View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

"HOW HIGH IS UP?

Address by
Theodore H. Roberts
President
Federal Reserve Bank of S t . Louis

Before the
St. Louis Chapter
of the
Financial Analysts Society
Missouri Athletic Club
October 20, 1983

I am especially pleased to have this opportunity to speak to the
St. Louis Chapter of the Financial Analysts Society.

One of my earliest

business assignments was serving Harris Bank as a financial analyst.

During

that period I was a card carrying member of the Investment Analysts Society
of Chicago.

I followed bank and insurance stocks, primarily, but I also

kept an eye on finance companies, savings and loans, and mutual fund management companies.

During that time I was a member of the Subcommittee on Bank

Reporting of the Corporate Information Committee of the Financial Analysts
Federation and was involved in the recommendations for improving bank earnings statements.

Later as chief financial officer, I marveled at the wealth

of information which we routinely made available to bank stock analysts.
While my principal problem as a bank stock analyst was obtaining adequate
information, it seems to me that today the biggest problem for an analyst is
determining what part of the wealth of information is important.

I also had

the duty of managing investor relations and some of you called on me to
discuss your holdings.

In view of the recent Canadian interest in Harris, I

hope you held on to your stockl
October, Mark Twain once wrote, is one of the most dangerous months in
which to speculate 2jn_ stocks.

He noted that the other especially dangerous

ones were July, January, September, April, and all the other months. Having
been so warned, I am not here today to speculate in stocks.

Instead, I

would like to speculate about stocks. That is, I would like to speculate
about the factors that have influenced the behavior of equity values over
the past several years and that are likely to continue to do so into the
future as wel 1.
At the present time, the economy is robust, unemployment is declining
and inflation is remarkably low.




During the past year, virtually across the

- 2 -

board, stock market i n d i c a t o r s were pushing up i n t o previously unexplored
territory.

"Record highs" were reported so f r e q u e n t l y t h a t such announce-

ments were almost commonplace.

Of course, t h i s was before the computer

companies s t a r t i n g s u r p r i s i n g us.
Unfortunately, i n my o p i n i o n , the euphoria associated with recent
share p r i c e r i s e s has served t o m i s d i r e c t public a t t e n t i o n from c e r t a i n
fundamental questions about stock market behavior--both past and f u t u r e .
When I read t h a t the stock market values are "up" t o record highs, I am
reminded o f the childhood conundrum: "How high i s up?"

In r e a l terms, a f t e r

adjustment f o r i n f l a t i o n , stock prices are nowhere near record l e v e l s - - i n
f a c t , they are now about where they were 30 years ago.

In r e a l terms, stock

prices peaked i n the l a t e 1960s and declined s t e a d i l y t h e r e a f t e r .

While the

stock market indices have been generally r i s i n g t o nominal record highs
since the l a t e 1960s, i n r e a l terms, shareholders, t o quote Twain again,
"have been f a s t r i s i n g from affluence t o p o v e r t y . "
The fundamental question t h a t must be answered, i f we want t o understand both the past h i s t o r y and f u t u r e prospects f o r e q u i t y values, i s n o t ,
"Why are stocks doing so well now?"

The important question i s "Why have

stocks done so badly over the past f i f t e e n years?"

From 1950 t o the l a t e

1960s, r e a l share prices were generally r i s i n g ; over the past f i f t e e n years,
they were generally f a l l i n g .

The c h i e f d i f f e r e n c e between these two periods

i s t h a t there was l i t t l e or no i n f l a t i o n i n the e a r l i e r p e r i o d , but generally
r i s i n g and e r r a t i c i n f l a t i o n i n the l a t t e r p e r i o d .

The o l d adage t h a t stocks

were a good hedge against i n f l a t i o n turned out t o be dead wrong.
And t h e r e i n l i e s the puzzle.

We a l l know, or at l e a s t t h i n k we know,

why higher and more uncertain i n f l a t i o n has adverse e f f e c t s on the bond
markets.




But why a r e n ' t stocks, which presumably represent some underlying

- 3 -

" r e a l v a l u e s " , immune from the impact of i n f l a t i o n ?

With the 20-20 v i s i o n

t h a t always comes w i t h h i n d s i g h t , we can see c l e a r l y t h a t i n f l a t i o n adversely
impacts on share prices f o r several reasons.
F i r s t , because depreciation charges are based on h i s t o r i c costs rather
than on c u r r e n t replacement c o s t s , p r o f i t s are overstated and the f i r m ' s
r e a l taxes r i s e .

