View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

HOUSING AT THE CROSSROADS"

Address by
Theodore H. Roberts
President
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Before the
Home Builders Association
St. Louis, Missouri
April 17, 1984

THE
FEDERAL
RESERVE
RANK of
ST. LOUIS

I am very pleased to have this opportunity to share my views on
housing and monetary policy with members of the St. Louis Home Builders
Association.
With the recent substantial rise in interest rates and this
morning's report of a 27 percent decrease in housing starts last month,
some of you hardy survivors must be wondering if we are about to replay
the homebuilding devastation of 1981-82. I was in the banking business
at that time and also a director of a Real Estate Investment Trust, and
I saw what happened to even the best homebuilders.

The sharp rise in

inflation preceding that period encouraged speculation both in land
acquisition and building.

The mood of the times was "buy it or build it

before the price goes up again." No one anticipated the level of interest
rates which it eventually would take to control rapidly increasing prices
throughout the economy.

Builders found that interest reserves on

development projects were grossly deficient as short-term interest rate
levels soared, increasing the costs of their floating rate construction
loans. Meanwhile substantially higher long-term interest rates priced
buyers out of the market, lengthening the time required to dispose of
completed properties, even at distressed prices.
None of us wants to experience such difficulties again. The
question is how to avoid them.

Sometimes in searching for a solution, it

is useful to stand back and look at a problem in historical perspective.
That seems particularly appropriate when you realize that the St. Louis
Home Builders Association is celebrating its 50th anniversary this year,
and the Fed has been around some 70 years. Both of us must have been
doing something right just to have survived through all the tumultuous
events of these years.




- 2 -

Let's first take a quick look at what has been happening to housing
and its financing since 1934, the year your association started. Home
ownership in this country has risen from less than one-half of households
to almost twcr-thirds. By comparison, only half of British, French, and
Italian, and just one-third of German families now own their own homes.
Clearly, the homebuilders of America deserve great credit for producing
affordable, quality residences for a broad segment of the population.
Of course, you have had a little help along the way. The universal
dream of homeownership has fostered political pressures which have
produced public policies designed to increase the allocation of resources
to housing through massive direct and indirect subsidies. These include
federally chartered and insured mutual savings and loan associations with
special tax advantages, and access to the money and capital markets via
credit from federally sponsored agencies. These institutions were
literally designed to make low-rate, long-term, amortizing mortgages.
One also thinks of federally insured and guaranteed mortgage loans, and
tax free bond issues of states and cities to raise funds for relending in
low rate mortgages. Beyond all those, we have the income tax
deductibility of mortgage interest and property taxes with an estimated
annual value to homeowners of some $37 billion.
Meanwhile, thrift institutions were not immune to the problems of
inflation and tight money. Without substantial government assistance and
considerable "creative accounting," most thrift institutions would not
have survived until rates declined in 1982. Their problems were
aggravated by deregulation of deposit interest rates which raised funding
costs and reduced operating margins to negligible proportions. Determined




- 3 -

not to get caught in the same interest rate squeeze again, thrift
institutions have begun to emphasize variable rate lending and are
selling off fixed rate loans.
The past few years have produced more innovations in mortgage
finance than we have seen since the early thirties. You recall the
"creative financing" used by sellers of homes during the period of
highest interest rates.

These short-term, balloon loans, usually at

below market interest rates kept properties moving and concealed a
decline of about 10 percent in real market prices after 1979. More
recently, builder "buy-downs," and graduated payment mortgages have
joined the options available to home buyers. A common denominator of all
these new mortgage forms is a shift of interest rate or payment risk to
the borrower, certainly a matter of some concern since a rash of defaults
and forced sales is not likely to be constructive for new homebuilding.
A more fundamental development in housing finance has been the
pooling of mortgages into securities for sale either to institutions or
individuals.

Initially, these mortgage-backed participation certificates

were guaranteed by Ginnie Mae, Fannie Mae, or Freddie Mac. Now, we are
seeing some being sold with only conventional mortgage backing and
carrying no government agency guarantee. Recently, such securities have
converted underlying mortgage amortization payments into bond-like
semi-annual payments of various short, medium, or long-term maturities,
thereby substantially broadening the market.

These mortgage backed

securities now supply over half the funds for new mortgages. By removing
much of the regional interest rate differential, they have helped create
a truly national market for mortgages.

In a way, we have gone full

circle in mortgage finance and are now back to the practices of the




- 4 -

twenties except for retaining the pattern of long-term mortgage
amortization.

Once again, individuals are a major factor in the supply

of mortgage credit either directly or through pension funds. Combine
this development with modern computer technology and you have the
possibility of instant credit approval and sale of mortgages via computer
terminals to mortgage bankers, investment bankers, or brokers who package
them into securities form and resell them.

