View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

1986: WHAT WE KNOW, WHAT WE DON'T KNOW AND WHAT WE KNOW AINfT SO
Remarks by Thomas C. Melzer
to the St. Louis Society of Financial Analysts
January 8, 1986
I appreciate the opportunity to be with you today.

Some months ago

when I was asked to address the Society early in 1986, I thought it might
be appropriate to discuss the Bank's outlook for the coming year.

Now

that the time has arrived, however, I question whether I should make any
predictions.

First of all, I'm not really confident of my prognostic

abilities right now.
win big last week.

I was convinced that the Cowboys and Raiders would
Of course, if football scores were treated like GNP

numbers, both teams may in fact have won.

Even if the "flash" estimates

of the scores might look bad, with some appropriate data revisions and
new seasonal adjustments, both could easily be winners.
The main reason for my reluctance

is that uncertainties about

prospective policy actions are greater this year than they have been in
recent years.

Consequently, our predictions have a longer-than-usual set

of assumptions attached to them.

Unfortunately, people typically remember

predictions but forget the conditions underlying them.

This is fine if

your predictions come true; no one will notice that you were right for
all the wrong reasons.

But it is important to remember that predictions

can be wrong for the right reasons; that the conditions—including policy
actions—necessary to make them come true failed to materialize.

With

this stringent warning, I would like to talk about what we know and what
we don't know for 1986.
Real Economic Growth and Employment

There are a variety of factors

that will influence real economic growth and employment in 1986.

First,

long-run trends in population growth and productivity have produced real
GNP growth of about 3 percent per year for the past 90 years.




This

- 2 -

long-run average rate of real growth allows the economy to absorb the
growth in the labor force without significant increases in unemployment.
Considering only these longer-run influences, we would expect real output
to grow about 3 percent and unemployment to remain close to 7 percent in
1986.
The rapid money growth that we had in 1985 is a second influence on
real output, at least for the first part of 1986.

Based on our work at

the Bank, accelerations in money growth typically precede faster economic
growth, and decelerations in money
slowdowns.

growth typically

The lag between significant

changes

precede economic

in money

growth and

movements in real output is fairly short, about six to nine months.
There was a considerable jump in money growth last year—it grew about
12 percent in 1985, up sharply from about 7 percent in 1984—and the
impact of this surge in money growth on spending and output should spill
over into the first part of this year.

Adding to this positive but

temporary influence on real output and employment during this year are
the continuing declines in oil prices.

Lower energy prices not only

serve to restrain price increases in general, they also provide an impetus
for increased production.

Consequently, given what we know, real economic

growth is likely to come in around 3.5 to 4.0 percent in 1986.

As a

result, the unemployment rate should drop slightly below its current
7.0 percent level.
But what about what we don't know?

The two biggest unknowns that

will affect the economy this year, and for years to come for that matter,
are fiscal and monetary policy actions.

Over longer periods, changes in

government spending seem to have little effect on the economy; for shorter
periods, however, such as two or three quarters, changes in government




- 3 -

expenditures have discernible effects on spending and output.

There

appears to be considerable confusion over what is likely to happen to
government expenditures, especially in the light of Gramm-Rudman.

More-

over, the confusion over tax reform makes it difficult to predict what is
likely to happen to business investment.

The possibility of future tax

increases if Gramm-Rudman is constitutional, and government expenditures
are not cut, makes investment predictions even more difficult.
If last year is any indication, monetary policy actions, at least
as far as the growth of Ml is concerned, are also subject to considerable
uncertainty.

As you well know, there were two sets of monetary targets

announced last year.

Because money growth was so strong in the first

part of the year, the first target was abandoned when it became clear
that attempting
expansion.

to achieve

it would have risked ending

the current

However, the second target, which ignored the rapid money

growth in the first half and widened the permissible ranges, was not
achieved either; money growth remained strong throughout the entire year.
Why did money grow so much faster than the Fed's targets?

Primarily

because of the unusual and unexpected behavior of velocity.
monetary

targets

were

chosen

under

the

assumption

that

The Fed's
growth

in

velocity—the ratio of spending to Ml—would be positive during 1985.
Instead, velocity plummeted.

In the first half of 1985, velocity fell by

more than 5 percent; in the second half, it declined by about 5.5 percent.
Naturally, uncertainty over velocity movements raises two very different
problems for predicting the economy in 1986.

If money growth is slowed

precipitously and velocity growth remains negative, there is considerable
risk of a sluggish economy by the second half of this year.

In this

case, economic growth over the year would end up below what we expect.




- 4 -

On the other hand, if money growth remains fast and velocity growth
increases, real output growth could well be stronger and unemployment
even lower than I indicated.

The basic problem is that there is con-

siderable uncertainty over what velocity will do this year.

Of course,

two years of very fast money growth present other problems—primarily
those related to price changes.
Inflation

Which brings us to inflation. Again, there are a variety

of factors that will influence prices during this year.

First, there is

the build-up in the underlying monetary pressure on prices.

For nearly

forty years, the key indicator of inflationary pressure was the long-run
or trend growth in the narrow money stock, Ml.

Over the past three

years, however, this relationship has broken down; while the trend growth
(or three-year average growth) in Ml has risen to about 9.5 percent,
inflation has remained flat at about 3.5 percent.

If the historical

relationship between trend money growth and inflation should begin to
come back on line, even partially, higher inflation will again become a
problem.
The falling value of the dollar in foreign exchange markets will,
of course, compound any inflationary pressures.

The lower-valued dollar

not only makes imported goods more expensive, it also enables domestic
producers to increase their prices as well.