I n f l a t i o n i s , a f t e r a l l , a t a x ; one t h a t f i r m s are u n l i k e l y

t o t o t a l l y avoid paying.
Second, higher and more v a r i a b l e i n f l a t i o n produces greater u n c e r t a i n t y
about the f u t u r e purchasing power of money and the value of bonds and stocks.
This increased u n c e r t a i n t y pushes up the r e a l r a t e of i n t e r e s t t h a t must be
o f f e r e d t o p o t e n t i a l and e x i s t i n g shareholders.

T h i r d , the greater uncer-

t a i n t y about f u t u r e values shows up also as a movement up the q u a l i t y scale
and down the m a t u r i t y spectrum i n terms o f asset h o l d i n g s .

This attempt t o

increase the l i q u i d i t y o f investments produces f u r t h e r downward pressure on
stock p r i c e s .
F i n a l l y , there i s some evidence t h a t firms have attempted t o maintain
the r e a l value of t h e i r dividends i n the face of r i s i n g i n f l a t i o n , even
though t h e i r r e a l a f t e r - t a x earnings were d e c l i n i n g .

In so d o i n g , they were

simply paying out c a p i t a l - - i n other words, p a r t i a l l y l i q u i d a t i n g the f i r m s
over t i m e .

This being the case, i t should surprise no one t h a t stock prices

f e l l i n r e a l terms over t h i s period..
Thus, despite widespread notions t o the c o n t r a r y , i n f l a t i o n i s neither
good f o r the stock market nor i s i t s impact neutral on share values.
I n f l a t i o n has a well-documented pernicious e f f e c t on business f i r m s and
t h e i r shareholders.
Now i t i s tempting as we view the present s i t u a t i o n , t o hope t h a t we
are over the i n f l a t i o n "hump."




We have gone from the d o u b l e - d i g i t

inflation

- 4 -

of a few years ago t o r a t e s t h a t c u r r e n t l y r i v a l those of the 1950s and
e a r l y 1960s.

However, i n my o p i n i o n , i t i s premature t o conclude t h a t

prospects f o r increased i n f l a t i o n are nonexistent.

In several key respects,

the current s i t u a t i o n c l o s e l y resembles t h a t which e x i s t e d i n the l a t e 1960s
and which p r e c i p i t a t e d f i f t e e n years of accelerated i n f l a t i o n and d e c l i n i n g
stock values.
There are two things t h a t we know about i n f l a t i o n .
i s p r i m a r i l y a monetary phenomenon.

First,

inflation

While there are a wide v a r i e t y of non-

monetary f a c t o r s t h a t influence p r i c e behavior from y e a r - t o - y e a r , these
influences e s s e n t i a l l y net out over longer time periods.
f o r c e behind i n f l a t i o n i s excessive money growth.

The c h i e f d r i v i n g

For example, from 1954 t o

1966, money growth was 2.5 percent per year and i n f l a t i o n averaged 2.2
percent per year.

From 1967 t o 1982, the money stock grew about 6.4 percent

per year and prices rose about 6.5 percent per year.

Thus, i f we want t o

determine what causes p e r s i s t e n t i n f l a t i o n , we must f i n d out what causes
p e r s i s t e n t high growth rates i n money.
Second, we know t h a t changes i n money growth have l i t t l e or no
immediate a f f e c t on i n f l a t i o n - - m o n e y a f f e c t s i n f l a t i o n w i t h a f a i r l y long
lag.

Our research a t the Federal Reserve Bank of S t . Louis shows t h a t

p e r s i s t e n t changes i n the money stock are followed i n i t i a l l y by changes i n
real output.

I t takes roughly three years before the f u l l impact of changes

i n the money stock show up i n p r i c e s .

Thus, while the long-run l i n k between

i n f l a t i o n and money growth i s c l o s e , the s h o r t - r u n r e l a t i o n s h i p i s f a i r l y
loose and, at t i m e s , tenuous.

Accordingly, one should not view the combina-

t i o n o f current low rates o f i n f l a t i o n and the 11 percent money growth over
the past year as an anomaly.

The f u l l impact of t h a t money growth should

show up i n 1984 and 1985 p r i c e l e v e l s , not i n the present ones.




- 5 -

The natural question to ask at this point is what precipitated the
acceleration in money growth starting in the late 1960s?

Those of us with

long memories will recall that, around the middle 1960s, fiscal policy
decisions were made which entailed greater expenditure for both domestic and
international programs.

The rise in expenditures, unaccompanied by higher

taxes, produced greater deficits and upward pressure on interest rates.
From that time, until late 1979, the Federal Reserve attempted-to "lean
against" these interest rate movements.

