View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

"HOW SHOULD MONETARY POLICY RESPOND
TO FISCAL RESTRAINT?"
Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer
Paducah Rotary Club
Paducah, Kentucky
December 12, 1990

After months of haggling, hundreds of hours of debate
and intense political lobbying, Congress and the President
recently agreed to a nearly
deficit-reduction package.

$500 billion,

five-year,

This compromise was forged out

of a growing national concern about the size of the deficit
and its harmful effects. Now that the deal has been struck,
however,

there have been cries from all quarters—the

Administration, Congress and some in the private sector—for
the Federal Reserve to step in and counter the imagined
adverse effects of forthcoming fiscal restraint.
Today, I would like to discuss the question of whether,
in principle, the Fed should respond to these pleas; namely,
should monetary policy be eased in the face of fiscal
restraint.
are,

But before doing this, we need to consider what

in fact, the effects of deficit reduction on the

economy.
A government deficit can be reduced by raising taxes,
cutting spending or,

as the current deficit-reduction

package contemplates, doing both.

While it is difficult to

determine the size of this package,

initial estimates

suggest that it will have a modest effect on the deficit.
The proposed spending cuts, with the exception of those for
defense, are from "planned" rather than current levels.



Consequently, they do not reflect real reductions in the
level of government spending.

Indeed, there is no guarantee

that the spending cuts will even materialize.
Nonetheless, to the extent that cuts in government
spending are realized,

they will initially reduce the

overall demand for goods and services.
taxes on gasoline,

alcohol,

Likewise, increased

luxuries and some peopled

incomes will initially reduce overall spending, as well as
spending on these taxed items.

Therefore, it is reasonable

to expect that such cuts in spending and increases in taxes
will reduce the overall level of output and employment.
Indeed,

there is some evidence that changes in deficit

spending have such short-run effects.
These short-run effects occur, in part, as individuals
who are laid off take time to find employment in other
sectors of the economy.
jobs.

But ultimately these people do find

Thus, the short-run effects of a reduction in the

deficit are truly that; they do not last.

Indeed, the

evidence is strong that changes in deficit spending have no
lasting effects on the level of output, employment, the rate
of inflation or even interest rates.

Thus, despite what

most people clearly believe, the size of the deficit, or the
size of changes in the deficit, just does not matter in the
long run.
How can this be?

How can public opinion be so wrong

about what is likely to occur if deficits are reduced?

The

problem is that we have been taught to believe a myth.

For




2

decades, prevailing economic theory led us to believe that
the effects of government spending on the economy differed
significantly depending upon whether they were financed by
taxes or by issuing government debt.

But this is not the

case.
We

all

understand

that

tax-financed

spending

redistributes income from one individual to another and
causes resources to be reallocated from the production of
some goods and services to the production of others.
However, common sense tells us that tax-financed spending
has no effect on the overall level of economic activity.
The increase in government spending is offset by spending
reductions of those who are taxed.
Certainly less well-known, however, is that, in the
long

run,

exactly

the

same

conclusion

deficit-financed government spending.
confused?

Primarily for two reasons.

holds

for

Why are people so
First, the costs of

government spending are more easily hidden when it is funded
by deficits—it is hard to tell who is really paying the
bill in this case.

Nevertheless, someone is, just as

taxpayers obviously do when spending is financed with taxes.
This is necessarily true because deficit spending has no
effect on output in the long run.

The amount of goods and

services available is the same with or without deficit
spending.

Consequently, the bottom line is that government

can spend more only if someone else spends less.
really only a question of whether we pay now or later.




3

It is

Then too, public officials, the press and even some
economists talk only about the short-run effects of a change
in fiscal policy.

Because their emphasis is on the

immediate consequences of such a change, they place little,
if any,

attention on the absence of long-run effects.

Consequently, many people firmly believe that the economy
would

be

characterized

by

a perpetual

state

of

under-employment without the stimulus of deficit spending.
Of course,

this reinforces their belief that deficit-

financed government spending is "costless."
noted, costless deficit spending is a myth.

But,

as I

Inevitably, the

costs are paid by someone initially—and the taxpayer
ultimately.
Clearly, then, monetary policy should ignore fiscal
actions in the long run.

But what about the short run?

Should monetary policy be eased to offset the short-run
effects of fiscal restraint?

My answer to this question is

"No!"
There are several reasons for this.

First, while

coordinating monetary and fiscal policies sounds simple
enough—merely ease monetary policy when fiscal policy is
tightened

and vice versa--in

practice,

the

proper

coordination of the two is virtually impossible to achieve.
Why?

