View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

EMBARGOED UNTIL 1:30 p.m. CST
Wednesday, January 11, 1995

HOW CAN THE FED INFLUENCE INTEREST RATES AND SUSTAIN GROWTH?




Remarks by
Thomas C. Melzer
President, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Annual Economic Forecast Meeting
Home Builders Association of Greater St. Louis

January 11, 1995

I am pleased to be here today and welcome the opportunity
to discuss an often widely misunderstood topic—the Federal
Reserve's monetary policy.

The Fed is often portrayed as

Scrooge—raising interest rates, slowing the economy, fighting
an imaginary inflation.

The Fed at times is even viewed as

"anti-growth," and its actions especially harmful to those
sectors, like homebuilding, that are interest-sensitive.
This

characterization

pains

me.

I

can

tell

you

definitively that, as a Fed official, I do not like high
interest rates, and I certainly am not "anti-growth."

Quite

the contrary, I seek a monetary policy that fosters the
maximum

sustainable

Sustainable

growth

rate

of

cannot,

growth
however,

for

our

be

economy.

achieved

by

manipulating interest rates in an attempt to rev up the
economy.

Rather, the Fed can best promote low long-term

interest rates and sustainable economic growth by pursuing a
credible monetary policy designed to achieve stability in
prices over time.
I will focus my remarks today on three key points:
First, I will discuss what factors determine economic growth
and how the Fed plays a role; next, I'll turn to how inflation
can impede growth; finally, I'll discuss the benefits of a
credible anti-inflation monetary policy.
Let me get into my first point about determinants of
growth by mentioning that I have spoken with homebuilders on
a

number

of

occasions,

and

I

understand

sensitivity of your business to interest rates.




the

crucial

I was not a

2

Fed official at the time, but can imagine how harmful the high
interest rates of the early '80s must have been for the
construction industry.

As one who now helps determine the

nation's monetary policy, I want to avoid the circumstances
that can lead to such extremes in interest rates.
The way I see it, there are two fundamental determinants
of output growth in any industry: resources, such as labor and
capital, and productivity growth, that is, improvement in the
efficiency with which resources are used to produce goods and
services.

The Fed is often called upon to stimulate the

economy, but except for brief and unpredictable periods,
monetary policy has little, if any, direct effect on economic
growth.

Fundamentally, the production of real goods and

services is determined by real factors, such as employment and
investment in plant and equipment.
Homebuilders often tell me that the region's employment
growth is perhaps the most important influence on the demand
for new construction over time.

But the Fed cannot raise

employment, find new resources or devise ways to increase
productivity.

Indeed, over time, the Fed doesn't even have

much control over the level of interest rates.
The Fed can affect growth indirectly, however, through
the impact of its policy actions on the price level.

If

monetary policy causes excessive fluctuations in the price
level—inflation or deflation—it can hinder the working of a
market economy and interfere with the allocation of resources
to their most productive uses. A monetary policy that limits




3

such fluctuations can contribute to achieving maximum economic
growth over the long haul.
Monetary policy actions are often discussed in terms of
interest rate movements. The power attributed to the Fed over
the level of interest rates, however, reflects a widespread
misunderstanding

over

Monetary

is carried

policy

what

the

Fed

out

can

through

and

cannot

Federal

do.

Reserve

purchase and sale of government securities, the so-called open
market operations.

These operations affect the volume of

reserves that commercial banks have available to make loans
and other investments and, ultimately, that determine the
nation's money supply.

Now, undoubtedly these operations do

affect various interest rates, especially short-term interest
rates such as the federal funds rate, which is the interest
rate that banks charge one another for overnight loans of
reserves.

But all interest rates are determined by market

forces—supply and demand—and the Fed has relatively little
direct influence, especially on long-term interest rates such
as those for Treasury bonds or mortgages.
One might think that the Fed could push interest rates as
low as it wanted simply by increasing the amount of money it
supplies to the economy.

