View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

"MONETARY POLICY: RULES VERSUS DISCRETION
Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer
The Arkansas Bankers Association Convention
May 16, 1988

Today, perhaps more so than ever before, widespread attention is
being focused on the conduct of this nation's monetary policy.

Regard-

less of whether they are primarily concerned with the threat of future
inflation, the prospect for continued economic expansion, the outlook for
financial markets or the direction of the dollar's movement in exchange
markets, people generally agree that monetary policy is the key factor in
determining what will actually happen. Consequently, it is not surprising
that they devote considerable efforts to interpreting current monetary
policy actions and predicting future ones.

Nor is it surprising that

monetary policymakers find their actions frequently "second guessed" and
occasionally criticized by the public.
Perhaps the harshest public criticism has been directed specifically
against the seemingly vagarious nature of monetary policy actions. People
naturally find unexpected, ofttimes unexplained, policy actions and their
associated unexpected economic consequences to be disconcerting.

One

common response to such criticism is that, by its very nature, monetary
policy can't be "predictable":

indeed, the slogan "monetary policy is an

art, not a science" has been used by so many so often that it has now
nearly achieved "gospel" status.

Before we accept this view as gospel,

however, it might be helpful to determine what it really means and
whether, in fact, it is actually valid.




- 2 -

In the broadest sense, the "monetary policy as art versus science"
debate reflects, once again, the age-old argument about the relative
advantages of rules versus discretion.

In the political arena, we all

recognize that there is a specific combination of some rules and some
discretion that we consider to be optimal at any time.

The consequences

of having too much discretion and too few rules are acknowledged to be as
undesirable as those of having too little discretion and too many rules.
Of

course,

this

same

rules

and

discretion exists when considering the monetary policy process.

Put

simply, the question is:

potential

trade-off

between

should monetary policy decisions be made within

the context of some rules or constraints that are known by the public or
should policymakers have complete discretion?

I would like to emphasize

that I am talking about self-imposed rules which can be changed by the
central bank itself, but with the knowledge of the public.

In order to

see why the debate about rules versus discretion is a vital part of the
monetary policy process, we must first look at how policy actions are
related to the goals of policy.
The basic goals of monetary policy, in the U.S. and abroad, are
clearly recognized and widely accepted.

We know that, over longer time

periods, the rate of inflation we observe results from sizable differences
in the growth in money relative to the growth in the quantity of goods
and services produced.

We also know that, over longer periods of time,

output growth is relatively stable.
the rate of
achieving

one

inflation

is mainly

chief

of

goal

These two observations tell us that
a monetary

policy—the

phenomenon.

desired

long-run

Therefore,
rate

of

inflation—requires making sure that the long-run growth in the quantity
of money is consistent with the inflation goal.




- 3 -

The

second

destabilizing
inducing

generally

employment

recessions.

accepted

and

There

output
is

goal

of

growth—in

evidence

that

policy

is

to

avoid

particular, to avoid
rapid

and

substantial

changes in money growth can temporarily affect economic activity; rapid
accelerations in money

growth

can produce

temporary

expansions, and

severe decelerations in money growth can produce recessions.

If we want

to minimize the periods of economic over-heating and over-cooling that
typically characterize business cycles, we must reduce the volatility of
the growth in money.

In other words, we must generate reasonably stable

monetary growth.
While it may sound easy to accomplish these policy results, I want
to assure you that it is not.

Monetary policymakers must carefully

assess the relationship

their

actions.

between

tools and

the desired

policy

The tools of monetary policy in the United States consist of

the Federal Reserve's ability to change reserve requirements, to change
the discount rate, and

to engage in open market operations.

While

increases and decreases in reserve requirements will affect the growth of
the money stock, this "tool" is seldom used for policy purposes.
Increases and decreases in the discount rate make it more or less
expensive for financial institutions to borrow additional reserves from
the Fed.

Thus, changes in the discount rate, theoretically at least,

could provide a useful tool for policy actions designed to change the
growth of money.

Unfortunately, the precise effects of changes in the

discount rate on borrowed reserves are not that closely predictable:
financial institutions may not be borrowing from the Fed to begin with
and, thus, the change in cost may be irrelevant.

Moreover, even if they

were borrowing, the change in price may be of little consequence.




Thus,

- 4 -

changes in the discount rate in the past have primarily served as policy
"signals" or announcements

by

the

Federal Reserve

to

the financial

community; they have not generally been used as direct policy tool per se.
By simple process of elimination, we can see that open market
operations—the buying and selling of government securities in financial
markets—are the dominant tool of monetary policy.
Reserve

buys

securities, financial

When the Federal

institutions, either

directly

or

ultimately, end up with additional reserves; as a result, additional
loans, deposits and money are created.

In contrast, when the Fed sells

securities, financial institutions lose an equivalent amount of reserves;
as a result, they must contract their activities.

