View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOR RELEASE
Friday, February 16, 1968
Approximately 4 P.M., EST




MONEY AND INCOME

Remarks of

SHERMAN J. MAISEL
Member
Board of Governors
of the
Federal Reserve System

at the

Faculty and Graduate Students Colloquium
sponsored by the
Graduate Economics Club
Yale University

New Haven, Connecticut
February 16, 1968

MONEY AND INCOME

Few things fascinate mankind as much as money.

And one thing

that seems almost invariably true is that, at least from the standpoint
of the individual, the supply of money is seldom as plentiful as the supply
of theories about it.

Since even a simple theory may give significant

insights into the workings of the econorny and of the monetary system, it
has been beneficial to have so many.

I hope we will never cease to have

new theories nor tire of examining the old ones along with the new.
In the course of these examinations, however, we ought to remember
the warning given every beginning student of economics:

stay on guard

against oversimplification, especially when it is proposed that a theory
be used as the basis for determining a policy that is to be applied in
practice.
For purposes of study, in furtherance of the understanding of
particular processes, oversimplification may be positively helpful--as
when we assume "all other things remain unchanged," even though in fact
they do not.
For policy purposes, however, particular theories may have marked
deficiencies.
short.

They may apply only in the long run, and not at all in the

They may describe mainly underlying tendencies and touch upon only

a segment of reality.

When used for policy proposals without these factors

being taken into account, they may lead to prescriptions that would do more
harm than good.




-2-

Economic history is full of theories that have attempted to prove
that if the supply of money or credit could be made to behave in accordance
with certain simple criteria, nearly all economic problems would be solved.
Since scarcely anything could be more attractive or convenient, it is not
surprising that the perennial search for such single, simple solutions is
still in progress--and perhaps in full cry, to judge by the samples carried
daily in the press of simplistic monetary proposals or policies advocated
by some of our most eminent professional economists, by generally wellinformed political leaders, and by well-trained financial writers.
Today I would like to discuss some of the reasons why I think
that theories that accept or overemphasize (in my judgment) the money supply
as the major determinant of income would serve poorly as the basis for
formulating monetary policy, in contrast to those that stress the need to
consider the interactions of non-monetary together with all monetary causes
of shifts in income and spending.
For ease of exposition, I will use the terms "money supply theory"
or "money supply only" for propositions that put most stress on changes in
the money supply as the prime determinant of economic activity, and "moneyincome-expenditure" theory for those which stress the need to look at a
broader list of variables.

(While I have gone over the literature carefully

and have tried to be representative in statements of views, an individual
believer in either theory may well object that his views are not fairly
represented.




Almost anybody who has written in either area could almost

-3-

certainly come up with past statements that would enable him to disavow
the theories as they are presented here.)
Briefly I feel the analysis leads me at least to conclude that
while important contributions have been made to show that "money does
matter," this is far from the conclusion and it leads to entirely different
policy prescriptions from claims that "only money matters."

The belief that

control of the money supply would be the most efficient type of governmental
economic policy is not supported by either the facts or theory.

It pays

too little attention to the basic non-monetary causes of instability and
to changes in the demand for liquidity.
Because our economic system is complex, we need complex theories
to analyze it.

We must take into account changes in demand whether they

come from government spending, from psychological factors, from endogenous
cycles, from the money supply, from shifts in liquidity preferences or
innumerable other forces.

By considering a large number of variables which

alter income, employment, and prices, we can explain and predict what is
happening to the economy.

Based on this knowledge, a flexible monetary

and fiscal policy can be more efficient than a single variable policy in
reducing the amount of instability and increasing the growth rate of the
economy.




-4-

Velocit.y and Interest Rates
Before taking up some rather faulty assumptions upon which the
money supply theory seems to me to rest, I'd like to absolve the theory of
one such assumption that j_s, however, embraced in the associated policy
prescription of a constant growth in the money supply.
of a stable link between money and income.

That is the assumption

Stress is placed in the pre­

scription not the theory on the stable long-run relationship between income
and changes in money.

Price and interest impacts on money demand under

normal circumstances are said to be slight.

