View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
10:00 a.m. EDT (3:00 p.m. local time)
September 28, 2017
Revised version: October 12, 2017

The Independent Bank of England--20 Years On

Remarks by
Stanley Fischer
Vice Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at
“20 Years On,” a conference sponsored by
the Bank of England
London, England

September 28, 2017
Revised version: October 12, 2017
Vice Chairman Fischer updated his remarks to elaborate on topics raised at the Bank of
England conference for which the speech was originally prepared.

It is a pleasure to speak at this commemoration of 20 years of Bank of England
monetary policy independence. In my remarks today, I will consider how central
banking in the United Kingdom and the United States has evolved in response to the
challenges of recent years. I will address a limited set of topics and will have time to
touch only briefly on each. 1
These remarks are divided into three parts. In the first part, I will discuss several
aspects of aggregate monetary policy: central bank independence, policy transparency,
and policy tools. In the second part, I consider differences between the approaches of the
two banks to their lender-of-last-resort function. And, third, I will close with brief
reflections on the central bank’s responsibility for financial stability.
Revisiting Goal Independence versus Instrument Independence
We start by considering a central bank that influences economic activity only
through its influence over the general level of interest rates. 2 More than two decades ago,
Guy Debelle and I offered two terms--goal independence and instrument independence-to describe such a central bank’s degree of independence. Our definitions were as
follows: “A central bank has goal independence when it is free to set the final goals of
monetary policy. . . . A bank that has instrument independence is free to choose the
means by which it seeks to achieve its goals.” 3 In May 1997, the Bank of England

1

I am grateful to Ed Nelson of the Federal Reserve Board for his excellent assistance. Views expressed in
this presentation are my own and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Board or the Federal Open
Market Committee.
2
The implications for monetary policy of central bank actions other than the use of its general monetary
policy tools will be considered in the latter parts of this presentation.
3
See Debelle and Fischer (1994, p. 197).

-2achieved instrument independence--something the Federal Reserve had already long
had. 4
Under the new law, the Bank of England’s Monetary Policy Committee (MPC),
rather than the Treasury, set the policy interest rate. Inflation targeting, which began in
the United Kingdom in 1992, continued under the new system and was codified in the
Bank of England Act of 1998. 5 The MPC was given an explicit numerical inflation
target, corresponding to effective price stability, alongside an implied stabilization goal
for real economic activity. 6 Consequently, the Bank of England from 1997 had the
combination that Debelle and I advocated: instrument independence but not goal
independence.
We also judged that the vagueness of the Federal Reserve’s statutory objectives
meant that the Federal Reserve “has considerable goal independence.” 7 Today both the
FOMC and the MPC have a numerical inflation goal--2 percent. However, this
numerical goal is not specified in legislation in either country. In the United Kingdom,
the Chancellor of the Exchequer sets the MPC’s inflation target: currently 2 percent per

4
U.S. monetary policy independence in the post-World War II era dates at least from the Federal
Reserve/Treasury Accord of 1951. See Eichengreen and Garber (1991). I discussed Federal Reserve
independence in detail in Fischer (2015a).
5
See the text of the act in Bank of England (2015a). (Since 1998, the U.K. Parliament has made a number
of amendments to the Bank of England Act 1998--among them a change, in 2016, to the frequency of MPC
meetings, from monthly to eight times a year. See Bank of England (2017a).)
6
From the start of inflation targeting in the United Kingdom in 1992, it was made clear that the authorities,
when faced with a situation in which inflation was different from the target rate, would generally not seek
to restore inflation to target as quickly as possible. Rather, they typically would opt for a policy that sought
to bring inflation back to target gradually, without unnecessary destabilization of real output. See LeighPemberton (1992) and Bernanke and others (1999, pp. 156-57). This approach has continued in the MPC
era, as discussed later. It is an approach consistent with the MPC’s remit in the Bank of England Act 1998
to achieve the inflation target through policies consistent with the economic policy of the U.K. government,
“including its objectives for growth and employment.”
7
See Debelle and Fischer (1994, p. 217).

