View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

"MONETARY POLICY - A REVIEW OF THE OPTIONS

Address by
Theodore H. Roberts
President
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Before the
20th Annual Economic Outlook Conference
of the
Chicago Chapter of the American Statistical Association
and the
Chicago Association of Commerce and Industry
Palmer House
Chicago, Illinois
June 8, 1983

Today I would like to discuss some fundamental issues
in monetary policy—issues that are not new but are as relevant
today as they have been for decades past.

I think it is no

longer debatable that an economic recovery is under way and the
three-year span of economic stagnation and recession has come
to an end.
Yet, public perceptions about the economic order are
not sanguine:
projections of an awesome federal deficit
overhang financial markets,
the recovery is viewed as fragile with
unemployment still much too high,
some perceive real interest rates to be
exceptionally high,
and the persistent strong exchange value of
the dollar and problems with loans to lesser
developed countries threaten international
markets.
A great many people are calling upon policymakers—in
particular, monetary policymakers—to alleviate these
problems. At the same time, people are puzzled because they
find it difficult to determine precisely what monetary policy
is doing or what it is capable of doing.
I would like to talk to you about the options facing
monetary policymakers and their potential for reducing the
economic risks facing this Nation. As you know, I am a novice
at central banking.

I realize that you may wonder how much

insight into policymaking I may have gleaned in only four




-2-

months as the President of the Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis. Let me reassure you that in my prior incarnation as
a commercial banker for nearly 30 years I learned (sometimes in
financially excruciating detail) just how much influence
monetary policy decisions have on financial markets; in today's
world, professional bankers must be reasonably good amateur
macroeconomists to survive.
Also, being a newcomer to monetary policy has its
advantages.

In particular, I can avoid the natural reluctance

of policymakers to criticize their own past actions. Since I
have no vested interest in past policy alternatives, I hope
that I can view them objectively.

Finally, from your

perspective, there is an additional benefit from listening to a
newcomer to monetary policymaking.

Someone once noted that the

art of central banking consisted, in part, of taking something
perfectly understandable and making it hopelessly confusing. I
really don't feel that I have acquired that skill in only four
months; thus, I hope that what is understandable to me will
also be understandable to you.
In order to assess the likely success of the policy
options potentially open to the Federal Reserve, we must first
clearly understand just what it is that the Federal Reserve can
do.

Regardless of what policies it may pursue and irrespective

of what goals it may wish to attain, the Fed can immediately
and directly do just three things.
reserve requirements.




First, it can change

Second, it can change the discount

-3-

rate.

Finally, the Fed can buy and sell securities and foreign

currency, thus increasing or decreasing the amount of reserves
in the financial system and affecting the supply of money and
credit.
It is also important to remember what the Fed cannot
do—at least directly or immediately.

The Federal Reserve

cannot directly control the total supply of credit.

There are

a host of actual and potential suppliers of credit in financial
markets who make decisions independent of Federal Reserve
actions.

Further, despite common folklore and financial market

mythology to the contrary, the Federal Reserve cannot
arbitrarily and unilaterally control interest rates. To be
sure, its reserve supplying actions influence interest rates
via their impact on financial institutions.

However, the Fed's

direct effect is small and temporary.
Most of the current debate on Federal Reserve policy
is not concerned with what the ultimate goals of monetary
policy should be.

In my opinion, we all agree that policy

should seek to achieve sustainable economic expansion and
relatively stable prices. The only real question is how to do
this.

Or, rather, what targets of monetary policy will best

indicate the actions necessary to achieve these goals?
The candidates most often mentioned as potential
targets for monetary policy are interest rates, commodity
prices (usually the price of gold is stressed), foreign
exchange rates, credit growth, and the growth of certain




-4-

monetary aggregates, notably Ml and M2. These are the
potential options available for guiding monetary policy to
achieve the desired goals.
I shall discuss each of these in turn, but for the
sake of brevity let me dispense quickly with the three that are
least attainable:

control of commodity prices, control of

foreign exchange rates, and control of credit growth.

I will

then concentrate on interest rates and the monetary aggregates.
What about proposals to target on and stabilize some
measure of commodity prices?

Why not return, in effect, to the

"good old days" of the gold standard?

The argument in favor of

stabilizing the price of gold is well known.

The price of gold

is presumably quite sensitive to any excess supply or demand
for money.

