View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY
Monday, November 23, 1970
Approximately 8 p.m. EST




MONETARY POLICY:

THE MONEY SUPPLY

Remarks of

SHERMAN J. MAISEL
Member
Board of Governors
of the
Federal Reserve System

at the
39th Annual Dinner Meeting
of the
Long Island Bankers Association
East Meadow, Long Island
New York
November 23, 1970

MONETARY POLICY:

THE MONEY SUPPLY

Daily I am surprised by the sweeping statements reported in the
press by economists, financial analysts, pundits, and others of what has
happened, is happening, or will happen to the money supply, and what the
results have been or will be on interest rates, jobs, prices, and the stock
market.
My surprise arises because so many of these statements accept as
facts what may be misconceptions, partially tested theories, errors, or
wishes. Common themes of many of these pronouncements are the large differ­
ences in gross national product, prices, and interest rates that will result
from rather small differences in the rate of growth of the money supply.
The magnitudes involved, and the implied cause-and-effect relationships are
frequently described with a confidence that rarely acknowledges the lack of
certainty surrounding these matters.
I should like to draw your attention today to some of the problems
involved in defining and measuring the money supply, and in interpreting
the implications of changes in its rate of growth. I would not go so far
as to point to the Bible and say that "the love of money is the root of all
evil," for many economists and others interested in monetary policy, but I
don't think it amiss to suggest that the love of money, to the exclusion
of some other important facts and uncertainties of economic life, can result
in incorrect and misleading conclusions.
Let me begin by making some statements which are in a considerably
different vein than many current comments.
First, there is no general agreement as to what the term
"money supply" means. Its meaning frequently varies with the
user.
Second, if one believes that changes in the "money supply"
cause movements in prices, output, and interest rates, and that
more or less fixed relationships exist between the changes in
money and the other quantities, then in recent months and years
different definitions of money would yield substantially dif­
ferent results.
Third, similarly, even with a single definition of the
money supply, predicted results can vary widely depending on
whether the estimates of money used are preliminary, revised,
or final and on the periods used for measuring changes.




-2 -

Fourth, how much the "money supply" changes in a month,
quarter, or year results from decisions of millions of separate
and independent units. The Federal Reserve's influence over the
money supply is indirect. The links between Federal Reserve
actions and the decisions of others to alter the money supply
are not fully understood. Estimates of how much the money sup­
ply will change in any period given a specific course of Federal
Reserve action have a considerable margin of error.
None of these four statements imply that monetary policy does not
have a considerable impact upon the economy. None imply that measures of
movements in various monetary aggregates or concepts of money are not use­
ful gauges for formulating or implementing monetary policy. There is almost
complete agreement that monetary policy does affect jobs, interest rates,
and prices.
What these statements do imply is that any simple assertions as
to how or to what extent current or lagged movements in the "money supply"
cause or may cause specific movements in the very complex economic and
financial world ought to be examined with care. An understanding of the
lack of accuracy in the data, theories, and analysis surrounding over­
simplified causal statements should lead to a better appreciation of possible
errors in the analysis of current and prospective movements in the economy.
Money supply is a helpful tool to use in guiding monetary policy.
However, like many useful but complicated tools, it has great potential for
being misused, to the discomfort of its practitioners, as well as the
economy.
The Money Supply and the Economy
Economists are in general agreement that output, jobs, prices,
and interest rates rise or fall in response to a wide variety of specific
forces. Included among the factors which can alter the pace of economic
activity are changes in the growth of the labor force, technological
developments, changes in wage rates, shifts in desires to save and invest,
changes in government taxes and expenditures, movements in money and credit,
as well as expectations of what will happen to all of these forces.
While some analysts put more stress on a particular set of factors,
few disagree that each of these forces has, at times, caused economic fluc­
tuations. Not many economists accept the idea that movements in the economy
can be described in simple terms or that one can predict accurately what
will happen over the next month, six months, or several years from movements
in a single variable such as the money supply. In fact, I know of no one
who has been able to predict successfully how the money supply will change
let alone how these changes will influence the major economic variables.