-3year for the U.K. consumer price index. 8 In the United States, in the FOMC’s Statement
on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy, first issued in 2012 and discussed
annually, Committee participants have judged that the longer-run inflation objective that
corresponds to the Federal Reserve’s mandate is a rate of 2 percent per year, as measured
by the change in the price index for personal consumption expenditures. 9
In practice there is little difference between the policy goals of the two central
banks, or between the variables that are targeted. But there is a subtle difference between
them in terms of who sets the inflation target. To date, that difference has not generated
any major divergence between the approaches to monetary policy of the two central
banks.
Although much has changed in central banking since the 1990s, the case for
instrument independence and against goal independence remains sound. The case against
goal independence is that it is not appropriate in a democracy: goals should reflect the
preferences of society at large and should not be determined by unelected officials.
The goals of monetary policy should be set by the central government, as is the
case in both the United States and the United Kingdom. We all know what the goals of
the Bank of England and the Fed are: For both, the goals are stability of the price level
and full employment. Although there is a hint of a lexicographic ordering in favor of the
rate of inflation in the Bank of England’s mandate, the Federal Reserve’s dual mandate
unambiguously places equal weight on both goals. Across the world, there seems to be a
8

For the most recent statement by the Chancellor of the Exchequer on the inflation target to be pursued by
the MPC, see Hammond (2017).
9
See Federal Open Market Committee (2017). See Bernanke (2012) for testimony discussing the longerrun objective shortly after it was announced. Bernanke (2015, p. 528) indicated that the FOMC’s
announcement of the 2 percent longer-run objective was preceded by consultation between himself and
congressional leaders. In Fischer (2015a), I took the explicit 2 percent longer-run objective as the means
by which the FOMC had made its legislated price stability goal operational.

-4preference for inflation either to be the only goal variable or to be lexicographically
emphasized over unemployment. But I do not regard that difference as very significant.
There is no central bank that--in Mervyn King’s terminology--is an “inflation nutter.” 10
Instrument independence is necessary because, without it, the central bank is
unable to set the stance of monetary policy that it believes to be most consistent with
achievement of the statutory mandate. That said, there are, to be sure, degrees of
instrument independence, and one can easily envisage central banks with considerable
instrument independence whose actions on their instruments are constrained by law or by
decisions by the treasury. For example, in a country that has committed its central bank
to enforce an exchange rate band (with the exchange rate free to move within the band),
the central bank will not be fully instrument independent, though it may have a
substantial amount of independence with respect to the precise settings of the policy
interest rate and other monetary tools.
Historically, central banks were frequently created to finance public spending.
However, these banks--such as those in Sweden and the United Kingdom--were later
sometimes given their operational independence in part to create a greater separation of
monetary policy from fiscal policy--in particular, in order to ensure that they would not
be vulnerable to pressure to finance the government budget (that is, to monetize public
spending). Around the world, the fear of the central bank losing its ability to meet its
price stability goal may well have been the prime reason for governments to implement
instrument independence. 11

10

See King (1997, p. 89).
For further discussion, see, for example, Bernanke (2010), Debelle and Fischer (1994, p. 217), and
Fischer (1994, pp 262, 290-91). Initially, the argument was that the central bank was needed to prevent
11

-5Fundamentally, however, central bank instrument independence is desirable
because monetary policy is an esoteric and complicated art or science, involving
technical judgments that have economy-wide and often long-lasting consequences: A
separate institution is needed to manage and take responsibility for monetary policy.
Central banks have over the years--in some cases over a few centuries--amassed an
expertise and developed a character that makes them the natural candidates to perform
the functions expected of such institutions. As the Governor of the Riksbank has
observed, the most important skill and reputation that a central bank needs is one of
reliability. 12 That is, both the central government and the general public should be
confident that their central bank can be relied on to deliver a stable price level and close
to full employment, along with financial stability. If such independent institutions did
not exist, we would have to invent them; if they exist and perform well, the country is
blessed; and if they exist and perform badly, they need to be reformed--by a change in the
laws by which they are governed, by changes in their structure, or by changes in
personnel--and sometimes all of the above.

Transparency, Accountability, and Communications
In a paper written for the Bank of England’s tercentenary, I considered how an
instrument-independent central bank might conduct itself. 13 My discussion noted that an
independent central bank should adhere to the “principle of accountability to the public of

inflation from becoming too high; now, the argument is couched in terms of symmetry of the losses from
both too-high and too-low inflation.
12
The Governor of the Riksbank is Stefan Ingves.
13
See Fischer (1994, 1995). Much of my discussion was with particular reference to the United Kingdom,
and I argued that the Bank of England should receive independence.

