View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

DEPOSIT INSURANCE REFORM: SOME OVERLOOKED ISSUES
Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer
Day with the Bank Commissioner
Little Rock, Arkansas
June 27, 1990

The

Financial

Institutions

Reform,

Recovery

and

Enforcement Act, passed by Congress last year, required the
Treasury Department to study deposit insurance reform.
Their report is due by next February.

While there are few

"sure things" in this life, it is a reasonably good bet
that,

in the next year or so, Congress will make major

changes

in the

nation 7 s

deposit

insurance

program.

Consequently, whether you think that such reform is a bad
idea or a good idea, it is clearly an idea whose time is
rapidly approaching.
Unfortunately, like rapidly approaching thunderstorms
and freight trains, rapidly approaching ideas can also be
quite dangerous to the public at times.

Whenever there are

strong pressures on policymakers to reach significant and
far-reaching

decisions quickly,

occasionally are overlooked.

some

important

issues

In the next few minutes, I

would like to discuss some issues that I believe should be
considered,

carefully and thoughtfully,

before deposit

insurance reform becomes a reality.
I want to assure you, before we consider these issues,
that I do not believe Congress will necessarily overlook
them in its debates on deposit insurance reform;




1

however,

in my opinion, several of these issues have been overlooked
in much of the recent public discussion on this matter.
Therefore, because Congressional actions are influenced by
public concerns and public opinion, I would like to see
these issues receive some recognition.

And, what better

place to achieve this than right here at the Day With the
Bank Commissioners.
Now, I certainly don't have to tell you why deposit
insurance reform is imminent.
growing,

The already huge, but still

cost of the federal governments commitment to

depositors at bankrupt savings and loan associations is
certainly the primary reason to expect changes.

Another,

related reason reflects the strong pressures from large
banks who want to obtain permission for activities that they
are now

locked out of by current banking regulations.

Changes in the deposit insurance program are necessary if
the range of permissible banking activities

is to be

broadened, while, at the same time, the deposit insurance
fund's exposure to prospective and actual losses is to be
reduced.
Several types of deposit insurance reform have been
proposed recently.

Not surprisingly,

all of them are

intended to reduce the risk assumed by banks.

There is one

fundamental question that must be addressed before choosing
which prospective change to adopt.

That question is, who

should be responsible for limiting the risks assumed by
banks?




Currently, bank shareholders and government bank
2

supervisors share this responsibility; however, given the
current deposit insurance program, the cost of bad decisions
and bad luck is borne primarily by taxpayers.

Some proposed

reforms would strengthen the powers of bank supervisors.
Others would require depositors to assume a greater share of
the costs of bank failures.
be expected

As a result, depositors would

to take on increased

assessing and limiting bank risk.

responsibility

for

Let's consider each of

these proposed reforms in turn.
The arguments in favor of increased supervision by bank
regulators are obvious; so much so, in fact, that there is
no reason to detail them here. Unfortunately, it is all too
easy to overlook the disadvantages of increased powers for
bank supervisors; consequently, I want to focus on these.
Two examples should illustrate both the proposed reforms
that would increase powers for bank supervisors and the
potential disadvantages associated with doing this.

One

proposal being considered is the introduction of deposit
insurance premiums based on the risks assumed by banks as
perceived by bank supervisors.

The second proposal would

require bank supervisors to apply progressively stronger
discipline on banks whose capital ratios fall below the
established

standards.

Now,

how could these proposed

reforms possibly have serious disadvantages?

What have we

overlooked?
First, these proposals assume that bank supervisors are
able to determine, better even than bank shareholders and




3

management, both the risks facing banks and the current
market values of all bank assets and liabilities.

Second,

and much more serious, is that such bank supervision and
regulation will, at the margin, stifle bank innovation and
competition.

To see why, consider that, from the bank

supervisors perspective, the best of all possible outcomes
would be zero bank failures—which could occur only if even
the most bungling bank management couldn,t possibly fail.
In order to reduce the chances of bank failure, supervisors
will

inevitably

exaggerate

the risks

involved

in new

services or banking practices and retard their adoption.
Moreover, one easy way to reduce the potential number of
bank failures would be to restrict the extent of competition
in banking.

How?

Simply by imposing restrictions both on

the more aggressive banks and on new entry into banking.
The key issue I want to emphasize is not whether good
and valid reasons for strengthening the powers of bank
supervisors actually exist. In fact, they do exist.

My

point is simply that there are costs associated with doing
so.

And,

these costs, the potentially adverse social

consequences

of

such regulatory

actions,

are

often

overlooked when the regulatory bandwagon rolls by.
Now,

what

about the proposed

reforms that would

increase the role of depositors in limiting banking risk?
As you know, these proposals include reducing the size of
the insured account, introducing some form of co-insurance
and, perhaps, limiting the total number of insured accounts




4

that any individual can hold regardless of where they are
held.

The intent of these proposals is to increase the risk

or cost of bank failure borne by depositors.

Now, of

course, these proposed reforms will be for naught unless the
notion

that

eliminated.

some banks are too big to

fail

is

also

Otherwise, depositors will reduce their risks

by shifting to those banks that they perceive as too big to
fail.

In this case, the reforms would simply raise costs at

the smaller banks without limiting the risks assumed by the
larger

ones.

Given

the recent

history

of

banking

supervision in this country, the mere announcement that,
henceforth, no bank will be considered "too big to fail"
probably would not convince depositors at the biggest banks
that their funds were at risk.

I will leave it to your

imagination to think of what might actually convince such
skeptical depositors.
Now,

why would anyone really believe that giving

depositors an increased regulatory role would be a good
idea?

What are the advantages of adding an additional bank

risk "enforcer"—the bank depositor—to the game?