-3-

Yet as I read the daily and weekly press, see comments of experts
on money and stock prices, bond prices, or the economy, I fail to note the
same skepticism or agnosticism with respect to statements on these matters
that I find in the technical literature. Simplified statements about money
made to clarify examples or help in debates among theoreticians appear in
entirely new contexts. In their new habitat they are surrounded by far
more specificity and far fewer qualifications than in their original context.
Each further remove of such statements from their origin seems to increase
their certainty. That, in my judgment, decreases their likelihood of being
accurate descriptions of what is happening or is likely to happen in the
economy.
"The Money Supply"
Any article on money points out the diversity of elements that
have served as money in the past. As our financial system has grown in
complexity, the possible elements to include have expanded rapidly. Table I
shows a few of the most common definitions of money currently in use. In
magnitude the amounts they represent vary from the $48 billion of currency
in circulation to a total of $674 billion if we include as money currency
plus deposits at all financial institutions. Even this list leaves out
what many would think of as obvious candidates for inclusion such as money
orders, travelers checks, or debt created by the use of credit cards, which,
to an increasing extent, is being monetized.
What you call "money" really depends on who you are and what you
do. To the world's central banks, special drawing rights on the Inter­
national Monetary Fund are "a generally accepted means of payment"--but not
to any commercial bankers. Money can be one thing for a lawyer and another
thing for an economist.
According to one school of thought, definitions should not be
based on grounds of principle, but on grounds of usefulness in organizing
our knowledge of economic relations. Thus, we should define as "money"
that collection of private and public debt which yields the best predictions
of changes in prices and nominal income or GNP.
Unfortunately for this approach, it frequently turns out that
what seems like the best definition based on past periods does the poorest
job in predicting the future.
Because of failures and dissatisfaction with the purely empirical
approach to the definition of money, economics is full of theoretical debates
as to what should properly be considered as money. Because of the wellknown difficulties of any theory proving another wrong, these debates change
few allegiances when it comes to preferable definitions of the money supply.
Those who use the term "money supply" glibly are frequently unaware of or
unconcerned with these basic differences and the impact they can have on
current analysis.




-4-

Measurinq the Money Supply
In Table I, columns 2-4 give the rate of growth for each of
seven definitions of the money supply for the years 1967-1969. Columns 5-7
give the annual rates of growth for more recent periods.
You might expect that if the money supply described as demand
deposits and currency grows at, say, 5 per cent, other monetary aggregates
would also grow at or near 5 per cent. Columns 2-7 demonstrate that this
is simply not the case. In 1969, for example, while demand deposits and
currency were growing at an annual rate of 2.5 per cent, member bank deposits
were shrinking at an annual rate of -4.2 per cent.
Even if the rates of growth are not identical, however, one might
nevertheless assume that the relative rates of growth should be roughly
constant. For example, we might expect that the rate of growth of currency
in circulation should always bear some constant relationship to the rate of
growth of currency and demand deposits. But, as columns 8-13 demonstrate,
this also is not the case. When we look at year-to-year data, the rate of
growth of currency fluctuates from .83 to 2.32 times the rate of growth of
currency plus demand deposits. The similar ratios for currency, demand
deposits, and time deposits vary from -0.61 to 2.14 even though the narrower
concept makes up nearly half the second. The variance is even greater when
we look at shorter periods.
Obviously, if one thinks there are close and quite exact relation­
ships between changes in money and what happens in the economy— how one
defines money is extremely important. Any forecast based on one definition
of money will vary from one using another definition by the full amount of
the large differences in movements among the concepts of money shown in the
table.
The problems of measurement go far beyond the differences in
definition. They exist within each series. The figures one sees quoted as
to how the "money supply" grew over the past week, month, or quarter has an
error factor (RMS) of 50 per cent or more. Therefore what should be expected
to happen to some other magnitude if there were a direct causal relationship
would have this great an error also.
For example, consider the implications of the fact that differences
in the money supply as it was first reported for each week in 1967-69 and
as it was revised early this fall had a range of minus $1.4 billion to
plus $1.0 billion. The mean deviation was over $490 million. In 1969,
revisions of the estimated growth rate of the money supply in the first six
months amounted to over 100 per cent. The difference between one wellknown model's estimate during the period when monetary policy decisions had
to be made and that which the model predicted from the revised data of the