The stabilization of the price of gold, it is said,

would lead to the "proper" money growth; the money stock would
always equal precisely what the public wished to hold and would
not induce fluctuations in output or the rate of inflation.
Unfortunately, there are innumerable events that could
raise the world price of gold: political crises overseas,
industrial innovations, and changes in inflationary
expectations anywhere in the world.

The Fed's response under

gold price targeting would be to contract the money stock; the
result would be a decline in economic activity, even though
there would have been no inflationary pressures in the U.S. Of
course, over the very long term, we might find that prices
would be stable.




But I doubt that we, or any other country,

-5-

would subject our economies to systematic and frequent
fluctuations in output, employment and prices in the shorter
run to achieve price stability over a century.
A similar option is to stabilize exchange rates.

If

such stabilization implies that all countries will permanently
fix their rates of inflation at some pre-agreed level, it could
work.

But I doubt that such an agreement is politically

enforceable.

If, on the other hand, stabilization of exchange

rates means that the U.S. will conduct its monetary policy in a
manner which will simply keep the value of the dollar constant
against other currencies, then we are, once again, subjecting
our economy to every economic policy decision abroad.

I doubt,

again, that such policy would be palatable to our society.
The third potential option for monetary policy
targeting is some measure of total credit.

Those who advocate

focusing monetary policy actions on the basis of credit growth
targets do so primarily because there is a fairly close
relationship between the growth of credit and the growth of
GNP.

Perhaps the biggest problem with using credit growth

targets for monetary policy is that the Federal Reserve, in the
absence of statutory credit controls, cannot exert close
control over total credit growth.

As a result, attempting to

determine the proper policy response to differences between
credit growth and some established target is subject to
considerable error.

Targets that can not be controlled closely

are simply not useful for policy purposes.




-6-

The fourth option is interest rate targeting.
Intuitively, interest rate targeting and interest rate
stabilization appear both reasonable and achievable actions for
the Federal Reserve to pursue.

If interest rates were solely

determined by the interaction of the supply and demand for
money, interest rate stabilization would be the perfect target
for monetary actions. Any increase in the demand for money
would be immediately manifested as an increase in interest
rates.

The Fed would prevent interest rates from rising by

supplying the additional money that the public desires, thus
avoiding an economic contraction.

Conversely, should a

decrease in demand for money cause interest rates to fall, the
Fed would simply contract the money stock and prevent an
increase in the price level.
Unfortunately, there are three strikes against
interest rate stabilization:

a theoretical one, an empirical

one, and a political one. First, interest rates are not
determined by the supply and demand for money alone; they are
primarily determined by the supply and demand for credit.
Thus, when credit demands increase, interest rate stabilization
leads to monetary actions that increase both credit and money
even though the demand for money is unchanged.

The net result

is that changes in credit demands will produce procyclical
movements in money growth, exacerbating the swings in output,
prices and interest rates. That is strike one.




Empirically, we have tried interest rate

-7-

stabilization, in one form or another, from the late 1960s to
the end of the 1970s; its legacy was accelerating inflation.
Within these 15 years, inflation rose from near zero to double
digits.

That's strike two.
Finally, there are the political ramifications of

interest rate targeting.

If the monetary authority is

explicitly targeting on interest rates, political pressures
will invariably arise to pressure the monetary authority to
reduce rates, regardless of the longer-run consequences of such
actions. Recent Congressional bills that seek to add interest
rate targets to monetary deliberations are a good example of
this kind of pressure.

Interest rate targets inevitably invite

increased political interference and preoccupation with
short-run considerations at the expense of long-run goals. And
that, in my opinion, is the third strike against interest rate
targeting.
The fifth option is targeting on money growth.

This

procedure presumes that the demand for money is relatively
stable; not in the sense of being unchanged, but in the sense
that it is predictable.

If this were not the case, then

significant and unexpected increases in the desire to hold
larger money balances would result in recessions, and
unforseeable decreases in money demand would produce inflation.
Those who advocate monetary growth targeting assert
that money demand j[s relatively stable because of two pieces of
evidence.




First, over extended time periods, there is a close

-8-

relationship between money growth and inflation.

To cite just

one example of the long-run similarities: from 1954 to 1966,
the average annual rate of growth in Ml, the narrow money
stock, was 2.5 percent and the average annual inflation rate
was 2.2 percent.

Since 1966, money growth has averaged 6.4

percent per year and inflation has averaged 6.5 percent per
year.