At first

glance, many individuals would consider such reform to be a
step backwards, a reversion to times when banking risks were
seemingly

increased,

not decreased,

uninsured

depositors.

Could

depositors really be a good idea?

by the actions of

increasing

the role of

What have we overlooked?

First, deposit insurance reforms that place depositors
with accounts in excess of the insurance limit at risk might




5

enhance

the

effectiveness

of

bank

disciplining the more risky banks.

supervisors

in

The more risk-averse

depositors will place their funds with the less-risky banks;
other depositors will force the riskier banks to pay higher
interest rates for deposits.

Thus, depositors, as well as

bank supervisors, will point out to bank shareholders and
management that greater risk is costly.
These actions by large depositors will also reinforce
bank supervisors7 actions intended to have banks achieve and
maintain adequate capital ratios.

Other things the same,

banks with higher capital ratios are less risky banks.

If

less risky banks are able to attract funds at lower interest
costs, banks will find that it pays them to increase their
capital ratios.
An additional overlooked benefit from this reform is
that, if banks as a group maintain higher capital ratios,
supervisors will be able to change the focus of their
efforts.

Instead of second-guessing management decisions at

each and every bank, they will be able to concentrate more
of their resources on those banks

in poor

financial

condition and those who persist in engaging in higher-risk
activities.
Finally, the proposed reforms that place greater risks
on large depositors might reduce the losses to the bank
insurance

funds by

limiting

the discretion

of

bank

supervisors to offer forbearance to troubled banks.

The

mass exodus of large depositors from troubled banks would




6

force bank supervisors to deal with those problems much more
quickly than they have in the past.

Our experience over the

past decade shows clearly that losses to the deposit
insurance funds generally increased substantially whenever
the supervisory agencies granted forbearance.
Up to now,

we have considered

only the positive

consequences that might arise if certain deposit insurance
reforms that increase risks of large depositors are enacted.
However, there is something about nature that abhors a "free
lunch."

And, unfortunately, these reforms also have some

important, often overlooked, implications for international
competition

in banking

services and for the

scope of

authority of U.S. banking supervisors.
Our previous discussion,

like many discussions of

deposit insurance reform, ignored the fact that U.S. banks
compete in an international banking arena.

Suppose that, as

a result of deposit insurance reform, large depositors at
U.S.

banks now find their deposits riskier,

deposits at the largest U.S. banks.

even those

What would you expect

them to do when they also discover that, unlike the new U.S.
policy, the governments of other developed countries are
willing to guarantee all deposits at their countries'
banks—even those at their branches in the U.S. Obviously,
large depositors will simply shift their deposits to the
offices of foreign banks operating here and abroad.

The net

result would be to reduce the relative size and importance
of the U.S. banking industry worldwide.




7

Another

overlooked

consequence

of

these

reform

proposals is that they will place increased pressures on the
Federal Reserve System.

Any deposit insurance reform that

places large depositors at greater risk will increase the
probability that, occasionally,

there will be depositor

"runs" on individual banks; even less often, perhaps because
of unusually bad news affecting many banks, there may be
runs on large numbers of banks.

Thus, such reforms will

contribute to increased importance of the Federal Reserve's
role as the nation's

"lender

of

last resort."

This

increased pressure on the Federal Reserve has both a "good
news" and a "bad news" aspect to it.

First, the good news

is that the Federal Reserve has learned an important lesson
from the 1930s, when its failure to act forcefully enough as
a lender of last resort, according to some monetary history
writers,

contributed to the resulting economic downswing.

We certainly would not make that mistake again.
However, the bad news is that, in acting as the lender
of last resort, the Federal Reserve might have to take
considerable losses on its loans to troubled banks. How
would this happen?

In the event of a widespread depositor

run on many banks at the same time, the Federal Reserve
might have to concentrate more on preventing a nationwide
liquidity crisis than on determining the solvency of the
banks it lends to or the quality of their collateral.
such a time,

At

it is extremely difficult to determine,

particularly on such short notice, which banks are solvent




8

and which are not; this is especially true if the news that
triggered the banking crisis raises substantial doubts about
the underlying values of assets at many banks.
conditions,

the

substantial losses.

Federal

Reserve

could

Under these

end

up

with

The irony in this situation is that the

federal government would not eliminate its exposure to
losses

if

it reduces deposit

insurance

coverage

and

presumably shifts the risk to depositors.
Is

this

Ultimately,

"shifty"

operation

a good

idea

anyway?

Congress will have to make that decision.

However, there is a story about the Fed's operation in the
early 193 0s that might help to illustrate the potential
conflicts that any central bank faces during a banking
crisis.

One day, in the midst of the nation's worst banking

crisis,

the president of a small bank called the Fed.

Panic-stricken, he explained that his bank faced a run by
depositors and that he needed our help.

The Fed official

who took the call, noticing that the Fed had lent to this
bank previously, told the bank's president that an armored
car would be dispatched immediately. When the armored car
arrived at the bank, the president ran out, shouting "You
arrived just in time.

Bring the cash in right away."

The

Fed staff member who accompanied the armored car said,
"Bring it in?

We're here to get ours back."

Now, as I noted earlier, the Fed has learned a lot
about central banking since the early 1930s.

The point of

the story, however, and the point of my entire discussion is




9

simply that reform of the nation's deposit insurance program
is likely to produce considerably more effects than have
been generally recognized.

In particular,

the various

proposals intended either to strengthen the role of bank
supervisors or to induce greater depositor discipline of
banking risk have broad but often overlooked implications
for the operation of our banking system.

Let us hope that

these implications will not remain overlooked when Congress
gets down to debating the merits of the various proposals
for reforming deposit insurance.




10