While the velocity of money

admittedly fluctuates in the short run, emphasis is on its stability over
the long run.
It is this assumption that allows the relationship to be turned
on its head.

Money can be thought of as the tail which wags the dog.

is exogenously determined by the Federal Reserve System.

Money

To make the public

willing to hold the money stock, income must adjust to the level of money.
This leads to the concept that if money grows at a constant rate, income
will also grow at a constant rate.

Discretionary monetary policy should

be replaced by one based on a more or less constant growth in the money
supply.
The theory itself points out that the demand for money depends
upon interest rates as well as upon income.

As a result, adjustments to

changes in either the supply of money or the desire to spend can occur by
alterations in interest rates and in the velocity of money.
for money changes with interest rates.
alter interest rates, not income.




The demand

A change in the supply of money may

-5-

Thus, the direct causal link between money and income is broken.
An excess of money over the demand for it may cause people to buy bonds
in place of, or in addition to, commodities.
goods may similarly raise interest rates.

A rise in the demand for

A given supply of money may not

halt the expansion of demand from non-monetary sources.

It may support a

higher income level by turning over more rapidly.
It is, of course, true that there is a way in which changes in
bond prices and in velocities may affect spending.

An excess of money

holdings may be passed on through successive portfolios via shifts in yields
on assets.

People and institutions see short-term gains in selling bonds

at high prices.

As one does so after another, the outcome eventually will

be more spending, but how much more cannot be foreseen.

How high a degree

of leverage the money stock can exert on income, particularly in any short
or intermediate period, is questionable.
While avoiding this error of which they are at times accused, the
"money supply only" theories do seem to me to neglect, ignore, or dismiss
as insignificant a number of other highly important points.
Non-Monetar.y Causes of Spending Shifts
One is the effect on the economy of changes in spending caused
by wars, changes in the size and composition of the population, alterations
in technology, government programs, the expected return on capital, and
shifts in exports.

The impact on income may become cumulative through

operation of the multiplier-acceleration process as well as through the




-6-

effects produced by changes in expectations.

Progress and growth can lead,

and have led, to destabilizing movements in demand.

Furthermore, there is

no obvious force in the economy which would prevent these movements from
becoming explosive in either direction.
Monetary factors may, of course, interact with these other changes.
If there are changes in the rate or level of spending, and the money supply
cannot adjust, changes will be produced in interest rates, bond prices,
and wealth.

These changes will react in turn upon future expenditures.

Those who stress non-monetary causes of instability believe that purely
monetary reactions arising from a stable money supply will be too slow,
and perhaps too weak, to offset the instability arising from non-monetary
causes.

Velocities will shift; interest rates alter; desires for liquidity

will change.

Because monetary influences are felt with a lag, immediate

market reactions to non-monetary developments can increase rather than
offset instability.
Market Imperfections May Raise the
Costs of Monetary Movements_____
Another matter the money-supply theory appears to neglect (or
assume away) is the problem of sectoral adjustments to monetary changes.
It is well established that monetary changes have a differing impact on
sectors of the economy.

Yet the theory assumes that shifts in demand as a

result of changes in interest rates or in the availability of credit will
either be smooth or not excessively inefficient.

In contrast, the money-

income-expenditure approach points out the degree to which laws, rules,




-7-

regulations, market institutions, and market imperfections influence income,
and to the extremely uneven adjustments to which these factors may lead.
These uneven adjustments may in turn bring about unexpected results with
heavy costs.
In constructing a theory simply to aid in understanding, as I
noted at the outset, it may be proper to disregard the legal and institu­
tional structure of the economy in order to study basic tendencies.

In

formulating policy, however, the economy's true reactions cannot be treated
so cavalierly.

Analysis for policy must consider the channels through

which economic forces move.
theoretical assumptions.

Policies do not sail the smooth seas of

They must steer their course among the rocks and

shoals of laws and institutions.
Money supply theorists assume perfection in the working of credit
markets, though perfection is as rare in markets as in life.

The imperfections

that characterize markets in practice serve in fact to reallocate credit
with seriously destabilizing results.

