View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

DEPOSIT INSURANCE REFORM: SOME OVERLOOKED ISSUES
Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer
Banking Law Seminar
Sponsored by University of MissouriKansas City School of Law
St. Louis, Missouri
October 29, 1990
Last year, Congress passed the Financial Institutions
Reform, Recovery and Enforcement Act to deal with the thrift
crisis.

While this legislation focused mainly on treating

the symptoms of the thrift problem,

it did require the

Treasury to study deposit insurance reform and report back
to Congress by next February.
cost

estimates

escalated,

for

In the meantime, however, as

resolution

of problem

thrifts

so too has the sense of urgency

deposit insurance reform.

have

surrounding

In fact, Congress recently held

hearings on the subject, well in advance of completion of
the Treasury study.

Consequently, whether you think that

such reform is a bad idea or a good idea, it is indeed one
whose time is rapidly approaching.
Unfortunately, whenever there are strong pressures on
policymakers to reach significant and far-reaching decisions
quickly, some important issues can be overlooked.
insurance reform is no exception.

Deposit

In fact, the risks of an

oversight are quite large, as deposit insurance has come to
have a broad role in our financial system.

In addition, the

large number of reform proposals may tend to complicate the
debate

without

necessarily

clarifying

the

issues.

Accordingly, in the next few minutes I would like to set




1

forth a framework for categorizing various proposals and
discuss some issues that I believe should be considered,
carefully and thoughtfully, before deposit insurance reform
becomes a reality.
Deposit insurance was intended originally to protect
small depositors and help prevent runs on banks.

A side

effect, however, was what has become known as the moral
hazard problem:

that is, if bank owners and managers have

nothing to lose, what is to stop them from attracting
insured deposits at high rates of interest and investing
them

in very

risky

undertakings?

Currently,

bank

shareholders, to the extent that their equity has value, and
government bank supervisors share this responsibility;
however, given the existing deposit insurance program, the
cost of bad decisions and bad luck is borne primarily by the
deposit insurance funds.

And, as we have come to learn so

painfully, losses that exceed the net worth of the funds are
borne by us, the taxpayers.
Some proposed reforms would strengthen the powers of
bank supervisors.

Others would require depositors to assume

a greater share of the costs of bank failures. Accordingly,
the depositors would be expected to take on increased
responsibility for assessing and limiting bank risk.

Let's

consider each of these proposed types of reform in turn.
The argument in favor of increased powers for bank
supervisors is that banks have assumed too much risk and
that supervisors should be given greater power to limit




2

risks.

On its face, this seems to be a very reasonable

proposition, especially in view of some of the stories we
have heard about the thrifts. Unfortunately, however, it is
all too easy to overlook the disadvantages of this approach;
consequently, I want to focus on these.

Two examples should

illustrate both the proposed reforms that would increase
powers for bank supervisors and the potential disadvantages
associated with doing this.

One proposal being considered

is the introduction of deposit insurance premiums based on
the risks assumed by banks as perceived by bank supervisors.
The second proposal would require bank supervisors to apply
progressively stronger discipline on banks whose capital
ratios fall below the established standards. Now, how could
these proposed reforms possibly have serious disadvantages?
What have we overlooked?
First, these proposals assume that bank supervisors are
able to determine both the risks facing banks and the
current market values of all bank assets and liabilities.
Second, and much more serious, is that such bank supervision
and regulation will, at the margin, stifle bank innovation
and competition.

To see why, consider that, from the bank

supervisor's perspective, the best of all possible outcomes
would be zero bank failures—which could occur only if even
the most bungling bank management couldn't possibly fail.
In order to reduce the chances of bank failure, supervisors
will

inevitably

exaggerate

the risks

involved

in new

services or banking practices and retard their adoption.




3

Moreover, one easy way to reduce the potential number of
bank failures would be to restrict the extent of competition
in banking.

How?

Simply by imposing restrictions both on

the more aggressive banks and on new entry into banking.
The key issue I want to emphasize is not whether good
and valid reasons for strengthening the powers of bank
supervisors actually exist. In fact, they do exist.

My

point is simply that there are costs associated with doing
so.

And,

these costs, the potentially adverse social

consequences

of such regulatory

actions,

are

often

overlooked when the regulatory bandwagon rolls by.
Now,

what about the proposed

reforms that would

increase the role of depositors in limiting banking risk?
These proposals include reducing the size of the insured
account, introducing some form of co-insurance and, perhaps,
limiting the total number of insured accounts that any
individual can hold regardless of where they are held.

The

intent of these proposals is to increase the risk or cost of
bank failure borne by depositors.

Now, of course, these

proposed reforms will be for naught unless the notion that
some banks

are too big to fail

is also

eliminated.

Otherwise, depositors will reduce their risks by shifting to
those banks that they perceive as too big to fail.

In this

case, the reforms would simply raise costs at the smaller
banks without limiting the risks assumed by the larger ones.
Given the recent history of banking supervision in this
country, the mere announcement that, henceforth, no bank




4

will be considered "too big to fail" probably would not
convince depositors at the biggest banks that their funds
were at risk.

I will leave it to your imagination to think

of what might actually convince such skeptical depositors.
Now,

why would anyone really believe that giving

depositors an increased regulatory role would be a good
idea?

What are the advantages of adding an additional bank

risk "enforcer"—the bank depositor—to the game?

At first

glance, many individuals would consider such reform to be a
step backwards, a reversion to times when banking risks were
seemingly

increased,

not decreased,

uninsured

depositors.