COMMONLY CITED MONETARY AGGREGATES:
RATES OF CHANGE AND RELATIVE RATES OF CHANGE,
DECEMBER 1966 - SEPTEMBER 1970
1

2

$
Bi11 ion
Out­
standing 19671/
9/70

3

4
5
6
Annual Rates of Change in Per Cent
19681/

19691/

12/699/70

5/707/70

7

|1 8
9
10
11
12
13
I Rates of Change Relative to Rate of Change
1
of Currency and Demand Deposits
!
5/7012/695/705/707/70
8/70 |l967l/ 19681/ 19691/
9/70
8/70
1
- .... j

1. Currency and
demand deposits

206.2

6.6

7.2

2.5

4.4

1.2

4.1

! 1.00

1.00

1.00

1.00

1.00

1.00

2. Currency, de­
mand deposits,
plus time dep.

423.2

14.1

6.5

-1.5

10.0

11.4

14.2

| 2.14

.90

- .61

2.27

9.50

3.46

!
3. (2), minus large ;
i
certificates of
13.2
deposit
401.8

6.0

1.8

6.7

7.2

8.3

l
! 2.00
i
j

.83

.72

1.52

6.00

2.02

.92

.89

1.24

1.45

2.42

1.22

¡1.79

1.25

-1.68

2.36

11.92

4.7G/

.......

4. Net monetary lia­
bilities of the
Treasury and
Federal Reserve
(monetary base)
5. Member bank
deposits
(credit proxy)
6. Currency in
ci rculation

82.2

6.1

6.4

3.1

6.4

2.9

5.0

308.0

11.8

9.0

-4.2

10.4

14.3

19.5

■ -..........

!

5.5

7.4

5.8

6.7

6.3

5.0

.83

1.03

2.32

1.51

5.25

1.22

i
7. Deposits at all
i
ii
i
financial insti.
I
plus currency
in circulation j 674.2 j 9.9

8.2

0.6

8.1

n.a.

n.a.

1.50

1.14

.24

1.84

n.a.

n.a.

.. --

..

- -

48.2

fi

■

—

l

!_/ Measured on a December-to-December basis.
n.a. - not available




i

cn
I

-6-

total monetary policy impact on GNP was nearly $10 billion. Such a magni­
tude, in many cases, would encompass the difference betwen an inflationary
and deflationary policy.
These revisions arise partly because preliminary data include a
large number of estimates. They also arise, however, from the fact that
the actual treatment by banks and other institutions of what is considered
money alters over time. When the new treatment becomes obvious, either the
definition must be changed or the series revised. As an example, most
definitions of the money supply include demand deposits at commercial banks
adjusted for certain factors. One of these factors is usually cash items
in the process of collection. But the tremendously heightened activity of
American banks abroad, plus the operations of their international subsidi­
aries such as Edge Act corporations, taken together with the activities of
foreign banks and agencies in our own domestic banking operations, added to the
ever-present ability of bankers to devise new techniques of making payments,
have resulted in considerable problems in estimating the amounts of cash
items considered to be in collection. Changes in regulations and the esti­
mates of these items result in significant differences in rates of monetary
growth.
These difficulties, plus the yearly changes resulting from reestimates of deposits at non-member banks and re-adjustments in the seasonal
factors which give us a seasonally adjusted money supply figure, should make
any commentator cautious. He who points to a particular number as repre­
senting "the" money supply at any given point in time, and who then makes
sweeping judgments about the direction of Federal Reserve policy and its
implications for the future is bound to find that frequently he has built
a fine analytical structure on shifting sands. After the next revision in
data, his theories and analysis may find their foundation surely shaken, if
not removed entirely. In fact, it is not at all uncommon to find that by
merely substituting later data in the analysis, conclusions drawn from earlier
data might be reversed.
The Usefulness of the Money Supply Concept
This critical view of what I believe to be uncritical uses of the
money supply concept is, of course, not new. I and many others have spoken
and written of this problem frequently in the past. I am, however, often
asked whether I don't see an inconsistency between these observations and
the fact that for the past five years I have even more frequently stressed
the need for the Federal Reserve to pay more attention in its policy formu­
lation and operations to changes in the money supply and monetary aggregates.
[The term "monetary aggregates" simply reflects the fact that the theoreti­
cal and operational concepts of the money supply are so inexact. If for
short-hand purposes one defines the money supply concept narrowly, one needs
a broader term, i.e., "monetary aggregates," to reflect the other and more
broadly based related concepts such as those shown in the table.]