If each sector of the economy had

equal access to all capital markets--as it does not--everything would work
through the price mechanism and allocational goals would be well served.
If markets were truly impersonal--as they are not--those with the projects
promising the best return would be the ones to get the credit.

But the

truth is that forces other than prices play major roles in the market
place.




When credit is tight (loanable funds are scarce in relation to
demand in the economy), this becomes glaringly apparent.

For example,

there is really little in a long-standing customer relationship to tell
a bank that a prime depositor has a particularly meritorious project.

Yet,

at times of credit stringency, he is given credit on favorable terms while
other applicants with excellent projects are rationed out of the market
for considerations that are perfectly logical to the bank.

If markets

functioned with perfect economic efficiency, this would not happen.
For the economy in general, the most important effect of high
interest rates has been to restrict the flow of funds to the housing market
as the bond market has attracted funds that in other times were deposited
in mortgage lending institutions (due to legal interest rate constraints
and the slow turnover of assets at these institutions).
Because real resources move slowly, this failure of credit to
flow to its most efficient point constitutes an important stabilization
problem.

It is difficult to move labor geographically or to retrain a

plumber to be an engineer.

Also, unions can halt entry of new labor into

the market just as monopoly and oligopoly halt entry of new businesses.
Given this lack of real factor mobility, a temporary shift of credit may
cause structural unemployment.

It also may in the case of housing lead to

an inflationary rise in rents and the cost of living if the supply of
residences lags demand.
enough time.

It may be true that the resources would move given

But the length of time required is much longer than is

practical for the business cycle, and the reallocation is neither perfect




-9-

nor cheaply accomplished.

Nobody suggesting specific policy proposals

today can responsibly ignore these imperfections.
Fiscal Policy Is not Insignificant
Also ignored, neglected, or downplayed by faithful adherents to
the money supply theory is the extremely significant role the government's
expenditures and its deficit may play in determining the course of economic
and financial developments.

The expansion in expenditures caused by the

war in Viet Nam has had major impacts on our economy in recent years.

Wars

can cause major changes in income irrespective of how they are financed.
But the ease and efficiency with which resources are shifted to the war
effort is not independent of tax policy and how the war debt is financed.
To prove that a money creation rule could take the place of
fiscal and debt management policy, one must show that by maintaining a
constant growth in the money supply changes in other policies would be
reduced to insignificance.
is true.

But most economists agree that the opposite

Tax and debt policy can create a more efficient system of trans­

ferring resources.

The level of demand is not dependent entirely on the

money supply and independent of the method of financing.

Financing through

borrowing rather than through taxing may cause significant structural
changes.

Most experience indicates that the level of production and the

amount of resources available for the war can be influenced by fiscal and
debt policy.

Who pays for the war and how income is redistributed also

would be different under a system which used money supply as the key policy
variable.




-

10 -

In order to ignore the question of whether goods and services
are purchased by the government or private spenders, one must assume that
borrowing to reallocate resources is an efficient way of reallocating them.
In addition, aggregate demand must not increase.
If the government spends the proceeds of its bond issue on real
resources while only part of the funds come from household demand for real
resources the latter is not true.
taxed has his wealth reduced.

If funds are raised by taxes, the person

The reduced wealth makes it difficult for

the taxpayer to borrow to augment his income.

It appears that a person

who turns in more money in taxes reduces his consumption by more than one
who turns in this same additional amount to pay for a bond.

A change in

income or wealth produced by governmental expenditures may alter spending
even if the supply of money is unchanged.
Since the pattern of government demand differs so much from that
of household demand, an increase in governmental expenditures requires a
major shift of resources.

When the government borrows heavily to pay for

its expenditures, bond rates may be pushed up enough to cause major
alterations in the flow of funds.
while others are fully supplied.

Some users of credit may get more,
In general, the lack of mobility of

factors of production limits the effectiveness of high interest rates in
reallocating resources.

The impediments to accomplishment of such shifts

in terms of rigidities, bottlenecks, etc. are significant and cannot be
ignored.

