View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

The Recovery and Monetary Policy :: December 2, 2010 :: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
home | news & media | careers | site map

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OJ CLEVELAND
A bout U
Tours

For the Public

News & Media

Com munit y D e velopm ent

S tream ing Media

Forefront M agazine

Speakers Bureau

I Our IRegion

I Research

I Ban kin g

I Learning Centter

Savings Bonds

_________________ Home > For the Public > News and Media > Speeches > 2010 > The Recovery and Monetary Policy
D _ SH RRE

^

f ...

The Recovery and Monetary
Policy

Additional Information
Sandra Pianalto

Introduction
If you have been following the news, you are aware that the Federal
Reserve recently decided to purchase an additional $600 billion in
Treasury securities over the next six months. That decision has
received a lot of attention. Tonight, I’m going to explain why I
supported the decision to purchase additional Treasury securities.
To do that, I think it would help to provide some background and
context. So I will begin by briefly describing the issues we consider
when making monetary policy decisions. I will also talk about my
outlook on the economy. Finally, I’ll talk about why I decided that
purchasing additional Treasury securities was the right course of
action.

P resident and CEO,
Federal Reserve Bank o f Cleveland
Featured speaker for the Oberlin
College Department of Economics
Craig Hall, Oberlin College, Oberlin,
Ohio
December 2, 2010

Issues in Monetary Policy Decisions
Let me start with some background on the issues we consider when
making monetary policy decisions. I am a member of the Federal
Open Market Committee, or FOMC, the Federal Reserve’s
policymaking group. The FOMC consists of the members of the
Federal Reserve Board in Washington, DC, and the presidents of the
12 Federal Reserve Banks across the country. Congress has given the
Federal Reserve a dual mandate to conduct monetary policy in ways
that will promote price stability and maximum employment over
time.
So let’s look at the first half of the dual mandate—price stability.
Because Congress has not given us a numerical objective for inflation,
FOMC members have some latitude in selecting the inflation rate we
think is the most compatible with healthy economic growth over the
long run. The purchasing power of the dollar over time is determined
by the monetary policy decisions we make. Put more simply, inflation
is a monetary phenomenon.
Centuries of economic history have taught central bankers to avoid
both inflation and deflation. When the general level of prices
increases year after year, people come to expect their money to lose
its purchasing power, and they will tend not to make the best
spending and investing decisions. In particular, inflationary conditions
encourage people to borrow funds for speculation. They figure they
can just repay their loans with cheaper dollars in the future.
On the other hand, deflationary conditions discourage borrowing for
investment, since people believe that the debt they hold now will
become more expensive to service and repay. But that isn’t the only
danger of deflation. Once consumers start expecting price declines,
they will put off buying things until prices go down further. These

http://www.clevelandfed.org/For_the_Public/News_and_Media/Speeches/2010/Pianalto_20101202.cfm[4/29/2014 1:51:29 PM]

The Recovery and Monetary Policy :: December 2, 2010 :: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
price declines could lower sales, shrink profits, hold down wages, and
limit hiring. So inflation and deflation can each bring bad outcomes
and undermine healthy economic performance.
As a practical matter, FOMC members tend to think that inflation
over the longer run in the range of 1 / to 2 percent is most
compatible with healthy economic growth. My preference is to have
inflation average 2 percent over the longer term. If I lived in the
world of economic textbooks, I would choose zero inflation, but I
have chosen 2 percent to provide some room for measurement error
and to keep some distance from the perils of deflation. I’ll have
more to say about that risk later when I discuss the current policy
situation.
The other half of the Federal Reserve’s dual mandate, as I said, is
maximum employment, but we tend to think differently about a
working definition for this concept. That’s because the amount of
employment that equals “full employment” can vary over time due
to changes in a variety of areas like technology, business practices,
taxes, labor market regulations, and other public policies. As a
result, FOMC members estimate what level of employment our
economy is capable of sustaining, and we reassess these estimates
from time to time. At our last meeting in early November, most
FOMC members indicated that when our economy returns to full
employment, the unemployment rate would move back down to a
range of 5 to 6 percent.
Over the longer term, the FOMC is trying to achieve price stability
and maximum employment. So now let me explain how we decide
which policy actions are most likely to foster those outcomes.
The decisions the FOMC makes today have immediate effects on
financial markets, but their effect on output, employment, and
prices develops much more slowly, and begins to show up six to 18
months after a monetary policy decision. To do our jobs effectively,
then, we have to make forecasts. Each member of the FOMC
develops his or her own economic forecast using data, models, and
information we gather from talking to business and community
leaders. In fact, you may have seen coverage of a meeting I
moderated at The Ohio State University this week with Chairman
Bernanke, where we engaged a group of business leaders in a
discussion about labor markets.
All of this information—both hard data and real-time anecdotes—is
useful for the FOMC members as we develop our projections for the
economy under a variety of economic scenarios. At our meetings, we
debate the pros and cons of monetary policy options under these
scenarios—whether output is likely to be growing either faster or
slower in the months ahead.
Not surprisingly, FOMC members don’t always hold the same views.
But the forecasting process provides a structured way for us to
discuss the outlook and our policy options, and to reach decisions.
The Committee publishes a summary of our projections quarterly, and
many members discuss their views about the outlook at events and
forums such as this one here at Oberlin.
Since the outlook plays such a prominent role in the policy process, I
want to tell you what I see when I analyze the economic situation.