The consequence of such a policy,

however, would be to generate inflation—excessive money
growth causing prices to rise.

After a time, the effort to

lower interest rates would backfire and end up producing
higher interest rates instead.

Sooner or later, the public

would recognize that the Fed was pursuing an inflationary




4

policy and demand higher nominal interest rates to compensate
for higher inflation.

In this way, inflation is like a tax

that, among other things, erodes the purchasing power of those
who save or invest.
The principal way that monetary policy can hold down
long-term interest rates is thus by holding down expectations
of future inflation.

A policy that is strongly committed to

maintaining stability of the price level over time will
minimize expected inflation and therefore produce lower longterm interest rates than otherwise. Keep inflation down, and
long-term interest rates will be low.

Of course, interest

rates will always rise and fall to some extent—even when
there is no inflation—but rates will be lower in the absence
of inflation than they would be if prices are rising.
My second point is that inflation can impede growth.
First, inflation can hinder economic performance by causing
interest

rates to be high.

Another

problem with high

inflation is that it tends to be quite variable from one year
to the next.

When the rate of inflation varies widely from

year-to-year, business people and consumers have difficulty
planning their investments and expenditures because inflation
camouflages the signals given by changes in relative prices.
A construction firm that experiences an increase in the price
of lumber, for example, will be unsure how much of the
increase reflects factors unique to its own market as opposed
to

a

general

possibilities




inflation.

The

implications

for the firm may be very

of

the two

different.

An

5

inability to distinguish changes in relative prices from
changes in the general price level will likely lead to
inefficient resource allocation, and hence to lower growth.
High and unstable inflation also encourages people to
divert

resources

away

from

productive

inflation hedges and speculative ventures.

investment

into

The overbuilding

in commercial real estate and the speculative frenzy that
characterized many metals and commodity markets in the late
'70s and early '80s, for example, reflected expectations of
continued price increases, not fundamental values.
Inflation

also

promotes

borrowing

and

consumption,

because a rising price level means that debts will be repaid
with dollars that buy less in the future than they do today.
Though more limited now, for many years consumer interest
payments were deductible from taxable income, which made
borrowing more attractive when inflation was high. Meanwhile,
savers

were

taxed

on

their

inflation-adjusted income.

nominal

income,

not

their

It was not uncommon in the '70s

for savers to lose wealth on their financial investments in
real terms, despite having a nominal gain and an income tax
liability.

Not surprisingly, people expend considerable

resources trying to forecast inflation and find inflation
hedges. In the absence of inflation, these resources could be
allocated to more productive uses.
This brings me to my third main point. We have seen how
inflation

can hinder

economic

performance.

A

credible

commitment by monetary policymakers to low inflation, on the




6

other hand, can reap many benefits.

If the public believes

that the Fed will maintain price stability, the inflation
premium in interest rates and the allocation of resources
toward inflation hedges will be minimized, and the meaning of
individual price and wage signals will be clearer.
Let me give you a few examples of the value of a credible
anti-inflation policy.

Last year the United States and

Argentina had similar rates of inflation—about 3 percent in
the U.S. and 3.5 percent in Argentina.

Why was it then that

investors were willing to buy U.S. government securities
yielding 8 percent, but required a return of 16 percent on
Argentinean government securities?

Some of the difference in

yields might be explained by political risk, or simply the
difficulty

of

obtaining

information

about

securities

in

Argentina, but surely one reason has to do with inflation.
Even though

inflation

is now roughly

the

same

in both

countries, our histories with inflation are very different.
For many years, Argentina had high inflation, which penalized
those who saved.

Compared to Argentina, inflation has been

relatively low over time in the U.S. , and hence the public has
more confidence in the future value of the dollar than it has
in the Argentinean peso. Simply put, interest rates are lower
in the United States in part because our central bank has more
credibility at controlling inflation.
Let's look at a few more countries. Among the industrial
countries, the differences in government bond yields are less
stark. Still, during 1994 long-term government bond yields in




7

G-10 countries ranged from a bit over 3 percent in Japan to
nearly 9 percent in Italy.

