View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

EMBARGOED UNTIL 12:30 p.m. CDT
Thursday, October 3, 1996




"GETTING INFLATION RISK OUT OF INTEREST RATES"

Remarks by
Thomas C. Melzer
President, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

St. Louis Society of Financial Analysts
St. Louis, Missouri

October 3, 1996

It is a pleasure to meet with you today to discuss some issues that, I am sure,
concern us all: inflation, and inflation risk in interest rates. In my remarks today, I
want to talk about two methods of reducing inflation risk in interest rates. The first one
is indexing securities for inflation. The second is more far-reaching—getting inflation
to an effective level of zero and keeping it there. I will make a few comments
concerning the Treasury's plan for introducing index-linked government debt instruments,
and provide my views on how index-linked government debt might help in making
monetary policy. Then I want to turn to the issue of the proper long-run goal for
monetary policy. I want to argue that a credible monetary policy, delivering stable
prices, is the best way to eliminate the inflation risk in interest rates—and the best
monetary policy for promoting economic growth.
Inflation risk premiums
Let me begin with a simple decomposition of interest rates on government
securities that is often used by economists and market participants. The return on a
government debt instrument of a given maturity has at least three components. First,
there is a real component, which compensates investors for the use of their money over
a specific time period.

Second, there is an expected inflation component, which

compensates investors for the loss of purchasing power of their money over the same
period. And, finally, there is an inflation-risk premium, which compensates investors
for taking the risk that inflation will be higher than they expect at the time of purchase.
Estimating the size of these three components in historical data requires
sophisticated econometric analysis, and—even in the best of circumstances—it involves




2

substantial imprecision. But to get a general overview of how these components are
related, it is perhaps useful to consider two periods during the postwar era in the United
States when inflation has been comparatively low and stable.
The first period extended from 1960 through 1965. During these years, inflation
was between Wi and 2 percent, and the ten-year Treasury note was trading to yield
around 4 percent. Most analysts think monetary policy had considerable credibility at
that time, so inflation risk was not a large factor in interest rates. To the extent investors
expected inflation to continue at \lh to 2 percent per year, the bonds were priced for a
real yield of 2 to 2lh percent.
Now contrast that period with the years 1991 through the present, in which
inflation has been near 3 percent and, according to surveys, investors expect it to stay
at about that level. Unlike the yields of 1960 through 1965, ten-year Treasury securities
since 1991 have traded in a range between 6 and 8 percent for most of the period. If
these notes are priced to yield a real return of 2 to 2lh percent, the inflation-risk
premium may be as high as xh to 2lh percentage points.

That is a substantial

premium—one, I believe, that provides a real incentive for considering ways to eliminate
it. One possibility is to use indexed debt instruments.
Index-linked government debt
The Treasury recently announced more details of their plan to issue index-linked
debt beginning in January, but at this point no one can say with any certainty what
percentage of United States government debt might eventually be held in indexed form.
However, I think it is fair to say that the new program has every chance of achieving its
principal aim—that is, reducing the federal government's borrowing costs relative to the




3

costs of a debt portfolio consisting entirely of conventional government bonds. Even if
financial markets correctly anticipate future inflation developments and correctly price
future inflation into current bond yields, real-return bonds are preferable from the
Treasury's perspective. They allow the government to finance the same stream of
expenditures without having to pay an inflation-risk premium on the debt. Eliminating
the inflation-risk premium in government bonds is clearly an improvement in federal
government finance.
The Treasury's new debt program has other interesting features. The government
can, for instance, also save financing costs on a relative basis if the Federal Reserve is
able to deliver a better inflation performance than the financial markets expect at the time
the index-linked bonds are issued. Since I am an advocate of price stability, I hope that
the Fed will actually deliver, over time, the lower-than-expected inflation necessary for
this to occur—and for taxpayers to enjoy some additional savings from this source.
But perhaps the most important aspect of the Treasury's decision is that it changes
some of the inflation control incentives for fiscal authorities, including Congress. In
particular, index-linked debt reduces the incentive for fiscal authorities to pressure the
central bank to monetize the government debt—that is, to purchase more government debt
than otherwise would be the case. This would be a positive development, because
excessivefinancingof government debt by the monetary authority can lead to excessive
monetary growth and, eventually, higher inflation.
Pressures to monetize debt, of course, have not been the recent experience of the
United States. Nevertheless, financial markets are well aware that such possibilities
exist—possibilities that are confirmed not only by our own history, but also by the