A tax program may be far more efficient in freeing the type of

resources required and in insuring that no large quantities of resources
lack demand.




-11-

Shifts in the Demand for Money
As economists we recognize that market equilibria can be altered
by a shift in either supply or demand.
constant supply, demand must not shift.

For stability to result from a
This, however, doesn't appear to

be the case of the demand for money and credit.
shifted rapidly.

Desires for liquidity have

We have just experienced such a major shift.

In addition,

expectations about future profits also may move rapidly.
Unless we can raise the cost of capital relative to expectations
about future profits, we cannot slow the boom without causing grave structural
disorders.

There are situations in which expectations are even destabilizing

for the system.

An expected price inflation feeds itself by encouraging

people to buy goods and to draw down money balances.

This sort of expecta­

tion may not be amenable to a rule about the rate of growth of money.
Some expectations about returns on capital may be stabilizing
after awhile, but there is little guarantee that the short-run problem will
be costless.

A sharp reduction in expected return on capital may cause

major disruptions.

For stability, the use of fiscal policy or discretionary

monetary policy may be quite necessary in such a situation.

Similarly, if

expected returns promise to outpace the cost of capital, especially as in
a situation where business firms are particularly liquid, fiscal policy or
discretionary monetary policy may be needed to dampen the elements giving
rise to those expectations.

In neither case should the money supply con­

tinue to expand at a constant rate.

For it to do so would in the former

case not make it easy enough for people to borrow; in the latter case it
would make it too easy.




-12-

Mhat Is Meant by the Supply of Money?
The concept of the money supply is far more complex than it
sometimes appears.

Major differences in policy suggestions may follow

from how the "money supply" is defined.
There are at least four different versions of what the money
supply is.

While the movements of the money supply in all four versions

are related, the growth rates of the respective "supplies" may differ
greatly over periods of a quarter or even a year.

Whether or not these

differences are significant and which versions of the money supply should
be considered as a primary index for policy depends upon one's complete
theory.
Sometimes money supply theorists talk as if currency in circu­
lation and private demand deposits were all that mattered.

At other times,

they add private time deposits to get a larger version of the money supply.
Movements of these two "money supplies" differ considerably.

Because the

government's cash balance is large and it rises and falls rapidly as the
government takes in receipts and pays its bills, time and demand deposits
also grow at a rate different from total commercial bank deposits.

The

behavior of total deposits of commercial banks in turn may differ con­
siderably from those of savings banks and savings and loan associations.
Although some slippage exists, the total most directly affected
by Federal Reserve operations is that of commercial bank deposits.

Yet

the total that seems to fit most theories best is total deposits of all
institutions.




Moreover, even with a constant level of deposits,

-13-

significant effects may result from alterations in the equal but opposite
side of the balance sheet--loans and investments.

There are many cases

where the person to whom bank credit is loaned will influence the total
amount of spending.

To find these effects, we must look at bank loans and

assets as well as the money supply.
A policy that recommends strict control of a particular monetary
total must properly define the total to be controlled.

The recommendation

could apply to anything from free reserves to all financial assets.
operational, two characteristics must prevail.

To be

First, the target total

must be under the control of the Federal Reserve.

Second, the relationship

between the targeted variable and spending must be clearly defined.

A

choice then depends on both practice and theory.
The one thing that the Federal Reserve can control precisely is
the volume of bonds in its portfolio.

Although total non-borrowed reserves

--those made available through purchases of government securities in the
open market--are also within the reach of the Federal Reserve fairly con­
stantly, the money supply, in contrast, is the result of interactions of
the banks, the public, and the Federal Reserve.

In general, the further

you get from a definition of the targeted variable in terms of open market
operations the more difficult it becomes to determine how Federal Reserve
policy will affect it.

Depending on the definition of money used, the

total supply of it may be affected by public substitution between demand
and time deposits, by shifts from public to private deposits, and by
switches to bank deposits from other financial assets.




-14-

If control over the total money supply is all that is needed,
as the money supply theorists suppose it to be, the composition of the
total must be of no consequence.

