View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For Release ON DELIVERY

Tuesday, November 23, 1971
Approximately! P.M., P.S.T.
(4 P.M., E.S.T.)




Production
Prices
Pay
Productivity
and
Profi ts

Remarks
of
SHERMAN J. MAISEL
Member
Board of Governors
of the
Federal Reserve System

At a
conference on
Phase I to Phase II:
The New Economic Policy in Transition
Presented by
Institute of Industrial Relations
University of California, Berkeley
Tuesday, November 23, 1971
Hotel Mark Hopkins, San Francisco

Production
Pri ces
Pay
Productivity
and
Profi ts
I am glad to have this opportunity to speak to a joint labormanagement conference. We are in the midst of major new economic develop­
ments with tremendous potential impacts on the nation's and our individual
future. The interests of each of us as individuals, of all of us as a
nation, and of many other nations, are all heavily involved.
Success or failure will depend primarily upon how, at this
juncture, we make use of an old American idea: those policies are best
for each of us that are best for all of us. That is to say, success or
failure of the economic policies we are now embarked upon will depend
primarily upon a general willingness to move cooperatively along a path
delineated by national goals.
But such cooperation cannot be achieved by begging the fact that
in an alert, open, and vital society there is never going to be universal
agreement upon what policies, either general or specific, do in fact most
accurately serve our individual interests. On the contrary, criticism and
disagreement are not only to be expected: they are vital. They are neces­
sary in order to clarify issues and to provide solutions that take into
account the genuine divergent problems of individuals, groups, or firms.
What is not helpful, and will not work, is disagreement frozen
into polarization. Such rigidities need not follow from the fact that
some of you represent labor and some management. The national interest
clearly does not require that either management or labor even partially
abandon its role. The two represent differences of interests that are
both real and important. Consequently, each should be heard distinctly
in the dialogue that will shape the outcome of the policies now being put
into practice. Labor should continue to speak as the expert on, and advo­
cate for, workers. Management should continue to speak as the expert on,
and advocate for, the uses of capital. But— and here, as I see it, is
what makes vigorous difference compatible with productive cooperationlabor can--and should— speak for labor in the context of national goals,
and management can--and should— speak for capital with national goals in
mind.
The Goals of Policy
In order for partisan defense of real and important differences
to be tempered into working collaboration through inclusion of the national
perspective, we need to be guided by a full understanding of the national
goals as they have been set before us.




-2 -

Today, my primary aim is to examine the internal logic of the
apparent path to these goals. Each of you can then judge whether he be­
lieves the assumptions underlying the programs are or are not likely to
work out, and if not how he thinks they will vary.
The goals of the New Economic Policy are (1) to raise real out­
put, thereby lowering unemployment; (2) to lessen price increases; and
(3) to do this equitably by minimizing undesirable income redistributions.
Correction of the balance of payments is a related but separate goal that
must be left for discussion elsewhere. Suffice it to say here that all
of the international objectives which are the external counterparts of
our internal goals will be well served by success at home.
I think the interrelation of the national goals of the New Eco­
nomic Policy can be best expressed through the five P's I have used as
the title to these remarks--"Production, Prices, Pay, Productivity, and
Profits." How do they relate to the goals? Output in real terms and jobs
will rise with Production. The rate of increase in Prices must decline
into the 2 to 3 per cent sphere, even in the face of increased economic
activity. This is possible only if Pay and Profits corrected for changes
in Productivity raise costs by less than the 3 per cent limit. Further­
more, their relationship to Prices must be such as to maintain both equity
and a sufficient demand to call forth the desired increase in Production.
It is this basically simple, but fragile and subtle, set of
relationships and cross-connections that we must understand. I have
started by sketching them in this general way because the first and most
important thing to understand is that these five basic factors are in­
extricably bound together. Each influences all the others directly and
there are feed-back relationships among them all.
Let me turn now to a more detailed consideration of these ele­
ments of the economic equation and of their importance to one another,
prefaced by a brief look at where we stand just now.
The Current Consensus Forecast
I carefully avoid putting myself into a position where, as a
policy maker, I would have to strive to validate my own public forecast.
Therefore, I am not going to offer any inside information or even my own
personal views in this presentation but simply my interpretation of what
the consensus of economic opinion seems to be about 1972 in light of the
initial regulations approved by the Price Commission and Pay Board. I
might note parenthetically, in defense of consensus economics, that the
consensus forecast for 1971 appears to have been excel!ent--very close for
total spending, but too low for price increases and therefore slightly too
high for real output and too low for unemployment.