Open market operations

thus have a decided advantage over the other tools of monetary policy;
precise amounts can be added to or subtracted from the reserves of
financial institutions.

The process is both swift and certain.

And,

unlike changes in the discount rate, it does not depend on actions or
reactions of other players in the market.
discussion, I will

consider

open market

For the remainder of this
operations as

the

tool of

monetary policy.
In principle, then, monetary policy should be a simple operation:
if inflation rises above some desired level, the Federal Reserve can sell
securities in the market, reducing the growth of reserves immediately,
the growth of money in some intermediate period, and, finally, the rate
of inflation.

On the other hand, if inflation falls below some desired

level, the opposite policy action should correct the problem.

In general,

however, the appropriate monetary policy would be "steady as you go," the
purpose being to avoid the excessive open market operations and the




- 5 -

associated excessive volatility in money growth that would precipitate
undesirable fluctuations in output and employment.

This, of course, is

where the "rub" is, calculating precisely what "excessive" means.
Unfortunately, both for policymakers and for people in general, our
economy is huge and unwieldy.

As a matter of fact, these days we are

dealing not only with our own economy, but in many respects with the
economy of the world as a whole.

Clearly, an injection of reserves into

a financial system of that size does not produce instantaneous results,
nor does it produce precise results.

A banker who finds himself with

excess reserves may or may not make new loans immediately.
of the loan may or may not spend it immediately.

The recipient

And the rest of the

public who ultimately receive the proceeds of this loan may postpone
spending even longer.

In other words, there are lags between when the

injection of reserves takes place and when the ultimate impact on the
economy occurs.

These lags have been estimated to be as long as several

years; moreover, they appear to vary in length over time depending on a
variety of economic circumstances.
Meanwhile, as the economy grows, demands for money and credit grow
along with it.

Therefore, the appropriate quantity of reserves has to be

supplied on a daily basis.
appropriate?

But what rate of reserve growth is truly

The problem is really not much different from the one faced

by any business.

A firm wants to maximize its profits.

Of course,

between acquiring additional inputs (workers, machines, etc.) and actually
achieving the associated profits, there is generally some time interval.
The firm needs an indicator which is related, at least loosely, to changes
in its inputs and to its ultimate profits, and which is also readily
observable.

For a business firm, the level of output may be such an

indicator. Monetary policy needs an indicator as well.



- 6 -

Such an indicator must perform three basic functions:
reflect

the effects

of

it must

injection of reserves, it must reflect the

movements of policy goals—economic activity, and it must be observable
and measurable in a relatively short span of time.

In other words, such

an indicator must be controllable by the Fed, and it must accurately
relate to GNP.

When such an indicator exists, it becomes a target of

monetary policy, in the sense that reserves are injected or drained on a
daily basis in order to affect this target.

Once such a variable becomes

a

it must

target, it requires another

feature:

be observable and

measurable by the public so that the public can predict or anticipate
short-term actions of the Fed.

A target, in effect, provides a rule

which guides monetary policy decisions.
changed,

just

like

laws

can

be

Of course, the rule can be

changed; however, between changes,

everybody should know the existing rule and play according to it.
Historically, we have
policy purposes.

tried a variety of targets for monetary

Let me mention just a few of them.

The price of gold

was a monetary target for a number of decades in this century.

As it

turned out, however, the gold standard did not produce the desired
results and was abandoned.

Likewise, the modified gold standard-fixed

exchange rate target system used after World War II produced undesirable
fluctuations in GNP; it, too, was abandoned.
After that, we tried using interest rates as a monetary target.
While, for a time, this approach seemed to function well for short-run
purposes, both the controllability of interest rates and their relation
to GNP eventually broke down.




- 7 -

In the mid-seventies and early eighties, we used publicly-announced
money supply targets.

Until the early eighties, they functioned well;

they reflected economic activity with reasonable accuracy and they were
fairly closely related to the reserves provided by the Fed.

Announced

monetary growth ranges provided the public with a guide of behavior on
the part of monetary authorities; to the extent that these rules were
known and followed reasonably closely, they produced a reduction in the
public's uncertainty about what policy actions were likely to do to the
economy.
The negative aspect of a money supply—or monetary aggregate—rule
was the alleged increased volatility of interest rates in the short run.
By the early 1980s, the money supply (that is, Ml) was redefined to
include

all

checkable

deposits, including

interest-bearing

deposits;

about the same time, its relationship to GNP began to change.

While the

Fed's ability to control Ml did not diminish, the money supply's value as
an indicator of current and future GNP growth clearly declined.

Thus,

that rule was abandoned as well.
So what do we have left?

There are many who believe that, at the

present time, policymakers should "look at everything:" that, in essence,
there should be multiple monetary policy targets.