Could

by the actions of

increasing the role of

depositors really be a good idea?

What have we overlooked

here?
First, deposit insurance reforms that place depositors
with accounts in excess of the insurance limit at risk might
enhance

the

effectiveness

of

disciplining the more risky banks.

bank

supervisors

in

The more risk-averse

depositors will place their funds with the less-risky banks;
other depositors will force the riskier banks to pay higher
interest rates for deposits.

Thus, depositors, as well as

bank supervisors, will point out to bank shareholders and
management that greater risk is costly.
These actions by large depositors will also reinforce
bank supervisors1 actions aimed at having banks achieve and
maintain adequate capital ratios.

Other things the same,

banks with higher capital ratios are less risky banks.




5

If

less risky banks are able to attract funds at lower interest
costs, banks will find that it pays them to increase their
capital ratios.
An additional overlooked benefit from this reform is
that, if banks as a group maintain higher capital ratios,
supervisors will be able to change the focus of their
efforts.

Instead of second-guessing management decisions at

each and every bank, they will be able to concentrate more
of their resources on those banks in poor

financial

condition and those who persist in engaging in higher-risk
activities.
Finally, the proposed reforms that place greater risks
on large depositors might reduce the losses to the bank
insurance

funds by

limiting

the discretion

of

bank

supervisors to offer forbearance to troubled banks.

The

mass exodus of large depositors from troubled banks would
force bank supervisors to deal with those problems much more
quickly than they have in the past. Our experience over the
last decade shows clearly that losses to the deposit
insurance funds generally increased substantially whenever
the supervisory agencies granted forbearance.
Up to now,

we have considered only the positive

consequences of deposit insurance reforms that increase
risks of large depositors.
about

nature

that

However, there is something

abhors

a

"free

lunch."

And,

unfortunately, these reforms also have some important, often




6

overlooked, implications for international competition in
banking services and for the scope of authority of U.S.
banking supervisors.
Our previous discussion,

like many discussions of

deposit insurance reform, ignored the fact that U.S. banks
compete in an international banking arena.

Suppose that, as

a result of deposit insurance reform, large depositors at
U.S. banks now find their deposits to be riskier, even those
deposits at the largest U.S. banks which, previously, had
been too big to fail.

What would you expect them to do when

they also discover that, unlike the new U.S. policy, the
governments of other developed countries are willing to
guarantee all deposits at their countries1 banks—even those
at their branches in the U.S.?

Obviously, large depositors

will simply shift their deposits to the offices of foreign
banks operating here and abroad.

The net result would be to

reduce the relative size and importance of the U.S. banking
industry worldwide.
Another

overlooked

consequence

of

these

reform

proposals is that they will place increased pressures on the
Federal Reserve System.

Any deposit insurance reform that

places large depositors at greater risk will increase the
probability that, occasionally,

there will be depositor

"runs" on individual banks; even less often, perhaps because
of unusually bad news affecting many banks, there may be
runs on large numbers of banks.

Thus, such reforms will

contribute to increased importance of the Federal Reserve's




7

role as the nation's

"lender of last resort."

This

increased pressure on the Federal Reserve has both a "good
news" and a "bad news" aspect to it.

First, the good news

is that the Federal Reserve has learned an important lesson
from the 1930s, when its failure to act forcefully enough as
a lender of last resort, according to some monetary history
writers,

contributed to the resulting economic downswing.

We certainly would not make that mistake again.
However, the bad news is that, in acting as the lender
of last resort, the Federal Reserve might have to take
considerable losses on its loans to troubled banks. How
would this happen?

In the event of a widespread depositor

run on many banks at the same time, the Federal Reserve
might have to concentrate more on preventing a nationwide
liquidity crisis than on determining the solvency of the
banks it lends to or the quality of their collateral.
such a time,

At

it is extremely difficult to determine,

particularly on such short notice, which banks are solvent
and which are not; this is especially true if the news that
triggered the banking crisis raises substantial doubts about
the underlying values of assets at many banks.
conditions,

the

Federal

Reserve

could

Under these

end

up

with

substantial losses. The irony in this situation is that the
federal government would not eliminate its exposure to
losses

if

it reduces deposit

insurance

presumably shifts the risk to depositors.




8

coverage

and

Is this
Ultimately,

"shifty"

operation

a good

idea

anyway?

Congress will have to make that decision.

However, there is a story about the Fed's operation in the
early 1930s that might help to illustrate the potential
conflicts that any central bank faces during a banking
crisis.

One day, in the midst of the nation's worst banking

crisis,

the president of a small bank called the Fed.

Panic-stricken, he explained that his bank faced a run by
depositors and that he needed our help.

The Fed official

who took the call, noticing that the Fed had an outstanding
loan to this bank, told the bank's president that an armored
car would be dispatched immediately. When the armored car
arrived at the bank, the president ran out, shouting "You
arrived just in time.

Bring the cash in right away."

The

Fed staff member who accompanied the armored car said,
"Bring it in?

We're here to get ours back."

Now, as I noted earlier, the Fed has learned a lot
about central banking since the early 1930s.

The point of

the story, however, and the point of my entire discussion is
simply that reform of the nation's deposit insurance program
is likely to have considerably greater consequences than
have been generally recognized.

In particular, the various

proposals intended either to strengthen the role of bank
supervisors or to induce greater depositor discipline of
banking risk have broad but often overlooked implications




9

for the operation of our banking system.

Let us hope that

these implications will not remain overlooked when Congress
gets down to debating the merits of these various proposals.




10