-6those who make critically important policy decisions.” 14 Accountability, in the senses I
defined it, included the requirement “to explain and justify its policies to the legislature
and the public”--that is, policy transparency and communications. 15 Transparency,
public accountability, and policy communications form the quid pro quo of central bank
independence, and they can also contribute to achievement of macroeconomic goals.
These were points the FOMC recognized in its Statement on Longer-Run Goals and
Monetary Policy Strategy, which observed that clarity concerning policy decisions
“increases the effectiveness of monetary policy, and enhances transparency and
accountability, which are essential in a democratic society.” In my coverage of these
issues today, however, I would like to concentrate on the Bank of England, which in the
past quarter-century has been an innovator in several ways with regard to accountability
and transparency.
Calls for more transparency concerning U.K. monetary policy and the Bank of
England’s monetary actions predated independence. For example, in the late 1950s,
Richard Sayers observed: “It may not be wise to turn the central bank into a goldfish
bowl, but at least some relaxation of the traditional secretiveness would make for better
health in the nation’s monetary affairs.” 16 And some Bank communications vehicles,
such as the economic analysis in the Quarterly Bulletin and testimony and speeches by
the Governor and other Bank officials, were of long standing by the mid-1990s. But the
Bank of England made further strides toward improved transparency and
communications during the 1990s. In 1993, it initiated the Inflation Report. From the

14

See Fischer (1994, p. 262).
See Fischer (1994, p. 301).
16
See Sayers (1958, p. 314).
15

-7beginning, the Inflation Report was intended to increase transparency about the U.K.
monetary policy reaction function--that is, the connection between policy instruments and
economic variables, including the goal variables. 17 After independence, the Inflation
Report presented the MPC’s inflation forecast. Furthermore, alongside other Bank
statements, the Inflation Report provides a publicly available analysis of the economy
and of economic implications of developments like Brexit. The content reflects the
Bank’s change in focus--from markets in the pre-inflation-targeting era to
macroeconomic implications of financial and other developments. 18
The Bank expanded its policy communications after 1997, publishing MPC
analogues to the FOMC releases (some of them only recent innovations by the Fed),
namely, postmeeting MPC statements and meeting minutes. And an innovation of
Mervyn King in the early years of inflation targeting that has continued in the era of
independence is the Inflation Report press conference. Here, senior Bank figures discuss
the MPC’s forecast and the state of the economy. This innovation was a forerunner of
the Federal Reserve Chair’s press conference, begun in 2011, in which the Chair
describes the latest policy decision together with the Summary of Economic Projections
(SEP) of FOMC participants.

17

See Crockett (1994, p. 183). The desire to be explicit about the reaction function has continued to be a
theme of policymaker statements in the era of the MPC. See, for example, King (2002), Allsopp (2002),
Tucker (2007), and Bean (2009).
18
The MPC arrangements also require that a letter be written from the Bank Governor to the Chancellor of
the Exchequer in the event of an overshoot or undershoot of the inflation target that is in excess of 1
percent. As well as providing accountability, this arrangement gives the Bank an opportunity to emphasize
the longer-term nature of the inflation goal and the consideration given in MPC policy decisions to the
stabilization of real economic activity. For example, Carney (2016) outlined, among other things, “the
horizon over which the MPC judges it appropriate to return inflation to the target” and “the trade-off that
has been made with regard to inflation and output variability in determining the scale and duration of any
expected deviation of inflation from the target.”