While I sympathize

with those who are frustrated by the present lack of an acceptable single
monetary policy target, I believe that the "look at everything" approach
is likely to prove just as frustrating and potentially damaging as well.
Of course, policymakers should look at all available information
they can obtain concerning the present and future course of economic
activity.

However, to attempt to pursue policy using multiple targets

means, in reality, having no policy rules at all.




Suppose, for example,

- 8 -

that we have two targets, both controllable and both historically related
to GNP.

And suppose that, as has always happened for any pair of

variables, one day their growth rates diverge substantially, either in
direction or in magnitude. Which one should we pay attention to?

Clearly

we must decide which one is likely to be the more reliable.
This problem is compounded, of course, when many targets are being
monitored.

Thus, in one sense, whether we think we are looking at many

targets or not, there can really be only one
consistently.

target

that is used

If we try, instead, to actually set policy by switching

from one target to another, we will end up violating one of the required
features of a target—the ability for the public to anticipate central
bank actions.

Thus, the notion that policymakers can effectively use

multiple targets is, ultimately, more of a delusion than a real option.
Much of the reluctance to have a firm rule arises from an inherent
conflict in almost all decision-making between short-term and long-term
goals.

A good example of such conflict is the alleged

pressure on

corporate managers in recent years to shift their focus from longer-run
profits to immediate or very short-run gains, even if this shift reduces
the firm's longer-run prospects.
eliminate

the

poor

stock

market

The rationale for this shift is to
performance

that

attracts

hostile

take-over or merger activity.
In monetary policymaking, the potential conflict is just as real.
Suppose that, in the immediate future, policymakers would like to reduce
interest rates and, therefore, they make an open market purchase of
securities to pump more reserves into the banking system.

However, if

enough reserves are injected, the economy will grow faster, inflation
will rise, and so will interest rates.




Which goal should we judge as

- 9 -

more important:

lower interest rates now or less inflation and lower

interest rates in the future?

Unfortunately, the absence of a target or

a rule makes it considerably

easier

to pursue short-term

overlook the future consequences for the economy.

goals and

How can we, then,

reconcile some of these conflicts?
One possibility might be some long-term constraint on short-term
discretion.

Let me explain how this could work.

Suppose we agree that,

on a daily or weekly basis, the financial sector of the economy is likely
to be forever subject to a variety of shocks.

These shocks may be major

ones, like an unanticipated oil price increase or whatever produced the
October 19th crash; these shocks may be minor ones, like an unanticipated
movement in the unemployment rate or exchange rate.

If open market

operations to inject or withdraw reserves can alleviate or mitigate the
repercussions of such shocks, the monetary authorities should have the
discretion to react.

In a sense, they should be able to use multiple

targets in the short run and to pursue or abandon whatever targets they
have established.

But if their actions are unconstrained over long time

periods, the inevitable result will be considerably greater financial
uncertainties and more volatile inflation and output growth.
As I have discussed earlier, the monetary aggregates that we used
as targets in the mid-1970s and early 1980s have gone astray in recent
years, at least in terms of their quantitative precision.

However, the

general direction of their influence on spending and prices is still
the same as it was before.

If we inject reserves into the financial

system, we may not be able to predict precisely how much inflation will
accelerate; we can be sure, however, that it will rise.




Thus, while a

- 10 -

specific narrow monetary aggregate target may not be feasible at the
present time, a broad band that constrains the longer-run growth of a
specific monetary aggregate could be both feasible and acceptable.
But what monetary aggregate is more likely to be successful?

If

we want to eliminate the risks that are associated with pure discretion,
it must be one that can be easily and frequently observed, credibly
controllable, and known to the public.
be one

of

those

directly

controlled

This aggregate could actually
by

the

monetary

authorities:

specifically, either total reserves or the monetary base.
While a wide constraint may still imply substantial variation in
the rate of inflation, at least it would
inflation will be.

set

some

limits

on what

That implies that it will set limits on fluctuations

in long-term interest rates and also provide the financial community with
a useful frame of reference for assessing the likely consequences of
monetary policy actions.
What are the negative aspects of a constraint on the growth of
total reserves or the monetary base?

The only one I can think of is that

there may be times when it will require sacrificing short-run goals once
the constraint has been reached.

For example, it may mean that the

federal funds rate may be higher at times than it would be otherwise.
But then, we can directly ask the question that is all too often ignored
when policy actions are discussed:

this question is "Do we benefit more

from longer-run stability in interest rates and reduced long-run inflation
risks or from temporary short-term stability in some interest rate?"
In my opinion, answering this question is the key to long-run
successful policymaking.

And, at the very least, the existence of a

monetary aggregate constraint will require that we address this issue




- 11 -

explicitly and openly.

Without some broad constraint, it becomes more

likely that political pressures can become a significant ingredient in
monetary

policymaking

and

that

sacrificed for short-run gains.




long-run

economic

stability

can

be