4

experience of other countries, some in the not-too-distant past. The potentially insidious
effects of the link between government finance and monetary policy are one reason why
central bank independence is so crucial.
Indexed-linked debt, as it is being proposed by the Treasury, is not, however, a
perfect solution to the elimination of the inflation-risk premium in interest rates. In the
Treasury's proposal, the tax treatment is configured so that the inflation-adjustment
portion of the bond is taxed. Such tax treatment means that not all distortion in interest
rates caused by inflation is eliminated by these new instruments—in other words, on an
after-tax basis, investors are not kept whole. Complications such as these suggest that,
instead of trying to design securities to deal with inflation, we should consider doing
more to try to eliminate inflation.

Index-linked government debt could provide

information that might help monetary policymakers do exactly that.
If sufficient index-linked debt is issued and traded, monetary policymakers will
have a more direct way to observe market-based information on inflation expectations
and real returns. Of course, we have some ways of estimating inflation expectations
today—in part from interest rates themselves, but also from survey data and private and
government economic forecasts. But with index-linked debt, we will have more timely
and more accurate information on this key variable, because we can compare the indexlinked yields with the yields on conventional government debt.
The United Kingdom is one country that has a significant portion of its debt in
index-linked instruments. The central bank there, the Bank of England, uses marketbased information provided by these bonds to calculate measures of inflation expectations
over two-year horizons. This information then feeds into the monetary policymaking




5

process, which is directed toward meeting a stated inflation target. When market-based
measures of inflation expectations exceed the inflation target, monetary policymakers
receive a reasonably clear indication that their current policy is inconsistent with their
stated goals.
Unlike the United Kingdom and many other industrialized countries around the
world, the United States does not have an official inflation target. The main monetary
policymaking arm of the Federal Reserve, the Federal Open Market Committee, or
FOMC, has not specified its long-run inflation goals. So it is not clear how the
information provided by a market in indexed debt will be used by policymakers here.
My own view is that we should take a cue from the United Kingdom and elsewhere and
use the new information on expected inflation as a guide to the amount of credibility
implicit in monetary policy over time. Let me turn now to some of the reasoning behind
this view.
What the Fed should be trying to achieve
There is so much debate about the zigs and zags of monetary policy that
sometimes the big picture falls out of focus. In my view, the aim is to move inflation
toward an effective rate of zero and keep it there. A policy of price stability does the
most that monetary policy can do to meet the objectives laid out in the HumphreyHawkins legislation of 1978. While Fed officials sometimes discuss stable prices as a
long-term goal in their speeches and comments, the FOMC has not identified a price
index that provides a reliable measure of inflation, nor has it specified a target range that
would be acceptable. In my view, failure to make a firm commitment to price stability
puts upward pressure on the inflation-risk premium in interest rates.



6

What's more, the Federal Reserve could be lagging behind in world thinking on
inflation. Countries with formal inflation targets include New Zealand, Canada, the
United Kingdom, Sweden, Finland, Australia, and Spain. Other countries have less
formal, medium-term inflation goals, including Germany, France, Italy, and Switzerland.
These countries have typically chosen target ranges for inflation at least as low and often
lower than the current U.S. inflation rate. And while we have long enjoyed lower actual
inflation than many other countries, the inflation performance of the United States
appears to be deteriorating relative to that of other major industrialized nations. For
1996 and 1997, private forecasters envision the United States as having the secondhighest inflation among the Group of Seven countries. Only Italy's inflation rate is
forecast to be higher.
These forecasters clearly have questions about how committed we are to stable
prices, despite the Fed's professed intentions to move inflation lower over the long
term. This lack of full credibility is also reflected in the views of households and
firms in the United States. Surveys of inflation expectations continue to show that
professional forecasters, market participants, and consumers—as well as the rest of the
Federal government—all think and make plans based on the idea that 3 percent
inflation will prevail well into the next millennium. Three percent might seem low,
but I would remind you that it cuts the value of a dollar in half over a single
generation.
There is wide agreement among professional economists that persistent and
variable inflation is costly for society. It is not difficult to list some of the reasons for