Current studies support the assertion that sustained

changes in money growth will produce similar changes in prices
after a lag of about three years or so. This evidence suggests
that current monetary growth targets are not particularly
helpful for influencing current prices; they do, however, give
you a good idea of the direction and magnitude of price
movements some time into the future—provided that actual money
growth is in line with the targets.
The second piece of evidence that is frequently cited
is that in the shorter span of time, such as two quarters,
substantial contractions and expansions of money growth produce
changes in output in the same direction.

Thus, whether we are

concerned with the long-run impact on the rate of inflation, or
the short-run impact on economic activity, monetary growth has
been a historically good predictor of GNP growth.

This

supports the contention that the demand for money is relatively
stable.
Another piece of evidence supporting monetary
aggregate targeting is that there is a fairly close
relationship, over periods of six months or longer, between




-9-

changes in reserves or the monetary base and changes in Ml.
Thus, as opposed to what we observe with respect to credit
growth, Ml growth car^ be controlled by the Federal Reserve.
This option, however, has developed a rather bad
reputation over the past several years.

It is asserted, argued

and advertised that from October 1979 until approximately July
1982, it was precisely this option that was implemented by the
Federal Reserve System.

The results were abominable: we have

had two recessions in three years, interest rates skyrocketed
in 1980 and 1981, before declining in 1982, high inflation
persisted through 1981 before plunging in 1982, and total
output of goods and services for this whole period did not grow
at all. Hardly a picture of stability or economic growth.
Ironically, upon closer examination, this period
provides additional support for monetary aggregate targeting.
During this period, money growth was neither stable nor
generally within its target ranges.

Consider the actual

pattern of monetary growth from the fourth quarter of 1979 to
the present: 1.5 percent for the first two quarters, 13.3
percent for the next, 7.1 percent during the next, 3.2 percent
in the second half of 1981, 11 percent in the first quarter of
1982 and 4.7 percent in the subsequent two quarters.

In line

with the evidence that I have cited earlier, given these
fluctuations in money growth, I would have expected the
instability that has occurred.




What conclusion can be drawn from the five principal

-10-

alternatives currently being suggested for monetary policy
deliberations?
world.

First, none of them will produce a perfect

Regardless of which is chosen, we will still incur

short-run fluctuations in output, employment, prices, and
interest rates—and certainly some of these fluctuations, like
those associated with the 1973 and 1979 OPEC oil shocks, will
be unpleasant.

No monetary policy and no unique system of

targeting can eliminate all shocks to the economy.
But it seems to me that the choice of an option must
be made on the basis of which one minimizes the systematic
shocks to the economy.

Control of some commodity price or

exchange rate will necessarily produce short-run fluctuations
in output and price level. Targeting on a credit aggregate, to
the best of our knowledge, is an almost impossible task:

we

have no reasonable levers to pull. Stabilization of interest
rates, given growing credit demands and political proclivity
for always lower interest rates, will be procyclical and will
systematically raise the rate of inflation.

I must, therefore,

choose monetary aggregate targeting as the best of available
choices.

It has no attributes of systematic fluctuation, it is

controllable with reasonable accuracy, and it seems to be well
related to our goal—stable growth of 6NP.
In case you may think that this discussion is some
theoretical or dogmatic exercise, let me assure you that this
choice of targeting options is real and current.

At this time

there are several proposals in Congress, and I am certain that




-11-

many others will crop up again and again, which specify targets
to be used in monetary policy. While I do not believe that
legislated targets are at all desirable, a wrong prescription
can subject all of us to an economic future that may not be
acceptable to any of us.
We are now certain that a recovery is underway.
has been a decline in the rate of inflation.

There

There has been a

substantial decline in interest rates, and unemployment is
beginning to edge down.

But what we do now will determine

whether these gains can be sustained or whether we will embark
on the same roller coaster that has characterized our economic
performance of the past 20 years.

I am not naive enough to

believe that choosing a monetary aggregate target will solve
all our ills. But if one looks at history, if one looks at
empirical evidence, all other alternatives have failed.

Given

persistent and growing political pressure to satisfy various
sectors of our economy, given the uncertainties that these
pressures produce, we must have some rules that govern our
economic policies.
We cannot rely anymore on "playing it by ear"--there
are too many players that call the tune.

And if there is one

rule that I would like to see tried, it is the rule that allows
for a stable growth of our nation's money stock—a rule that in
my opinion has not been tried and, despite opinions to the
contrary, a rule whose time has come.