-8New Monetary Policy Tools
The MPC and FOMC have extensively--particularly in recent years--used two
monetary policy tools other than decisions on the current short-term interest rate. These
tools are forward guidance and asset purchases. 19
Monetary authorities used to be reluctant to discuss the future course of the policy
rate. 20 By 1997, however, there was widespread recognition of the merits of clarity on
the reaction function and of having long-term interest rates incorporate accurate
expectations of future policy. These considerations led to the FOMC’s use of forward
guidance regarding the short-term interest rate in its postmeeting statements during the
mid-2000s. The MPC, in contrast, for a long time generally preferred to let markets infer
likely future rates from the extensive communication it provided about its reaction
function. 21
Beginning in 2008, with the policy rate at or near its lower bound, regular forward
guidance acquired new efficacy. 22 Through forward guidance, additional

19

In addition to these tools, the MPC has used the Funding for Lending Scheme to boost bank lending. It is
beyond the scope of my talk to discuss this further innovation.
20
For example, Federal Reserve Chairman Arthur Burns once noted (Burns, 1977, p. 717): “Federal
Reserve officials are extremely careful to avoid any public comment that might suggest or imply some
particular outlook for interest rates.” In the United Kingdom, in 1981 Chancellor of the Exchequer
Geoffrey Howe observed (Howe, 1981) that it was not the authorities’ “practice to forecast interest rate
movements.”
21
Although it provides an inflation forecast in the Inflation Report, the MPC does not form an interest rate
forecast in conjunction with that inflation forecast. Instead, its current practice is to report a “CPI inflation
projection based on market interest rate expectations” (Bank of England, 2017b, chart 5.1). The fact that
the MPC’s Inflation Report forecasts (for real output growth, inflation, and the unemployment rate)
condition on market expectations of interest rates is one difference between the MPC forecasts and the
FOMC participants’ projections that are summarized in the SEP. Another difference is that the SEP
consolidates information on the projections constructed and submitted separately by the individual FOMC
participants, while the Inflation Report’s economic projections are arrived at collectively by the MPC and
are therefore the forecasts of the committee as a whole. This is another aspect of the differences of
behavior between the two monetary committees that is both interesting and possibly important, but for
which there is not enough time for a more detailed discussion.
22
Woodford (2013) provides an analysis of the value of forward guidance under various conditions,
including the case in which the policy rate is at its lower bound.

-9accommodation from short-term interest rate policy could be provided by lengthening the
period over which the policy rate was expected to remain at its lower bound. The
knowledge that the short-term policy rate likely would be lower for longer would put
downward pressure on longer-term rates. The FOMC has provided forward guidance on
the policy rate in its postmeeting statements ever since the target federal funds rate was
brought to the lower bound in December 2008. In addition, the SEP shows individual
FOMC participants’ expectations regarding the policy rate, though it does not identify the
individuals in the interest rate dot plot. In the United Kingdom, the MPC started
providing forward guidance in its postmeeting statements in 2013. 23
As the policy rate--Bank Rate--is still at its lower bound in the United Kingdom,
it remains to be seen whether MPC forward guidance will continue during policy firming.
For its part, the FOMC has provided forward guidance in its policy statements during the
tightening phase that began with the increase in the target range for the federal funds rate
in December 2015. I expect that the Bank of England will also likely continue to use
forward guidance when it begins to raise the policy interest rate above its effective lower
bound.
Asset purchases are less of a new tool than forward guidance. In the early postWorld War II decades, both U.K. and U.S. authorities sporadically attempted to influence
long-term interest rates directly by transacting in longer-term Treasury securities. By
1997, however, monetary policy operations in longer-term securities markets had fallen
into disuse. 24 The financial crisis changed matters, with both countries’ central banks

23

See Carney (2014) for a discussion of the benefits of forward guidance for the U.K. economy.
Federal Reserve operations for monetary policy purposes in longer-term securities markets had largely
been absent since the Operation Twist experiment of the early 1960s (see, for example, Meltzer (2009, pp.
316-23)). In the United Kingdom, operations in longer-term securities markets had continued to figure

24

- 10 expanding their balance sheets through large-scale purchases of longer-dated securities to
put downward pressure on longer-term interest rates and set in motion movements in
asset prices and borrowing costs that would stimulate spending by households and
businesses. It is widely, though not universally, recognized that these asset purchases
helped contain the economic downturns in the United Kingdom and the United States and
underpinned the subsequent recovery in each country. This experience raises the
question of whether the balance sheet will continue to be a routine tool of monetary
policy once interest rates normalize. 25 The FOMC has indicated its preference that,
barring large adverse shocks to the economy, adjustments to the federal funds rate will be
the main means of altering the stance of monetary policy. 26
Changing Perspectives on the Lender of Last Resort
The second section concerns the role of the lender of last resort. The financial
crisis and recession confirmed the value of central bank tools that affect the financial
system, beyond those most associated with monetary policy. One of these tools is the
discount window or lender-of-last-resort function. As of the mid-2000s, the posture of
the Bank of England and the Federal Reserve toward the lender-of-last-resort function
reflected the principles enunciated by Bagehot and the long absence of a severe financial
crisis: The discount rate stood above the key policy rate by a fixed amount; the discount