But if the total alone is important,

there must be some unifying purpose in holding all the assets included in
the total.
actions.

If time deposits are included, the motive cannot be trans­
It must have to do with liquidity or some other measure.

If the

measure were broadened so that all interest rate effects were internalized,
the relationship to income might be more stable.

But broadening theory to

such a measure is to eliminate the control of the Federal Reserve.
Statistical Studies
At times over-exuberant believers in the money supply theory seem
to be stating that there is little use quibbling over the theory because
the facts have been proved statistically, and that, there is an empirical
if not necessarily a theoretically valid law justifying the policy of
constant growth of money supply.

When we examine all the many studies in

this sphere and the relevant debates, it becomes clear that no such
certainty exists.
We face, of course, the typical problem of drawing conclusions
about an extremely complex system from partial statistics.

Looking at

post-Korean data, we can correlate about half of quarterly changes in the
GNP with changes in various definitions of the money stock.
bank deposits or credit seem to do best.)

(Total member

The models giving such

correlations contain lagged distributions for three to five quarters.




-15-

Similarly, we find sets of expenditure variables which give equivalent
results.

In each case, we must still look to other factors to account for

the majority of changes that have occurred.

This can be done with more

complete models such as have been constructed at the Federal Reserve based
upon the money-expenditure-income theories.
Our problem is not merely that of looking at a bottle that is
half empty and also half full.

The problem is a good deal more complex.

In each case, we can by theoretical reasoning improve or dissipate the
initial statistical results.
to be too simple.

Most of the models used in such tests tend

As an example, some published studies have argued at

length over the use of claimed misuse of the concepts of "turning points"
to attempt to prove either theory.
A comparison of turning points in no way does justice to a model
in which various factors other than money affect GNP.

This is particularly

true when monetary policy is expected to offset part of the expansionary
force of autonomous expenditures or of a runaway in expected return on
capital.

The effectiveness of policy depends on the relative strengths of

the two opposing forces, not on the point in time when policy changes.

If

a strong expansionary policy action were to be coupled with a weak downward
movement in other forces, one would expect the policy's effect would be
more swiftly felt than if the other forces were moving down rapidly.

The

necessary ceteris paribus conditions are not represented in some of the
statistical work.




-16-

The fact that eminent scholars can draw different conclusions
from similar data is, of course, not surprising.
extremely complex matters.

We are dealing with

There are innumerable ways of specifying the

basic models as well as of fitting data.
purely by past statistical results.

No one can or should be convinced

One must be convinced by the underlying

theories and by the ability to use the concepts in arriving at useful
predictions and policy judgments.
Conclusion
My conclusion from this analysis is that a flexible package of
policies based on forecasting should not be replaced by a single policy.
As economists we must continue to examine theories new and old, but we
ought not, without greater cause than we have yet been shown, abandon the
system of analysis which looks at numerous variables and considers as
relevant for policy the entire broad structure of our economy.

It seems

to me, on the evidence to date, that no policy based only on the control
of the money supply will suffice.
While important contributions have been made to economic research
to show that "money does matter"

in determining the course of the economy,

that is a far different thing from claiming that "only money matters,"
and the policy prescription to which it leads is entirely different.
Policy based on a broader, more complete analysis should in my opinion
lead the economy to more success in achieving the goals set for it.




-17-

Our problem in trying to use the various instruments of monetary
policy to help steer the course of the economy to its goals— maximum
employment and steady economic growth with relatively stable prices--is
comparable to that of a bus driver trying to get to the top of a mountain.
If the road were completely straight with a constant slope, it might make
sense for him to lock his steering wheel in place and hold his accelerator
at a fixed level.

If, however, the mountain curves and changes its slope

rather frequently, nothing could be more disastrous than an attempt by the
driver to lock his steering gear in place and apply a constant flow of
gasoline.

He would be far more likely to reach his goal by using his

steering wheel, his brakes, and his accelerator to help adjust to the
variations in his road.
In like vein, it seems to me that the American economy is too
dynamic to achieve stability from a single policy rule such as "hold the
growth of the money supply constant."