-3-

We must recognize, of course, that the generalized consensus
forecast for 1972 is still in the process of development. The forecast
is tentative and may alter a good deal in the next 10 weeks. It cannot
take final form until the debate immediately following the submission by
the Administration of the 1972 Economic Report and 1973 budget. During
this period, both the overall forecast and its components are likely to
change.
The prevailing consensus predicts that in 1972 the current dol­
lar gross national production will average $90 to $100 billion more than
in 1971--a rise of roughly 9 per cent. Furthermore, about 6 of the 9 per
cent will come from higher real output and 3 per cent from price rises as
measured by the GNP price deflator. This two-thirds, one-third division
would almost reverse this year's experience, when, even with the price
freeze and NEP since August 15, over 60 per cent of spending has been
dissipated on higher prices.
Given conditions expected at the start of 1972, a 6 per cent
growth in real output would translate roughly into a 5-1/2 to 5-3/4 per
cent average rate of unemployment for the year. Unemployment does not
decline by the same percentage as output rises because the labor force
increases and because greater productivity raises the amount produced
with a given labor force. The rate of increase in productivity, there­
fore, influences the level of unemployment as does the number who, having
left the labor market because of a lack of jobs, return as output expands.
Those who are both optimistic with respect to productivity and pessimistic
with respect to the extent of current hidden unemployment foresee higher
unemployment rates than do their opposites. In either case, by the end
of 1972, both unemployment and price increases are expected to be below
their yearly averages.
The Major Demand Assumptions
For the expected growth in production to occur, some parts of
the economy must step up their spending. Where does the consensus see
the newly generated (exogenous) spending coming from to trigger the ex­
pected expansion in growth?
—

Consumer durables. The major assumption is that new cars will
continue to sell at rates close to recent levels. Sales of
other consumer durables are also expected to be strong, aided
by new housing production.

—

Housing. Few predict a higher rate of housing starts next
year than in the last half of 1971. Most predict a small
decline. Still, expenditures on housing construction should




-4-

be higher. Housing construction at the start of a year is
related to the starts in the last half of the previous year.
Starts in the last half of 1971 are running nearly a third
above last year.
—

Government spending. While Federal fiscal policy has not been
specified for next year, most economists expect a somewhat
larger actual deficit and a movement of the high employment
budget from minor surplus to minor deficit. At the same time,
state and local expenditures are assumed to grow somewhat faster
than recently, moving closer to the average rate of increase of
the past few years.

These generating forces together are assumed to lift spending by
about $35 to $40 billion with governments furnishing more than half of
this total. Of all the above assumptions, that for the level of spending
on consumer durables is most critical and least certain.
Other assumptions (also far from certain) concern the reaction
of business to the New Economic Programs.
—

Investment on plant and equipment. Because of the reinstated
investment tax credit and somewhat greater confidence, business­
men, it is assumed, will increase their expenditures on plant
modernization. In addition, plant expansion will occur in
certain spheres despite an overall excess of capacity.

—

Inventory investment. More importantly, it is assumed that
investment in business inventories will rise towards more
traditional levels in relation to sales. Inventory investment
is the most volatile of spending streams. Levels have been
low for the past two years (although never reaching previous
recession minimums). If increased confidence augments the
need for higher inventories created by higher output» inventory
investment should increase considerably.

The consensus believes that the two sources of business invest­
ment together should expand demand by $15 billion.
Finally, the new jobs and additional wages created by this addi­
tional spending should induce other expenditures. Consumers would spend
more on nondurable goods and services. Such spending expansion should
parallel the rate of increase in income. When this new consumption is
added to the previous figures, the total increase in spending would be
$90 to $100 billion above 1971.