7

this conclusion. Inflation distorts the important signaling role of relative prices in the
economy, so that people have difficulty distinguishing price changes caused by
inflation from those caused by changes in supply or demand. Consequently, people
can get the wrong signals and make the wrong economic decisions. Inflation also
interacts with the tax code to create large distortions in economic decision making.
And many economists have estimated high costs from the "shoe leather" aspect of
inflation—so-named because inflation creates a disincentive to hold money, requiring
people to "walk around" a lot to get rid of money in exchange for goods and services.
In other words, they waste real resources in managing money balances.
These and other arguments about the cost of inflation are well worn—like the
proverbial shoe leather—and I am not going to go into them in any detail here. But
I do want to emphasize that few economists have serious disagreements with the
assessment I am presenting: taken together, the costs of inflation are substantial,
enough so that the best policy is a policy of stable prices. And, a stable price
environment does the most that monetary policy can do to foster the maximum
sustainable rate of real output growth.
All told, I think the benefits of price stability are clear. And since inflation is
the only outcome the Fed can control in the long run, price stability should be the sole
long-run objective of monetary policy.

Adopting this stance would put all

policymakers—as well as the public, Congress and financial market participants—on
the same page with respect to Fed objectives. The Fed could then react to changing




8

economic conditions without creating consternation in financial markets about its
resolve to keep inflation low.
Permanent gains from low inflation
If the FOMC can move inflation to a lower level, a level effectively equal to
zero, and keep it there, the United States economy will enjoy a long era of operation
free from the distortions caused by inflation. That is a permanent gain: year in and
year out, economic decisions will be made without confusion between relative price
changes and price changes caused by inflation. Economic players will not have to
work through a distorted decision process because of the complicated interaction of
inflation with the tax code. And, people will be able to spend less time managing their
assets in order to protect themselves from inflation. Instead, they can devote that time
to better uses. It seems to me that if we care about the long-run efficiency of the
economy, there is little question that we should develop a plan to move toward lower
inflation.
That may sound like a tall order, but I think there is a simple way for the Fed
to take a step in the right direction: The FOMC should announce its inflation forecasts
a number of years into the future. A convenient forum for such an announcement is
the semi-annual Humphrey-Hawkins report to Congress. An inflation forecast by the
Fed gives a best guess of how the policy intentions of the Committee will interact with
developments in the economy as a whole to produce inflation outcomes. That is
exactly the sort of information the American public needs concerning the plans for
monetary policy.




9

Many are undoubtedly concerned that a move to lower inflation would restrain
the economy from its full growth potential in the short run. Admittedly, a surprise
attack on inflation—a "slam-on-the-brakes" disinflation policy—might well have such
an effect. But an organized, well-publicized, and folly expected policy move toward
a stable price environment should pose no danger to the real economy.

It is

unanticipated, stop-and-go policies that make monetary policy and business cycles so
closely connected in many people's minds. A folly anticipated, smooth policy change
will allow markets, consumers, and businesses to plan for the new environment well
in advance. Since participants in the economy will have the opportunity to plan ahead,
the economy will not be forced to adjust to the "shock" from the kind of sudden,
unexpected change in monetary policy that is often discussed by academic economists.
In contrast, planning ahead and announcing intentions will allow markets to act in ways
that reinforce announced plans. Most macroeconomists agree with this position: It is
the unanticipated or surprise component of a change in policy that causes economic
turmoil, not the deliberate, well-publicized effort I am suggesting.
Conclusion
Monetary policy has been a success story over the last 15 years. The Fed has
fought and won a long battle to bring inflation down from the very high levels of the
1970s and early 1980s. In recent years, inflation rates have hovered at some of the
lowest levels in 30 years, and the stabihty of inflation has been remarkable. Lowering
inflation and keeping it reasonably stable have delivered substantial benefits to the U.S.
economy, including an environment conducive to 51 quarters of growth in the last




10

55—the most cyclically stable period in our history. By continuing the fight against
inflation, we can capture more economic gains for the U.S. economy in the years
ahead.
One of those gains would be getting inflation risk out of interest rates. These
risk premiums are costly for the U.S. economy. Indexed-linked government debt
instruments are a step in the right direction, but they provide only a second-best
solution to eliminating inflation risk in interest rates. The first-best solution is to
follow a credible monetary policy that delivers stable prices. That should be the goal
for monetary policy.




Thank you.