importantly in monetary policy until the mid-1980s, reflecting attempts by the authorities to influence the
term structure of interest rates or to control the stock of money or the volume of liquidity (see Fischer
(1987), Goodhart (1999), and Batini and Nelson (2005)). A difference between most of these earlier
operations and those in the modern era is that recent years’ asset purchases have usually involved an
expansion of the central bank’s overall balance sheet.
25
For a recent discussion of the Federal Reserve’s position on the matter, see Yellen (2017).
26
See, for example, Board of Governors (2017).

- 11 window was not used for macroeconomic stabilization; and depository institutions were
the users of the discount window, typically on a short-term basis. 27
In 1978, Rudi Dornbusch and I noted that the lender-of-last-resort function should
imply that “the central bank steps in to ensure that funds are available to make loans to
firms which are perfectly sound but, because of panic, are having trouble raising
funds.” 28 In the financial crisis that started in 2007, wide-ranging measures were taken
along these lines. In order to improve the functioning of U.S. credit markets, the Federal
Reserve made numerous changes to its lending arrangements: The spread of the discount
rate over the policy rate was lowered, lending was extended to include loans to
nondepository financial institutions, and facilities were created allowing longer maturity
of, and broader collateral for, loans than was usual for the central bank. 29
After its own experience during the financial crisis, the Bank of England
permanently widened lender-of-last-resort access to include not only commercial banks,
but also other systemically important financial institutions. 30 In the United States, the
discount rate has for several years been back to its normal relationship with the policy
rate, and the special lending facilities have long since been wound up. Emergency
lending facilities of the type seen during the financial crisis remain feasible, if needed,
though their usage has not been incorporated into the Federal Reserve’s routine lender-oflast-resort powers, along the lines of the changes seen in the United Kingdom. Instead,

27

See Bagehot ([1873] 1897) for the classic discussion of the central bank’s role as lender of last resort.
See Dornbusch and Fischer (1978, p. 528).
29
This is a very brief and simplified discussion of the actions taken by the Federal Reserve with regard to
the discount window during the crisis. See, among others, Cecchetti (2009) and Madigan (2009) for
detailed discussions. For reasons of space, I will not recount the United Kingdom’s policy response in this
area during the crisis.
30
Specifically, the Bank provided access to the largest broker-dealers subject to U.K. regulation and to
central counterparties. See Carney (2014) and Bank of England (2015b).
28

- 12 the restriction on their deployment has been tightened by requiring approval by the U.S.
Treasury.
Discount window lending puts public funds at risk--though I stress that the
Federal Reserve’s lending during the crisis did not, in fact, lead to any losses. The lender
of last resort is also a less impersonal, and more allocative, device than aggregate
monetary policy tools, because it involves direct lending by the central bank instead of an
attempt by monetary policy to alter the overall cost of private-sector borrowing. For
these reasons, the lender-of-last-resort function is bound to be more rule driven than
interest rate policy, and it is inevitably associated with collateral arrangements and other
safeguards to protect against losses and with strict eligibility criteria.
The Financial Stability Responsibility of the Central Bank
Our third and final section concerns the financial stability responsibility of the
central bank. This responsibility has been subject to considerable institutional change
over the past two decades. Until 1997, the Bank of England had wide supervisory and
regulatory powers. With the reforms of the late 1990s, the Bank had a deputy governor
responsible for financial stability, but regulatory powers were largely moved to a
different institution, the Financial Services Authority (FSA). A decade later, the financial
crisis demonstrated that financial imbalances can ultimately endanger macroeconomic
stability and highlighted the need for enhanced central bank oversight of the financial
system. In the post-crisis era, the FSA became two separate regulatory authorities, one of
which--the Prudential Regulation Authority, created in 2012--is part of the Bank of
England. In effect, regulatory powers have largely returned to the Bank. It is fair to say