-5-

The Division of Spending Between Output and Prices
There is a good deal less agreement among economists as to how
much of the expected increase 'in spending in 1972 will be translated into
effective demand for increased output and how much will simply cover rising
prices. For this analysis, two major givens are the 5.5 per cent pay
standard maximum and the 2.5 per cent price standard. Questions concern
the logic of their relationships, their equity, and the extent to which
they will be enforced. How closely will actual average compensation and
average price increases compare with the standards?
Actual compensation will, of course, differ from the 5.5 per cent
wage standard. Some wages and benefits will rise less than the standard,
either because they moved more rapidly than normal in recent years, or
because they are in industries with below-normal productivity gains, or
with wage-earners in a weak bargaining position. Others will move more
than the standard, because of existing contracts or equity catch-up con­
siderations. In addition, average compensation will rise because a higher
share of increasing production is likely to be in higner-wage industries
and because some overtime will be added.
A second critical question is the impact of increases in pro­
duction on productivity. In past recoveries from recession, increases in
productivity have greatly exceeded the long-run trend. Unchanged wage
and salary costs are spread over more units of production, while addi­
tional labor is used more efficiently. With this record, estimates of
increases in output per manhour for 1972 range between 3.3 and 3.8 per
cent, compared to a norm of 2.5 to 3.0 per cent. The consensus probably
falls at 3.5 per cent. This assumes that some of the low productivity
gains of the past few years will be made up.
The consensus forecast assumes a rise in profits in 1972 of 15
to 20 per cent. This would make profits' share of income about the same
as in 1969, but a good deal less than in prior years. Because profits
are a residual influenced by all sorts of diverse factors, they are ex­
tremely hard to predict. They depend on the accuracy of all the other
assumptions as well as on how effective a job each firm performs. So far
this year, the rapid rise in corporate profits has carried them to previous
highs in dollar amounts although as a percent of GNP and of sales they
remain low compared to past periods.
A general view would seem to be that'the 5.5 per cent wage
standard may translate into a 6 per cent rise in actual compensation.
If compensation rises by 6 per cent and output per manhour by 3.5 per cent,
then unit labor costs would increase by 2.5 per cent. This undergirds
the logic of a 2.5 per cent price standard, together with higher profits.




-6 -

The fact that prices rise on the average by the same amount as
unit labor costs--2.5 per cent each--does not, of course, mean that profits
cannot rise. As production rises there are normally two sources of addi­
tional profits. Even with the same profit per unit, each additional unit
sold adds to the profit total. Furthermore, profit per unit should rise.
Some additional production can take place without adding to plant or other
overhead. Thus, total cost per unit falls. The price standards apparently
attempt to insure that some of the profits from this second source are
utilized to cover added costs of labor and materials.
Spending, Prices, and Production
Having examined the various parts of the consensus forecast and
stated the basic assumptions of a 9 per cent increase in spending divided
6 per cent to output and 3 to price, we may check its internal consistency
through the relationships among the five P's. To what extent the increase
in spending calls forth new production or covers price rises, depends on
the effectiveness of policies influencing prices and pay and on the rate
of growth of productivity.
Let us therefore re-examine the assumptions and their relation­
ships.




—

Pay. Let it be assumed that the 5.5 per cent pay standard is
maintained firmly. Compensation per manhour would rise by
6 per cent, or slightly faster than wage rates.

—

Productivity. Increasing output plus the drive of firms to
improve operations and control costs lead to a 3.5 per cent
increase in productivity.

—

Prices. A 6 per cent increase in compensation per manhour,
less a 3.5 per cent increase in productivity, means that unit
labor costs rise by 2.5 per cent. The GNP price deflator will
rise somewhat faster than unit prices because no productivity
increases are allowed for governments and because of other
index number problems. Thus, a price standard of 2.5 per cent
on average is compatible with a 3 per cent increase in the GNP
deflator.

—

Profits. If prices and unit labor costs were to rise to the
same degree and real output rose by 6 per cent, profits would
rise rapidly. The price standards appear to call for prices
rising somewhat less than costs. Still the rise in output
would bring record total profits sufficient to insure that the
initial spending forecast for 1972 can prevail. Profit margins,
however, would still be below most prior recoveries.