The State of the Recovery and My Outlook
Let me begin by telling you something you are already painfully
aware of—the economy has been through its worst recession since
the Great Depression in the 1930s. The downward spiral began with
the housing crisis, which led to the financial crisis. Financial markets

http://www.clevelandfed.org/For_the_Public/News_and_Media/Speeches/2010/Pianalto_20101202.cfm[4/29/2014 1:51:29 PM]

The Recovery and Monetary Policy :: December 2, 2010 :: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
froze, production collapsed, and employment plummeted.
The Federal Reserve responded aggressively and creatively to this
crisis. The FOMC quickly reduced short-term interest rates to near
zero and helped lower long-term rates by purchasing about $1.7
trillion worth of mortgage-backed securities, government agency
debt, and Treasury securities. I’m firmly convinced that these actions
helped us avoid the worst possible scenario: a repeat of the Great
Depression worldwide. Yet many challenges remain.
Today, the economy is growing and has officially emerged from the
recession, but I’m sure you would agree that this recovery just
doesn’t feel like much of a recovery. Here’s why: research shows that
when recessions are preceded by financial crises, the downturn is
more severe and the recovery period takes longer than normal. In
fact, this has been the slowest economic recovery w e’ve experienced
in the post-World War II era, and the remnants of the financial crisis
are still holding back economic progress.1 Households have become
more cautious in this environment. Consumers have sharply cut back
on spending, and they continue to reduce their debt and save more.
And, of course, housing markets remain stressed. Finally, in the face
of weak demand, companies are still hesitant about adding people
back onto their payrolls.
Although the economy is growing, it is still digging itself out of a deep
hole. In fact, based on real GDP estimates that were revised in July,
we now know that output growth for 2007, 2008 and last year was
actually worse than previously reported. In other words, the economy
began its recovery deeper in the hole—and has more ground to make
up—than everyone thought earlier this year.
Nowhere is the depth of this hole more evident than in labor
markets. Right now, nearly 15 million Americans are unemployed, and
the unemployment rate stands at 9.6 percent. While it was
encouraging to hear that the economy added another 150,000 jobs in
October, we still have a long way to go just to reach 2007
employment levels. In normal times, about 150,000 new workers
enter the labor force every month. That means to even start making
a serious dent in the unemployment rate, we would need to add
substantially more than 150,000 jobs every month.
Troubling as these numbers are, what is even more troubling is how
long people are remaining out of work. About half the people who
are unemployed have been out of work for at least six months. In
another severe recession, back in 1982, the average duration of
unemployment peaked at 21 weeks, but today the average duration is
34 weeks.
These long spells of unemployment can lead to some unfortunate
consequences. Labor economists have repeatedly shown that the
longer people are out of work, the harder it is for them to find jobs.
And for some who are unemployed for a long time, when they finally
do return to work, they may be forced to take jobs that pay less or
aren’t as well-matched to their skills as the jobs they lost. When this
erosion of human capital is repeated millions of times over, it can
reduce economic efficiency and possibly even our overall standard of
living.
Some academics are speculating that the American job market has
changed permanently, and that w e’ll simply have to get used to a
higher rate of unemployment even after the economy recovers. They
argue that the structure of our economy has changed, and that there
will be a continuing mismatch between the types of skills employers
seek and the skills the labor force has to offer. Obviously, this
debate has important implications for the maximum employment
aspect of the Federal Reserve’s dual mandate.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/For_the_Public/News_and_Media/Speeches/2010/Pianalto_20101202.cfm[4/29/2014 1:51:29 PM]