- 13 that the Bank was initially glad to cede many of its financial powers, but that it was later
even more glad to have those powers restored.
Financial supervision has also been reformed in the United States in light of the
crisis. The Federal Reserve, which always had regulatory powers, received enhanced
authority and devoted more resources to financial stability. 31 In both countries, it
remains the case that not all financial stability responsibilities rest with the central bank-so it is less independent in this area than in monetary policy proper--and the central
bank’s tools for achieving financial stability are still being refined. Indeed, as I have
noted previously, a major concern of mine is that the U.S. macroprudential toolkit is not
large and not yet battle tested. 32
The Federal Reserve and the Bank of England benefit from each other’s
experience as they develop and improve arrangements to meet their financial stability
responsibilities. One major innovation that deserves mention is that the Bank of England
has two policy committees: Alongside the MPC is the Financial Policy Committee
(FPC). Although they coordinate and have partially overlapping memberships, the MPC
and FPC are distinct committees.
Why have both the MPC and the FPC? I offer a few possible reasons. First, not
all of a central bank’s responsibilities typically rest with its monetary committee. This is
true not only of the Bank of England, but also of the Federal Reserve: Our financial
regulatory authority resides in the Board of Governors, not the FOMC. Second,
aggregate monetary policy tools--typically, one is talking of the policy interest rate--are

31

This resource decision led, in 2010, to the creation within the Federal Reserve Board of the Office of
Financial Stability Policy and Research (which later became the Division of Financial Stability).
32
See Fischer (2015b).

- 14 often blunt weapons against financial imbalances, so deploying them might produce a
conflict between financial stability and short-term economic stabilization.
Macroprudential tools may be more direct and more appropriate for fostering financial
stability. 33 Third, financial policy might need less frequent adjustment than monetary
policy. Perhaps reflecting this judgment, the FPC meets on a quarterly basis, which
contrasts with the MPC’s eight meetings a year. 34 The lower frequency of meetings may
also reflect the desirability of a relatively stable regulatory structure; financial tools likely
should not be as continuously data dependent as monetary policy tools.
It is clear that the U.K. institutional framework for the preservation of financial
stability has much to be said for it. But it also seems clear that there is no uniquely
optimal set-up of the framework for the maintenance of financial stability that is
independent of the size and scale of the financial system of the country or of its political
and financial history.
Conclusion
It has been more than 20 years since the Bank of England celebrated its 300th
birthday with a conference focused on central bank independence. Since then, central
banks’ operating frameworks have undergone substantial changes, many in response to
the financial crisis. But the case for monetary policy independence set out in the 1990s
remains sound, and monetary policy independence is now widely accepted in the United
Kingdom, as it long has been in the United States. It is also clear that central bank
responsibilities other than policy rate decisions--specifically, the lender-of-last-resort

33

For policymakers’ consideration of this point in the U.S. context, see, for example, Bernanke (2011) and
Board of Governors (2016).
34
See Bank of England (2017c).

- 15 function and financial stability--are closely connected with monetary policy and that
these responsibilities play a prominent role in macroeconomic stabilization.
Let me conclude by observing that, while the crisis and its aftermath motivated
central banks to reappraise and adapt their tools, institutions, and thinking, future
challenges will doubtless prompt further reforms. 35 Or, if I may be permitted a few final
words on my way out the door, the watchwords of the central banker should be “Semper
vigilans,” because history and financial markets are masters of the art of surprise, and
“Never say never,” because you will sometimes find yourself having to do things that you
never thought you would.

35

It is worth noting that the 20-year period that is the focus of these remarks constitutes only a little over
6 percent of the history of the Bank of England--and there certainly have been a lot of surprises during that
short period in the history of the second oldest of the world’s central banks.