-7-

—

Production. If spending rises by 9 per cent and prices by
3 per cent, then real output would rise by 6 per cent, completing
the logical circle.

Clearly, the fact that the consensus forecast is internally con­
sistent does not guarantee that it will be correct. Its accuracy depends
upon a long list of assumptions many of which may turn out to be wrong.
However, as new information unfolds, each of us can use these
internal links among the five P's to alter any of the assumptions and
thereby to arrive at new projections.
Money and Credit
Finally, I suppose it is only proper that I not neglect the
implications of this forecast--which I stress is my reading of the con­
sensus, not my own forecast--in the monetary and credit field. Given the
consensus assumptions and the goals of overall policy for achieving greater
output and less inflation with equity, what monetary and credit conditions
appear compatible?
Three rather distinct approaches currently are being used in
attempts to analyze this problem. The first looks primarily at money.
It asks, given the probable demand for money, if spending increases 9 per
cent, what monetary supply would be necessary to maintain interest rates
at or below the 1971 levels? Is such a supply compatible with the general
goals?
A second approach asks what are the expected changes in saving
and investment given the projected chances in spending? Are these com­
patible with current interest rates?
A third approach concerns the supply and demand situation in
financial markets. It asks whether shifts among various groups who borrow
or supply credit are likely to lead to changes in interest rates.
At the moment, the consensus seems to agree that none of the
three approaches need result in an excess demand for money and credit.
In the monetary sphere, the assumptions are not incompatible with the
goals of current policy.
Money supply. When past relationships between growth in money
and spending are compared to the desired increase in spending for next
year of at least 9 per cent, it appears that--whether on a naive basis of
velocity and spending trends in the past five years, or through more com­
plicated econometric models--the increased demand for money (Mi) should
rise by at least 7 to 9 per cent in 1972, while the increased demand for




-8-

money (M2 ) should rise by 9 to 14 per cent. Since monetary relationships
are actually more complicated than most simple monetary models suggest,
this predicted demand should be adjusted to account for movements in in­
terest rates and in price expectations. The net effect of such adjustments
would probably be to lower the demand estimates somewhat.
As a result, the consensus analysis appears to predict a need
in 1972 for growth in M] of 6 to 8 per cent and in M2 of 7 to 12 per cent
to meet the basic goals of the NEP. No part of these ranges seems to
create any basic problem for monetary policy or the money supply.
Savings and investment. Similar conclusions arise from an analy­
sis of savings and investment. From this point of view, one must ask,
does the consensus forecast contain such sharp movements in investment,
the government deficit, or personal saving as to indicate a need for higher
interest rates so as to bring the separate schedules into equilibrium?
The answer seems to be "no."
Personal and business saving this year are expected to total
about $175 billion. In 1971, sharp increases in housing investment and
the Federal deficit have been accompanied by below normal increases in
business investment. The moderate increase in total investment has been
matched by large increases in personal saving.
Under the consensus forecast, business investment will rise
faster next year, but the increases in housing and the government deficit
will be smaller than this year. Corporate profits will rise very rapidly.
The 4 per cent dividend restriction will insure that most of this increase
is saved. At the same time, personal savings and depreciation allowances
will grow somewhat more slowly. Again, however, expected changes are not
large compared to total savings and investment. The consensus sees no
problem of an excess demand for investment which would require sharp changes
in interest rates.
Supply and Demand in Money Markets. The markets finance a great
deal more than current investment. Firms borrow to increase their liquid­
ity. Others shift their financing from banks to other lenders. Treasury
bills held as monetary reserves of foreign central banks may be sold if
private holders transfer funds back to the U.S. The Treasury may alter
the length of its debt structure. Families may refinance mortgages or
borrow to buy existing structures. Any or all of these shifts can cause
movements in individual interest rates. These may in turn raise or lower
the entire structure of rates.