This is actually taking place

today.
What brought about this virtual revolution in home financing?
are the likely longer-run consequences for the housing industry?

What

The

shock that initiated this scramble for different techniques to finance
housing was the accelerating inflation that began in the 1960s. Along
with greater inflation came a phenomenon of more variable inflation as
well.

Now, a more variable rate of inflation produces not only a varying

price level but also sizable and unexpected changes in relative prices.
As relative prices change, some activities will become relatively more
profitable and other less so. Consequently, people's spending and
investing patterns shift back and forth solely because of the
inflationary impact. The mix of economic activities shifts back and
forth in response to these spending patterns.
In the case of housing during the late 1960s and 1970s, the impact
of higher and more variable inflation was amplified by the deposit
interest rate ceilings; the end result was alternating booms and busts
for home builders. Since 196 0, the annual growth in output of all goods
and services varied between minus 2 percent to plus 6 percent. Housing
starts varied between minus 34 percent to plus 60 percent by the same
measure.




Housing construction experienced booms in 1968, 1972-73, and

- 5 -

1977-78; at the outset of each of these booms, the rate of inflation
jumped by 3 or more percent relative to its average over the preceding
two years. When this rapid runup in inflation combined with interest
rate ceilings, housing production was recurrently pushed to unusual and
unsustainable bursts of activity.

This movement was fueled by the

public's perception of negative real interest rates on mortgages. That
is, the interest rates charged to borrowers turned out (after the fact)
to be lower than the inflation rate. Lenders, it turned out, were giving
away wealth to borrowers.

Indeed, these three housing booms roughly

coincided with the largest negative real interest rates during the past
fifteen years.
If this were the full story of inflation's impact on housing, home
builders might well ask "What's wrong with housing booms?"

The problem

was, however, that each boom was followed by a bust which required
layoffs, costly inventory reductions, and high failure rates among
construction firms. Following the 1972-73 boom, housing starts fell to
less than half their 1972 peak; from the 1977-78 boom, they fell by about
50 percent over the next 4 years. In particular, as all of you know
well, 1979-82 was an especially traumatic and protracted period of
falling housing starts and failing home builders.
One result of recent financial innovations is that, ultimately, the
housing industry will not be subjected to the sharply magnified impact of
business cycles that affected it in the past.

In particular, it will not

be boosted by negative real interest rates, and it will not be depressed
when those rates become sharply positive.

The variable rate mortgage

will insure that the flow of savings to the housing market does not
disappear.




The much broader base of savers provided by mortgage pool

- 6 -

instruments will assure that mortgage interest rates do not fluctuate
more sharply than other long-term interest rates.
While these financial innovations will protect the housing industry
from magnified fluctuations relative to the rest of the economy, they
will clearly do nothing to minimize business cycles and interest rate
fluctuations in general. To a large extent this is the province of
monetary authorities and the policies that they pursue. Clearly,
monetary policy is not a panacea to all economic ills:

excessive

government borrowing and spending will not necessarily disappear, Middle
East crises will still cause energy prices to fluctuate, the vagaries of
weather will cause the prices of food to change, and people's decisions
whether to save more or to borrow will change interest rates. But, if
monetary authorities provided stable and moderate monetary growth, this
would go a long way towards reducing or minimizing the fluctuations that
we have experienced in the past.
If we want to eliminate inflation, we must reduce monetary growth
to reasonable levels which are compatible with output growth. But
research also indicates that abrupt and large reductions in money growth
cause sharp and costly economic contractions.

Thus, the long-term

solution must be a gradual and steady reduction in monetary expansion.
If this is to be achieved, however, we must condone market-induced
fluctuations in interest rates and in all other relative prices.
Attempts to manipulate interest rates produced the chronic inflation and
economic fluctuations of the seventies and early eighties. By focusing
on interest rates instead of money growth, we managed to win some
battles, but lose the war.




- 7 -

In the more immediate future, I can see the potential for the
adoption of a desirable monetary policy. There is no doubt that the
economy cannot continue to expand at 6 to 7 percent per year; real growth
of this magnitude is not sustainable. Nor, unfortunately for you, are
housing starts at an annual 2.2 million rate sustainable for any
considerable length of time. A slowdown is inevitable. Moreover,
monetary growth in the recent past indicates that inflation will
accelerate for a time, and short-term interest rates will rise. But if
monetary growth can be maintained at the middle of the current Federal
Reserve range, at about 6 percent, and then slowly reduced over the years
ahead, we could reduce inflation, we would see lower interest rates, and
we would see a much more stable economy.
I think you would agree that such an environment would facilitate
your planning, enhance your productivity, reduce your risks, and
generally make your prospects for survival more favorable.