- 16 References
Allsopp, Christopher (2002). “Macroeconomic Policy Rules in Theory and Practice,”
Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, vol. 42 (Winter), pp. 485-504.
Bagehot, Walter ([1873] 1897). Lombard Street: A Description of the Money Market.
New York: Charles Scribner’s Sons.
Bank of England (2015a). The Bank of England Act 1998, the Charters of the Bank and
Related Documents. London: BOE, July,
www.bankofengland.co.uk/about/Documents/legislation/1998act.pdf.
-------- (2015b). The Bank of England’s Sterling Monetary Framework: Updated June
2015. London: BOE,
www.bankofengland.co.uk/markets/Documents/money/publications/redbook.pdf.
-------- (2017a). “Monetary Policy Committee (MPC),” webpage, BOE,
www.bankofengland.co.uk/monetarypolicy/Pages/overview.aspx.
-------- (2017b). Inflation Report. London: BOE, August,
www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Documents/inflationreport/2017/aug.pdf.
-------- (2017c). “Financial Policy Committee Meeting Records and Statements,”
webpage, BOE,
www.bankofengland.co.uk/financialstability/Pages/fpc/meetings/default.aspx.
Batini, Nicoletta, and Edward Nelson (2005). “The U.K.’s Rocky Road to Stability,”
Working Paper Series 2005-020A. St. Louis: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis,
March, https://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/more/2005-020.
Bean, Charles (2009). “Comment on ‘Interest Rate Signals and Central Bank
Transparency,’” in Richard H. Clarida and Francesco Giavazzi, eds., NBER
Seminar on Macroeconomics 2007. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp.
52-54.

- 17 Bernanke, Ben S. (2010). “Central Bank Independence, Transparency, and
Accountability,” speech delivered at the Institute for Monetary and Economic
Studies International Conference, Bank of Japan, Tokyo, May 25,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20100525a.htm.
-------- (2011). “The Effects of the Great Recession on Central Bank Doctrine and
Practice,” speech delivered at the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston 56th Economic
Conference, Boston, October 18,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20111018a.htm.
-------- (2012). “Semiannual Monetary Policy Report to the Congress,” statement before
the Committee on Financial Services, U.S. House of Representatives, February
29,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/bernanke20120229a.htm.
-------- (2015). The Courage to Act: A Memoir of a Crisis and Its Aftermath. New York:
W.W. Norton and Company.
Bernanke, Ben S., Thomas Laubach, Frederic S. Mishkin, and Adam S. Posen (1999).
Inflation Targeting: Lessons from the International Experience. Princeton, N.J.:
Princeton University Press.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2016). “Minutes of the Federal
Open Market Committee, April 26-27, 2016,” press release, May 18,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20160518a.ht
m.
-------- (2017). “Minutes of the Federal Open Market Committee, March 14-15, 2017,”
press release, April 5,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/pressreleases/monetary20170405a.ht
m.
Burns, Arthur F. (1977). “Statement before the Committee on Banking, Finance and
Urban Affairs, U.S. House of Representatives, July 26, 1977,” Federal Reserve
Bulletin, vol. 63 (August), pp. 717-21,
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org/files/docs/publications/FRB/1970s/frb_081977.pdf.

- 18 -

Carney, Mark (2014). Speech delivered at the Lord Mayor’s Banquet for Bankers and
Merchants of the City of London at the Mansion House, London, June 12,
www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Documents/speeches/2014/speech736.pdf
.
-------- (2016). Letter from the Governor of the Bank of England to the Chancellor of the
Exchequer, February 4,
http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/monetarypolicy/Documents/pdf/cpiletter040216.
pdf.
Cecchetti, Stephen G. (2009). “Crisis and Responses: The Federal Reserve in the Early
Stages of the Financial Crisis,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 23
(Winter), pp. 51-75.
Crockett, Andrew D. (1994). “Rules versus Discretion in Monetary Policy,” in J. Onno
de Beaufort Wijnholds, Sylvester C.W. Eiffinger, and Lex H. Hoogduin, eds., A
Framework for Monetary Stability: Papers and Proceedings of an International
Conference Organised by De Nederlandsche Bank and the CentER for Economic
Research at Amsterdam. Dordrecht, Netherlands: Springer, pp. 165-84.
Debelle, Guy, and Stanley Fischer (1994). “How Independent Should a Central Bank
Be?” in Goals, Guidelines, and Constraints Facing Monetary Policymakers,
proceedings of a conference held in North Falmouth, Massachusetts, in June
1994. Boston: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, pp. 195-221,
http://www.bos.frb.org/economic/conf/conf38/conf38f.pdf.
Dornbusch, Rudiger, and Stanley Fischer (1978). Macroeconomics. New York: McGrawHill.
Eichengreen, Barry, and Peter M. Garber (1991). “Before the Accord: U.S. MonetaryFinancial Policy, 1945-51,” in R .Glenn Hubbard, ed., Financial Markets and
Financial Crises. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 175-206.
Federal Open Market Committee (2017). Statement on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary
Policy Strategy, amended effective January 31 (original version adopted effective

- 19 January 24, 2012),
https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/fomc_longerrungoals.pdf.