In retrospect, it was more like

spitting in the wind.
In general, monetary policy is implemented mainly through supplying
and withdrawing reserves of depository institutions through open market
operations.

The changes in reserves produce an expansion or contraction of

credit by these institutions.
Since interest rates are the price of credit, the net injection of
reserves and subsequent increase in the supply of credit, everything else
remaining constant, should cause a decline in interest rates. A net withdrawal of reserves, during periods of downward pressure on rates, holding
everything else constant, should produce the opposite results.

If this line

of reasoning is pursued to its logical conclusion, then it appears that the
Fed could set some interest rate and hold it there forever by simply
supplying or withdrawing reserves in- appropriate amounts.
Unfortunately, as our experience since 1965 has shown, there is a
fatal flaw in this analysis.
remain constant.

The flaw is that everything else does not

In particular, supplying or withdrawing reserves has

predictable effects that produce significant changes in the economy and, not
surprisingly, in financial markets as well.

When reserves of depository

institutions rise, these institutions actively expand their loans and




- 6 -

investments.

In so doing, they also create a d d i t i o n a l checkable d e p o s i t s - -

t h a t i s , they create a d d i t i o n a l money.

And an increase i n the money supply

impacts the economy i n p r e c i s e l y those p r e d i c t a b l e ways t h a t I j u s t
detailed.

I n i t i a l l y , i t induces an increase i n r e a l economic a c t i v i t y — i n

output and employment; u l t i m a t e l y i t produces an increase i n i n f l a t i o n .

A

decrease i n reserves, o f course, produces opposite and symmetrical changes.
These p r e d i c t a b l e r e s u l t s are not missed by bond and stock market
participants.

I f lenders expect i n f l a t i o n t o a c c e l e r a t e , they w i l l t r y t o

p r o t e c t t h e i r purchasing power by demanding higher nominal i n t e r e s t r a t e s .
And borrowers, under the same circumstances, w i l l pay the higher r a t e s .
Bond and stock prices w i l l d e c l i n e .
Thus, prolonged and repeated attempts t o keep short-term i n t e r e s t
r a t e s from r i s i n g a c t u a l l y produces, over the longer r u n , accelerating
i n f l a t i o n , higher and more v o l a t i l e i n t e r e s t rates and lower share p r i c e s .
For example, i n a recovery, when c r e d i t demands are r i s i n g , an attempt t o
hold i n t e r e s t rates constant by accelerating reserve and money growth,
simply f u e l s the recovery even f u r t h e r .

I t generates increased i n f l a t i o n a r y

expectations and causes prices and i n t e r e s t rates t o r i s e even higher than
otherwise.

In an economic c o n t r a c t i o n , attempts t o keep i n t e r e s t rates from

f a l l i n g , w i l l produce an even deeper c o n t r a c t i o n and eventually a drop i n
interest rates.

In other words, attempts t o use monetary p o l i c y t o s t a b i l i z e

s h o r t - r u n i n t e r e s t rates produce, i n the long r u n , imstable p r i c e s , unstable
employment, and unstable long-run i n t e r e s t rates and lower r e a l stock
values—precisely the p a t t e r n we have observed, at considerable expense,
unti1 recently.
Why i s t h i s past h i s t o r y r e l e v a n t today?

Because we face v i r t u a l l y

the same pressures now t h a t we faced f i f t e e n years ago.




Today we have large

- 7 government deficits, both current and projected.

Today, although interest

rates have currently retreated from the recent peaks, we face projections of
higher rates for next year.

And, each time interest rates tick upwards, we

see increased political and financial market pressure on the Fed to control
these rates, to keep them from rising by accelerating credit and money
growth.
Virtually everyone wants stable interest rates and rising real stock
values.

You and I, the financial markets, politicians and monetary

authorities all do.

It is precisely this desire that mistakenly underlies

the demands that the Fed should stabilize rates. But, attempting to
stabilize the Fed funds rate has a cost:

it produces increased fluctuations

in long-term rates, accelerations in inflation and reductions in the wealth
of shareholders.

It has produced fifteen years of real stock market losses.

Should monetary policy attempt to directly stabilize short-term
interest rates or to indirectly stabilize long-term rates by directly
focusing on longer-term money growth?