-9-

Again, when one examines the list of changes in the financing
structure that is implied by the consensus forecast, they seem to be those
which a system with a growing stock of money and savings should be able to
handle without much difficulty. Many believe that corporations have re­
structured their liabilities to such an extent that long-term corporate
debt will rise less next year than it did this year. Corporate saving with
higher profits and limited dividends should expand at least as much as new
investment. The housing market will seek more funds for new construction,
but the big shifts have occurred in mortgages for sales and refinancing of
existing structures. Since those who receive these funds must in turn
place them elsewhere, any problem would arise only if they placed their
receipts outside the usual rechanneling institutions.
A concern has been raised over the fact that a large share of
this year's large Treasury deficit has been financed primarily by increases
in foreign central bank holdings of U.S. Government securities, and that
these flows might reverse. This year's inflow did raise the demand for
short-term bills and as a result they are selling at relatively lower rates
than other money market instruments. A reversal of this year's flows would
cause a reversal in rate relationships between bills and other short-term
instruments but the difference would not seem great enough to cause any
major disruption.
On the whole, the total volume of funds raised next year should
increase but probably not by as much as either income or savings. This
year funds have been adequate. The financing "residual" implicit in the
consensus forecast for next year appears to be well within a range which
past experience suggests can be handled without a substantially different
interest rate structure.
Conclusion
The goals of policy now being initiated, as generally understood,
then, would appear to be in themselves internally consistent, and to be
realizable without placing undue strain upon the money markets or monetary
policy. All this, however, I would repeat, hangs upon a single assumption.
This is, that the goals of policy as now stated will remain our national
goals, that they will not be eroded or jostled out of their present harmony
and general practicability.
Is that a good assumption? This is the most important question
of all, because all other assumptions fall if this one gives way underneath
them.
I will try to answer, not in terms of a prediction, but in terms
of possibilities.




-1 0 -

First, I think we should all be clear beyond any possible doubt
that the goals of the New Economic Policy cannot be "enforced." Every
experience we have ever had in this country, and every comparable experi­
ence I know of elsewhere, shows that whatever plans of economic policy
human ingenuity can envision, and whatever schemes of enforcement can be
devised, other human minds are ingenious enough to get around, overturn,
and defeat them in short order, if those bent upon their destruction have
the support of public opinion.
Second, it should be equally clear that there is a corollary to
this: To have not only economic growtn but also economic balance and
order, we, as a people, must desire such results. If we do, we can suc­
cessfully create economic policies to achieve these desires.
The fact that no far-flung bureaucracy is being recruited to
"enforce" the controls and guidelines that are now our economic parameters
should not be alarming. If such a bureaucracy is needed the policies it
comes on to enforce cannot succeed; for those policies to succeed, only
enough of a bureaucracy is needed to devise reasonably equitable rules of
the game, keep them current, and explain them.
We can conclude, then, that it is possible for the New Economic
Policy to succeed.
Whether it will in fact succeed would seem to boil down to a
single question: Are the rules of the game now being handed down and put
into practice, sufficiently equitable to inspire a general desire among
us for them to succeed, or, if not so at first blush, do we have the will
to alter them in ways that will put the great power of public desire be­
hind them?
Once again, I would answer in terms of possibilities, and, in
those terms, the answer is certainly "yes." It is possible for us to
devise and hold to a pattern of economic good behavior that will unite us
generally in the conclusion that growth without corrosive inflation is the
most desirable type of growth. From such a pattern, each of us can bene­
fit most both in output and jobs and in equity. If we are convinced of
this, it will be very hard to keep us from succeeding in our aims.
This requires, not that any of us sacrifice our identities, our
expertise, or our belief that our own point of view--as farmers, profes­
sionals, public servants, businessmen, labor organized or independent, and
on down the corridors of our many ways of 1ife--is valid. Success requires
only that we do not consider our own view the only valid one, that we hold
fast to the principle, which is perhaps more typically American than any
other, and that I have already mentioned: those policies are best for
each of us that are best for all of us.




-1 1 -

The views of management and of organized labor, their interests,
and their differences are, as I have noted, genuine and important. But
their aims can be achieved only in the context of an economy that gives
due regard to the relationships of all five of the fundamental variables
I have stressed: Production, Prices, Pay, Productivity, and Profits.
A balance among these factors is the basis of national economic success,
and understanding of how they relate to one another is fundamental to
achieving our goals.




-0O0-