Fischer, Stanley (1987). “Monetary Policy,” in Rudiger Dornbusch and Richard Layard,
eds., The Performance of the British Economy. Oxford, United Kingdom:
Clarendon Press, pp. 6-28.
-------- (1994). “Modern Central Banking,” in Forrest Capie, Charles Goodhart, Stanley
Fischer, and Norbert Schnadt, eds., The Future of Central Banking: The
Tercentenary Symposium of the Bank of England. New York: Cambridge
University Press, pp. 262-308.
-------- (1995). “Modern Approaches to Central Banking,” NBER Working Paper Series
5064. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, March.
-------- (2015a). “Central Bank Independence,” speech delivered at the 2015 Herbert
Stein Memorial Lecture, National Economists Club, Washington, November 4,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/fischer20151104a.htm.
-------- (2015b). “Macroprudential Policy in the U.S. Economy,” speech delivered at
“Macroprudential Monetary Policy,” 59th Economic Conference of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Boston, Boston, October 2,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/fischer20151002a.htm.
Goodhart, Charles A.E. (1999). “Monetary Policy and Debt Management in the United
Kingdom: Some Historical Viewpoints,” in K. Alec Chrystal, ed., Government
Debt Structure and Monetary Conditions. London: Bank of England, pp. 43-97.
Hammond, Philip (2017). “Remit of the Bank of England,” letter from the Chancellor of
the Exchequer to the Governor of the Bank of England, March 8,
http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/monetarypolicy/Documents/pdf/chancellorletter
080317.pdf.
Howe, Geoffrey (1981). “Written Answers: Minimum Lending Rate,” House of
Commons debates, June 4,

- 20 http://hansard.millbanksystems.com/written_answers/1981/jun/04/minimumlending-rate#S6CV0005P0_19810604_CWA_167.
King, Mervyn (1997). “Changes in UK Monetary Policy: Rules and Discretion in
Practice,” Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 39 (June), pp. 81-97.
-------- (2002). “The Inflation Target Ten Years On,” Bank of England Quarterly
Bulletin, vol. 42 (Winter), pp. 459-74.
Leigh-Pemberton, Robin (1992). “The Case for Price Stability,” Bank of England
Quarterly Bulletin, vol. 32 (November), pp. 441-48,
http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/archive/Documents/historicpubs/qb/1992/qb92q
4441448.pdf.
Madigan, Brian (2009). “Bagehot’s Dictum in Practice: Formulating and Implementing
Policies to Combat the Financial Crisis,” in Financial Stability and
Macroeconomic Policy, proceedings of the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas
City’s Annual Economic Symposium. Kansas City, Mo.: Federal Reserve Bank
of Kansas City, pp. 169-89.
Meltzer, Allan H. (2009). A History of the Federal Reserve, vol. 2, book 1: 1951-1969.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Sayers, R.S. (1958). Modern Banking, 4th ed. Oxford, United Kingdom: Clarendon
Press.
Tucker, Paul (2007). “Money and Credit: Banking and the Macroeconomy,” speech
delivered at the Monetary Policy and the Markets Conference, London, December
13,
www.bankofengland.co.uk/archive/Documents/historicpubs/speeches/2007/speec
h331.pdf.
Woodford, Michael (2013). “Forward Guidance by Inflation-Targeting Central Banks.”
CEPR Discussion Paper 9722. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research,
November.

- 21 Yellen, Janet L. (2017). “Inflation, Uncertainty, and Monetary Policy,” speech delivered
at the 59th Annual Meeting of the National Association for Business Economics,
Cleveland, September 26,
https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/yellen20170926a.htm.