Where do the greater costs lie? I

hope that you will agree with me that the problems posed by daily
fluctuations in short-term rates are inconsequential compared to the risks
facing stock markets produced by volatile and uncertain rates of inflation.
Thus, I would like to see a monetary policy that does not try to prevent
every market-induced wiggle in interest rates, but which tries to reduce
both the level and volatility of inflation.
Of course, pursuing such anti-inflationary policy actions is easier to
advocate than to actually accomplish.

That is evident in the experience of

the last three years. And, clearly, there are difficulties in engineering a




- 8 -

smooth reduction o f i n f l a t i o n .

One of the major problems would be maintain-

ing such a p o l i c y long enough t o wring out i n f l a t i o n a r y expectations.

But

we know t h a t there i s very l i t t l e we can do about i n f l a t i o n i n the short r u n .
A decline i n reserve growth w i l l , under most circumstances, r a i s e
short-term interest rates.

Tnis i n v a r i a b l y produces widespread concerns

over the p o s s i b i l i t y of inducing a recession.

Yet we know t h a t short-term

i n t e r e s t r a t e s have l i t t l e impact on the economy.
t h a t produce appreciable changes.

I t i s the long-term rates

We can p r e d i c t with reasonable accuracy

what a reduction i n reserves w i l l do t o the money supply.
how t o t a l spending w i l l r e a c t .

We can p r e d i c t

And we have r e l i a b l e estimates of what can

happen t o output and what e v e n t u a l l y w i l l happen t o i n f l a t i o n .

The longer

run problem i s one o f p o l i t i c a l w i l l ; i n the past, long-run p o l i c y actions
t o reduce i n f l a t i o n have been repeatedly thrown o f f course by immediate
p o l i t i c a l and f i n a n c i a l market concerns about changes i n s h o r t - r u n i n t e r e s t
rates.
What options do we have?
short-term i n t e r e s t r a t e s .

We can continue t o demand s t a b i l i z a t i o n of

But then we ought t o remember t h a t chances f o r

r e a c c e l e r a t i o n o f i n f l a t i o n or appearance of recession increase substantially.

Neither of which would bode w e l l f o r the stock market.

I , f o r one, prefer long-term i n t e r e s t r a t e s t a b i l i t y and r i s i n g r e a l
stock values.

This can be achieved only through stable money growth and

lower i n f l a t i o n .

While we may debate endlessly the d e f i n i t i o n of money and

what happens t o v e l o c i t y , even an e l u s i v e monetary t a r g e t i s preferable t o
attempted s t a b i l i z a t i o n o f short-term i n t e r e s t r a t e s .
In summary, i f we want t o have stock markets t h a t are e f f i c i e n t , t h a t
perform t h e i r f u n c t i o n o f channelling savings i n t o long-term investments,
and t h a t increase the wealth of shareholders over t i m e , we must maintain low




- 9 -

and stable r a t e s of i n f l a t i o n .

And t h a t cannot be achieved by a monetary

p o l i c y t h a t reacts t o e\/ery wiggle of the federal funds r a t e !

Yet, t o my

dismay, f i n a n c i a l market p a r t i c i p a n t s are often the ones who clamor the
loudest f o r t h i s unsound course.

That, perhaps, i s the biggest puzzle of

all.
Our present s i t u a t i o n appears t o be an o p p o r t u n i t y t o accomplish
everyone's desired o b j e c t i v e - s u s t a i n e d economic expansion without undue
inflation.

The economy i s doing w e l l , i n f l a t i o n i s subdued, and the

monetary aggregates are squarely w i t h i n the long-term p o l i c y bands set by
the Federal Open Market Committee.

In my o p i n i o n , the best way t o keep them

there i s t o concentrate on management of reserve growth-- not the l e v e l of
short-term i n t e r e s t r a t e s - - s i n c e , over t i m e , t h i s w i l l determine money
supply growth.

This i s a two-way s t r e e t .

I f money growth lags f o r too

l o n g , we could p r e c i p i t a t e a recession.
As I review the changes i n the p r i n c i p a l monetary aggregates, I note
t h a t t h e i r r a t e of growth has slackened i n each successive month since May.
However, I also note t h a t growth of the monetary base has picked up
considerably since i t s low p o i n t i n J u l y .

This leads me t o conclude t h a t

growth o f the monetary aggregates w i l l increase at a more appropriate r a t e
i n coming months.
I leave i t t o you t o decide what t h i s means f o r i n t e r e s t rates and the
stock market.

One of the o f f s e t s t o what i s euphemistically termed the

" p u b l i c sector discount" t o Federal Reserve Bank Presidents s a l a r i e s i s the
f a c t t h a t we d o n ' t have t o p r e d i c t i n t e r e s t rates and stock p r i c e s .