret. In such
an environment, pre-emptive policy actions against inflationary pressures could be readily




9
understood for what they are. If people believed that the Fed was merely acting at an early
stage to head off inflationary imbalances, they would understand that the economy was not in
immediate danger of either a recession or a burst of inflation. If, on the other hand, the Fed
had poor credibility and poorly understood reasons for acting, the public might believe that
the Fed acts only when panicked, making any Fed action cause for alarm.
In conclusion, I have tried to emphasize to you today that "price stability" is a state that
must be sustained, and considered sustainable, over time. Although CPI inflation has been
running at just 1.8 percent so far this year, longer-term expectations are for roughly 3 percent
a year, and there is always a risk that inflation could run higher. What really matters is not
merely the absence of inflation at any given point in time, but the widespread presence of
public expectations that prices will remain stable in the future. I believe the best way for the
Fed to achieve price stability is to announce multiyear inflation targets, paving the way for
private plans and contracts and Fed policies to reinforce each other. In this way, price
stability represents a compact with the American people that, if upheld, could achieve lower
interest rates, eliminate the deadweight costs of inflation, and remove inflationary imbalances
as a cause of economic downturns. For its part, the Federal Reserve can best contribute to
this compact by confirming that it is following a price stability policy through the
announcement of specific inflation targets and a timetable for meeting them. A legislative
mandate along these lines would further strengthen the compact.
I do not think the excellent performance of the U.S. economy during the current
economic expansion is just a chance occurrence. The low-inflation environment has been an




10
important contributing factor, and the public should give monetary policies that have
restrained excessive money growth their due credit for contributing to current economic good
times. The public should also recognize that the Fed's single-minded pursuit of price stability
is the best way it can contribute to an economic environment of sustained growth and a rising
standard of living. Indeed, the best policy for economic growth is to keep inflation low and,
in principle, eliminate it.