Because monetary policy affects the economy with lags

that are variable and hard to predict.

Consequently, it is

difficult to determine precisely the right time to ease
monetary policy, and precisely the right amount of easing,




4

to offset the effect of fiscal restraint on output and
employment.

As a result, mistakes will be made.

For example, easier monetary policy might impact the
economy just as the temporary effects of fiscal restraint
are waning.

The result could be a very strong short-run

expansion and, hence, future contraction, just the opposite
of what

the

easing

was trying

to

achieve.

Poorly

coordinated monetary and fiscal policies inevitably make the
economy less stable, not more stable.
Second, regardless of the short-run outcome, easier
monetary policy always leads to higher future inflation.
Indeed, the financial innovations of the 1980s may have made
us less certain about the exact linkages between money
growth, output and inflation in the short run.

But common

sense and empirical evidence both tell us that money growth
and inflation are highly correlated in the long run.
To illustrate, the inflation rate dropped dramatically
in the

early

1980s

following

the

restrictive monetary policy in 1979.

adoption

of

more

And, following the

sharp acceleration in money growth in the middle 1980s,
inflation accelerated in 1987, though less sharply than
expected.

Finally, despite the temporary effects attributed

to the oil price rise,

there have been some positive

developments recently.

The seemingly persistent and

unacceptably high "core" inflation rate of 4 to 5 percent of
the past few years is beginning to respond to the more
restrictive and steadier monetary policy since the middle of




5

1987.

Over this approximately three-year period, money

growth

increased

significantly

at

about

a

from the nearly

3 percent

rate,

down

11 percent rate of the

previous three years. Many forecasters now believe that the
"core" inflation rate will drop significantly over the next
few years.
Finally, there would be yet another cost to a sudden
shift to easier monetary policy
restraint.

in response to fiscal

This cost is more subtle than the ones I have

mentioned so far, but it is certainly as significant to the
economy.

The cost would be the loss of public confidence in

the Federal Reserve's resolve to stabilize the price level.
It would arise because nominal interest rates include a
premium that reflects the market's expectation of inflation.
For example, if I want to earn a "real" 4 percent rate
of return over the next year and expect the inflation rate
to be 5 percent, I must get a nominal return of 9 percent on
my investment.

The inflation premium of 5 percent is just

sufficient to compensate for the expected loss of purchasing
power because of inflation.

Obviously, the best way to keep

nominal interest rates low is to reduce or eliminate any
inflation premium.

But this will not happen

unless

financial market participants believe that prices will
remain stable.

In other words, the Fed's commitment to

price level stability must be seen by all as credible.
At present, as I have already noted, the outlook for
inflation has improved significantly as a result of the




6

Federal Reserve's efforts over the past few years.

These

gains were achieved despite numerous requests for monetary
policy to ease.
requests,

Because the Fed generally resisted these

financial

market

participants

have

come

increasingly to believe that the Fed will stick to its goal
of stable prices.
But, of course, analysts are wary.
the past,

They know that, in

policymakers have succumbed to political and

economic pressures for "short-run" actions that have had
disastrous longer-run consequences.

They are wary because,

in the past, monetary policy has alternated between ease and
restraint, following whatever will-o'-the-wisp problem was
deemed to be the most pressing one at the moment.

And,

especially, they remember just how badly many people got
burned by unanticipated inflation in the late 1960s and
throughout

the

1970s.

This skepticism has built an

uncertainty premium into interest rates in the 1980s that
still has not been removed.
Therefore, in my opinion, an ill-advised and, in the
long run, ill-fated easing of monetary policy to offset the
presumed short-run effect of fiscal restraint would simply
undermine the hard-won credibility that the Federal Reserve
is gaining.

It would almost certainly be taken as a signal

that monetary policy has once again fallen prey to the
political "whims" of the moment.

Much of what we have

gained during the past three and a half years could be lost.




7

And
uncertain

for what?

Simply to avoid a temporary

loss in income and employment—assuming,

and
of

course, that it occurs and that we are clever enough to
offset it without destabilizing the economy.

Surely, the

risks of such a course of action are too great.

If we fail,

the economy will be less stable; the core rate of inflation
will rise; and the credibility gains of the past few years
will be wiped out.

A simple cost/benefit analysis suggests

that these costs far outweigh any conceivable short-run
benefits such monetary policy actions might achieve.
Instead, monetary policy should be focused on the one thing
that it can deliver: long-run price stability.




8