After all, they won't lose

customers now that their foreign competitors' prices are also rising.

So

far, the value of the dollar has fallen 25 percent from its peak last
February; continuing

declines may

add

additional

upward

pressure

on

prices.
The only bright spot on the price horizon is the continuing decline
in oil prices.

However, even this bright spot is somewhat tarnished.

Other commodity prices, which fell throughout most of last year, seem to



- 5 -

have turned around and have been rising fairly steadily since September.
To what extent these

increases in commodity

prices will offset the

influence of falling energy prices remains unclear.
What are the other major uncertainties in the inflation picture?
The primary uncertainty is whether the money growth-inflation link will
be re-established.

Quite frankly, we don't know why this previously

reliable link has broken down for the past three years.

Consequently, we

don't know if the breakdown is permanent or merely temporary.

If the

money-price link does not reappear in 1986, then inflation is likely to
rise only slightly above what it was last year; the upward pull on prices
generally exerted by the falling value of the dollar will be offset
somewhat by declining energy prices.

However, if trend money growth,

once again, starts influencing prices, then the inflation rate could rise
one to two percentage points above last year's rate by the end of 1986.
Interest Rates

Turning to interest rates, I should note that I

used to make my living at Morgan Stanley, in part, by capitalizing on
interest rate movements.

But, as a government trading manager, I never

found it productive to make rate predictions. We were just as interested
in making money on "aberrant" rate movements as we were on "real" or
predicted ones.

In any event, it is pretty well known that interest

rates, over time, move closely with the expected rate of inflation.

The

problem lies, as I noted earlier, in predicting what the rate of inflation
will do during 1986.
likely

to

remain

If it rises only slightly, then interest rates are

unchanged

from

their

current

levels; however, if

inflation begins to accelerate, interest rates, especially longer-term
ones, will follow.




- 6 -

Of

course,

other

factors

also

affect

interest

rates

beside

inflation; however, there is little that can be said currently, at least
accurately, about what is likely to happen either to real interest rates
or risk factors in 1986.
regarding

the

legislation.

impacts

In part, these are related to our uncertainties
of

possible

tax

reform

and

the

Gramm-Rudman

While these factors are not likely to influence short-term

rates much during 1986, they could play a major role in long-term interest
rate movements.
Now, having warned you about the uncertainties inherent in predicting real output, inflation, and interest rates, there is one final warning
I want to leave you with.

This is a warning about what to consider when

assessing various predictions made by other economic sooth-sayers.

To

paraphrase Will Rogers' well-known admonition, it isn't what we know that
hurts, nor even what we don't know, it's what we know that ain't so
that's the problem.
All predictions are based, presumably, on what we know, tempered,
of course, by honestly acknowledging that there are some things that we
don't know.

However, many of the predictions that I have seen or heard

recently appear to be based on premises that just "ain't so."
Let me give you just a few examples.
comments

recently

that

the

reductions

in

There have been numerous
deficits

associated

with

Gramm-Rudman will decrease the fiscal stimulus and thus reduce economic
growth in 1986 and thereafter.
If deficits, by

Now, we know that this is not the case.

themselves, produced

fiscal

stimuli, where was the

phenomenal growth in real output since 1981 during which time deficits
ballooned to record levels?




Since 1981, real GNP growth has been about

- 7 -

3 percent per year, roughly what it has been, on average, for the past 90
years.

In fact, the $11 billion reduction in the deficit projected for

1986 is going to have no impact on real growth or employment.

This same

reasoning also denies that the reduction in deficits under Gramm-Rudman
will require increased monetary stimulus to maintain real growth in the
economy. Again, this just "ain't so."
Another example is the claim that the reductions in the deficit are
likely to reduce interest rates, and, consequently, interest rates will
decline due to the passage of Gramm-Rudman.

This just "ain't so."

The

truth is that economists have been unable to find any substantive effects
of deficits on interest rates at all.

One could argue that Gramm-Rudman

may have impacted inflationary expectations, and thus interest rates, by
apparently
deficits.

reducing

the

risk

of

future

monetization

of

government

But, on the other hand, we must ask, with inflation presently

at 4 to 4.5 percent, how much further could long-term rates fall regardless of this reduced future risk?
Finally, those who argue that our current account deficit has
caused lower growth in output and higher unemployment forget that, in a
flexible exchange rate regime, every dollar of that deficit must be
invested in U.S. securities or equities; sellers of these securities
spend the proceeds mostly on U.S. goods and services.
these

dollars

remain

in the

activity is not reduced.

U.S. income

stream

and

Consequently,
total economic

Of course, there are some industries—export

and import-competing—that will shrink, but other industries will take up
the slack.

Consequently, a fall in the value of the dollar and a

reduction in the current account deficit cannot be viewed as stimulative.




- 8 -

On the other hand, expectations of a precipitous fall in the value
of the dollar would dry up the foreign capital inflow, reduce the amount
of credit supplied to U.S. markets, and cause upward pressure on U.S.
interest

rates.

Therefore, if anything, international

considerations

would dictate a steady monetary policy rather than the alleged need to
"ease"

to

produce

further

depreciation

of

the

dollar

and

alleged

stimulative effects on the economy.
The main point I would like to leave with you concerning economic
predictions is simply this:

they are a lot like New Year's resolutions.

Some are based on good intentions, some are based on nothing substantive
at all.

They are announced loudly at the start of each year and quietly

abandoned sometime thereafter.

We all hope that no one remembers them

clearly enough to remind us of our follies at the end of the year.

So I

promise not to remember your resolutions if you promise not to remember
my predictions.