More often than not, countries

that have had a history of relatively high inflation, such as
Italy, have higher long-term interest rates than historically
low inflation countries, like Japan. This relationship holds
true

even

for

inflation.

countries

with

similar

current

rates of

I interpret these numbers as saying that the more

successful a country has been at controlling inflation in the
past, the lower long-term

interest rates will be today,

irrespective of the current year's inflation.

Credibility

takes time to build, but we see that it does produce real
benefits in terms of lower long-term interest rates.
Now, let me turn to the recent behavior of long-term
interest rates in this country.

Remember that the Federal

Reserve affects the volume of bank reserves and the money
supply. Fed actions have little direct influence on interest
rates, which are determined by supply and demand.

Long-term

interest rates rose over the past year, especially during the
first half.

Several factors may have contributed to this

increase, but I believe that one reason was the expectation of
rising inflation.
From 1991 to 1993, the Fed pursued an aggressively
stimulative monetary policy.
rapidly.

Bank reserves and Ml grew very

At the same time, proposals were floating in

Congress to limit the Fed's independence
Because inflation results primarily

from politics.

from excessive money

supply growth, and because it tends to be higher in countries




8

where the central bank is more directly under the control of
politicians, I believe that doubts were raised in the public's
mind about the Fed's commitment to controlling inflation.
Although interest rates tended to fall during this period,
much of the decline was in short-term rates.
As the Fed began to tighten policy in early 1994, longterm interest rates increased by about as much as short rates.
By mid-year this pattern had largely ended, however, and
further

increases

in short-term

interest rates were not

matched by increases in long rates. In fact, when short-term
rates increased by 75 basis points in November, long-term
rates actually fell.
The

experience

credibility can be.

of

1994

demonstrates

how

fragile

It also shows, however, that increasing

public confidence in the willingness of monetary policymakers
to hold the line on inflation can help reduce long-term
interest rates.
inflation

That is, by establishing a credible anti-

policy,

policymakers

can

lessen

premium and encourage long-term investment.

the

inflation

Such a policy

also limits confusion over the meaning of individual price
changes and minimizes the unproductive use of resources in the
search for inflation hedges.
To conclude, let me restate the question posed in the
title of my talk:

"How can the Fed influence interest rates

and sustain economic growth?"
Some would have us adopt highly stimulative monetary
policies to push interest rates lower and speed up the




9

economy.

Inflation is not a problem right now, these people

say, so let's lower interest rates to propel growth.

We can

always reverse our policy later if inflation accelerates.
We have seen, however, that such a prescription for
monetary policy is short-sighted and would risk worsening
economic performance.

I think that none of us wants a

monetary policy that reacts excessively to the latest economic
news, or one that pushes down hard on the gas to rev up the
economy one year, then slams on the brakes the next.

Such a

policy puts too great a burden on the marketplace and causes
the public to waste time and resources trying to figure out
how policy will affect them and their businesses.
The gains in production or employment that may come from
adopting a highly stimulative monetary policy tend to be
short-lived, while the increased inflation it generates lasts
much

longer and ultimately requires painful measures to

restrain

it.

generates

Eventually,

only

employment.

inflation,

excessive
not

gains

monetary
in

stimulus

production

or

Our own experience, as well as that of other

countries, has taught us that monetary policy can best promote
low long-term interest rates and sustainable economic growth
only when it is oriented toward controlling inflation.
Price stability and sustainable growth are thus not
incompatible.

In fact, one requires the other.

A monetary

policy that is strongly committed to price stability is a progrowth policy.

The answer to the question of how the Fed can

influence interest rates and sustain growth, therefore, is by




10

adopting a policy of price stability.
historical

record

supports

and

what

That's what the
I

believe

appropriate goal of a pro-growth monetary policy.




is

the