-7-

The simple answer is, "No!" The Federal Reserve did in the past
pay too little attention to movements in the monetary aggregates. The in­
creased attention given to changes in the money supply have, in my judgment,
improved the System's responses. Critical to progress, however, has been
a recognition of the uncertainties in theory, in data, and in operations
which surround the concept of the money supply.. Past and future improve­
ments require that these uncertainties be explicitly taken into account and
not neglected or assumed away.
The Federal Reserve does influence the growth rate of money.
Through its direct impact on bank reserves, on interest rates, and on ex­
pectations, the Federal Reserve influences bank credit, currency, bank
deposits, bank and corporate liquidity, interest rates, and lending and
borrowing. These changes in money and credit have an impact on how much
the economy spends and on what.
This spending together with supply conditions--incl uding the price and wage actions of business, labor, and
governments--in turn influence prices and employment.
The chain of causation and the amount of the relationships between
Federal Reserve action and movements in money, in spending, prices, and
employment, may be hidden in the shadows and far from clear, but experience
shows that they do exist. This means that the Federal Reserve must manage
its operations with the greatest possible skill to avoid the type of dis­
asters which our and other economies have experienced too often in the past.
In formulating policy and conducting operations, paying greater
attention to the money supply has many advantages. When considered in con­
junction with movements in interest rates, sales, and output, attempts to
use the money supply as a guide or target require that greater attention
be paid to unexpected and undesired movements in the basic economy.
If operations are related to movements in the monetary aggregates,
the impact of unwanted movements in the economy which become reflected in
the demand for money and credit will not be allowed to lead automatically
to too much or too little expansion in reserves and money. Instead, if,
for example, real demand is falling, action to maintain the growth of the
monetary aggregates will cause a greater fall in interest rates than would
otherwise occur. This in turn will cause a counter-depressing improvement
in basic demand.
At a more technical level, operations related to the money supply
allow the Federal Reserve to focus more readily on the intermediate term
and the longer run or lagged effects of its actions. Even though in the
short run rates of change in the monetary aggregates may be extremely erratic,
for the longer period it appears to be simpler to construct probable rela­
tionships between movements in the aggregates and in spending than it is
using other monetary variables.




-8-

Conclus ion
Let me conclude by summarizing a more lengthy paper I have
written on this topic. To conduct monetary policy successfully, the
Federal Reserve must think in quantitative terms. It must be clear as
to where it wants to go and must specify how its actions are likely to
aid in reaching those goals. In formulating its plans for operations
the concept of the money supply serves a useful purpose.
At the same time, the Federal must take into account the great
uncertainty which surrounds this matter. We do not have a 100 per cent
accurate map of the critical relationships. We have only rough ideas as
to what will happen to the monetary aggregates when the Fed changes its
operations. We know even less about the relationships between changes in
money and changes in spending. At any time our monetary data, on which
operations must be based, have a high possibility of error. Finally, we
cannot be certain as to how the other major movers of the economy, such as
government, households, and businesses, will react in the period ahead.




This means that in operations we must:
—

Constantly struggle to improve our data and knowledge.

—

Take explicit account of the degree of uncertainty.

—

Consider in detail alternative policy paths and their
implications.

—

Enable non-quantitative and judgmental considerations
to influence decisions.

—

Remain flexible at any given time in the weight given
to a particular tool, theory, analytical concept, or
method of operation.