View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

STATEMENT ON

THE CREDIT DEREGULATION AND
AVAILABILITY ACT OF 1983

PRESENTED TO

COMMITTEE ON BANKING, HOUSING, AND URBAN AFFAIRS
UNITED STATES SENATE

BY

STANLEY C. SILVERBERG
DIRECTOR OF RESEARCH & STRATEGIC PLANNING
FEDERAL DEPOSIT INSURANCE CORPORATION

9:00 a.m.
Tuesday, April 12, 1983
Room SD-538

United States Senate

Mr. Chairman:
I am pleased to have the opportunity to testify on S. 730, a bill to amend
the Depository Institutions Deregulation and Monetary Control Act of 1980.
The latter bill, among other provisions, preempted state usury limits on
residential first mortgages and established minimum ceilings on certain
agricultural and business credits for a three-year period which ended March
31, 1983«

With respect to both of these provisions states were given three

years during which they could override the Federal preemption.
S. 730 would eliminate interest rate ceilings altogether on the same
covered areas of agricultural and business credit and eliminate rate ceilings
on consumer credit.
credit unions.

Ceilings would also be removed on all loans of Federal

S. 730 would permit states to override the Federal statute

during a three-year period following its enactment and, in addition, any state
action previously taken to override the 1980 Act would continue to be in
force.

If S. 730 is enacted, it could, for all practical purposes, eliminate

usury ceilings altogether in states that have not overridden provisions of the
1980 Act and choose not to override S. 730.
The FDIC endorses S. 730.

We believe that usury ceilings are an

impediment to market behavior and that these ceilings adversely affect all
sectors of the economy.

The case against usury ceilings has been well

documented in theoretical and empirical studies.

Those parties most directly

impacted by ceilings in those states with the most restrictive ceilings have
been among the strongest advocates of revision, providing practical evidence
of the perverse nature of restrictive ceilings.




)

-

2-

A recent study of the impact of the ceiling on consumers in Arkansas
documents how ceilings acted to reduce consumer options, to channel financing
to more costly and less efficient alternatives, to raise credit standards and
limit terms so that lower income consumers were rationed out of the market,
and generally to affect the economy in a perverse manner.

Other studies and

more casual observations indicate similar and equally perverse results in
other situations where usury ceilings have been very restrictive.
The Depository Deregulation and Monetary Control Act of 1980 set minimum
ceilings on agricultural and business loans that were tied to the Federal
Reserve discount rate.

Many have testified against the appropriateness of

tying ceilings to an administered short-term rate (I did in testimony on S.
1406 and S. 963 two years ago).
ceiling.

We are pleased that S. 730 sets no rate-tied

While better choices exist than the discount rate, there is no

assurance that a market-tied ceiling won’
t become overly binding at some
future date.

We favor the provisions of S. 730 which eliminate ceilings

altogether, if states don’
t act to override.

Also, we strongly favor the

inclusion of consumer loan rates in the Bill.
The best assurance that potential borrowers have access to credit on terms
consistent with risk, prevailing interest rates and the overall demand and
supply of savings comes from the maintenance of competitive markets in the
financial services industry.

Usury ceilings actually reduce competition and

the alternatives available in local credit markets.

They tend to injure the

very people they are intended to aid by denying them access to credit.
During the last few years Congress has taken important steps to increase
competition in financial markets.

Thrift powers to lend in business and

consumer credit markets have been substantially increased, and many states




-3have responded to Federal action by liberalizing lending options for
state-chartered institutions*
liberalized.

Interest rate ceilings have been substantially

While some restrictions remain (which we hope will be dismantled

soon), it is not much of an exaggeration to say that depository institutions
are unregulated with respect to what they can pay for funds.
certainly true of their competitors.

And that’
s

This has resulted in market situations

where outside competitors can easily penetrate local markets wherever
institutions pay significantly less than prevailing market rates.

Competition

has been substantially expanded for retail deposits.
In order to earn satisfactory returns on funds that are no longer
available at bargain rates, lenders are under pressure to seek out loan
alternatives in their traditional trade areas or, if necessary, in other
areas.

Thus, fewer markets will be insulated.

and that increase is likely to spread.

Competition has been increased

As a result, we do not see any need to

protect borrowers from "excessive" rates.

If community banks and thrifts are

to be viable competitors in the marketplace they will have to be able to earn
market rates on consumer, business and agricultural loans.
they won't be able to pay market rates for deposits.

If they can't,

Deposits will shift to

depository and other financial institutions in other parts of the country that
pay higher rates.

As a result ceilings will adversely affect local

institutions, limit local borrowing options and adversely affect those that
ceilings are supposed to protect.
We note from the financial press that recent declines in interest rates
may remove pressure to abolish ceilings through Federal legislation.

It is

true that not as many state ceilings are below market rates today than at some
times in the past.




However, nobody can forecast interest rates with a great

-4deal of confidence.
past, they have.

Too many external forces can affect rates and, in the

We see no reason to have second thoughts about eliminating

ceilings now, just because doing so is not that urgent.
We believe, and I have already suggested, that credit markets have become
more and more national markets.
large corporate credits.

No one would question this with respect to

Indeed, many foreign banks have penetrated lending

markets for what used to be considered regional firms, let alone the lending
market for national firms.

In consumer and real estate markets there are many

national participants including bank and affiliates and major nonbank
financial conglomerates.

We are not overly troubled by Federal preemption in

this area as S. 730 does give states the option of overriding the elimination
of ceilings as did the 1980 Act.

We understand that about 15 states took

advantage of this option in the last three years, although some merely
preserved their future options without imposing ceilings.
Mr. Chairman, the FDIC supports S. 730.