The Recovery and Monetary Policy :: December 2, 2010 :: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
But a group of economists at my Bank have studied this question as
well, and they conclude that most of the rise in unemployment our
country has experienced is cyclical, not structural.2 In other words,
the most important reason employers are hiring so slowly is that their
business activity has been slow to pick up, not because there has
been a sudden mismatch between worker skills and available jobs.
I know that some people are skeptical about this conclusion. It is
clear that for many people, jobs are hard to find. Indeed, the job
finding rate is pretty low, and economists at my Bank have shown
that this rate has been on a downward trend for 25 years. But the
recent cyclical downturn created a huge new glut of unemployed
workers, with the result that it will likely take a lot longer than
normal for people to find the jobs they want.
Let me bring this closer to home. While I recognize that it is never
easy to start out and find a job after you graduate, even from a great
school like Oberlin, a few years ago it was a lot easier than it is now.
Currently, the unemployment rate for college graduates under the
age of 25 is running at almost 9 percent. Before the recession, that
rate was under 5 percent. Unless you think that recent college
graduates are less well-prepared than they were before the
recession, I think it is reasonable to conclude that this is more
evidence of cyclical rather than structural unemployment, and that a
more rapidly growing economy should lead to more job growth.
Even though I expect overall economic activity to pick up in the next
couple of years, I expect hiring to strengthen only gradually. The
unemployment rate is likely to remain elevated for quite some time.
In fact, I do not expect it to fall below 8 percent before 2013.
And what about my outlook for inflation? The bottom line is that
inflation is too low. How could that be, you might ask? Aren’t prices
for many items such as tuition and medical care going up? The
answer is yes, but these price increases do not mean that overall
inflation is rising at the same pace.
Inflation is a deterioration in the purchasing power of money, which
leads to a general rise in most prices and wages. But prices can
change for reasons other than inflation. Relative price changes—both
up and down—happen as individual prices adjust to changing supply
and demand pressures. For example, although prices rose last month
for tuition and medical care, the prices of cars and clothing declined.
Central banks cannot do anything about relative price changes. But
through our monetary policy actions, we can influence overall
inflation. So, in developing our outlooks, we take a lot of care to look
closely into the details of the price statistics to distinguish between
the changes in the ups and downs of individual goods and services,
versus the average rate at which the whole market basket of
consumer prices is changing.
One of the most important inflation guideposts is the core Consumer
Price Index, or CPI. The core CPI is a measure of the rise in prices
based on goods and services people commonly buy, but it excludes
food and energy costs, which can change sharply from month to
month. By this measure, inflation has fallen to a record low of 0.6
percent.
I find that core inflation is a better predictor of future inflation than
the CPI itself. And an even better predictor than core inflation is the
median CPI—an inflation measure that my Bank publishes monthly.
The median CPI is considered about 50 percent more accurate in
gauging future inflation than the overall CPI. The median CPI doesn’t
take the averages of all of the prices in the consumer basket of goods

http://www.clevelandfed.org/For_the_Public/News_and_Media/Speeches/2010/Pianalto_20101202.cfm[4/29/2014 1:51:29 PM]

The Recovery and Monetary Policy :: December 2, 2010 :: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
that the CPI measures each month. Instead, it looks at the price
change that’s right in the middle of the entire long list of individual
price changes. Here is why that is important: if you’re just measuring
averages, as the CPI does, it’s easy for a big price shift in one item in
that basket of goods to push the whole CPI up or down. As it stands
today, the median CPI is also at a record low of 0.5 percent on a 12month basis.
Based on these two measures, I see no evidence of inflationary
pressures in the economy. If anything, there appears to be a slight
trend toward further disinflation. When you really drill down into the
CPI data, as my staff and I always do, you’ll find that nearly 40
percent of the items in the consumer’s market basket showed price
declines over the past month, while just 12 percent of the market
basket showed price increases above 3 percent.
In addition to regularly examining the CPI data, I also look at
indicators of future inflation coming from financial markets, where
investors are putting serious money behind their views about where
inflation is heading over time. At the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland, we have constructed a statistical model that uses data on
financial market transactions to infer the inflation expectations of
these market participants.3 In the latest release of our inflation
expectations model, which is a very popular feature on our website,
inflation expectations remain below 1.5 percent for 10 years, and
below 2 percent as far as the eye can see. 4
Given today’s extremely low inflation rates and the expectations in
financial markets that those rates will remain low, I think that
inflation will remain quite subdued through 2013. I do not expect to
see deflation—which is an outright decline in the general level of
prices—but with demand in the economy still weak and
unemployment so high, continuing disinflation is a risk to my outlook.
In periods of significant economic slack, there is the potential for
very low inflation to tip into deflation.
Admittedly, deflation is rare in the modern experience of
industrialized economies. The last time this country had deflation
was in the Great Depression of the 1930s. As a result, very few
Americans have direct experience with the problems associated with
deflation. On the other hand, Japan—which has a large industrial
economy—has been struggling for several decades, and scholars point
to deflation as a root cause.
Deflation could prove much harder to fight than inflation. The FOMC
has experience dealing with inflation above our objectives, but we
have no experience dealing with outright deflation, and I’d like to
keep it that way.

Why I Supported the Decision to Purchase
Additional Treasury Securities
So, I headed into the November 3 FOMC meeting with an economic
outlook that had the economy falling short on both parts of the
Federal Reserve’s dual mandate of price stability and maximum
employment. With monetary policy already highly accommodative,
the question I faced was whether further monetary stimulus could
improve the situation. Would more monetary stimulus ease financial
market conditions in ways that would promote some additional
growth in spending, output, incomes, and employment? And would
this extra boost, modest though it might be, also act to counter any
lingering disinflationary pressures? In the end, I concluded that there
were enough negative risks to growth and disinflation in my outlook
to merit taking steps that would protect the economy from those
risks.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/For_the_Public/News_and_Media/Speeches/2010/Pianalto_20101202.cfm[4/29/2014 1:51:29 PM]

The Recovery and Monetary Policy :: December 2, 2010 :: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
As I contemplated the potential benefits of further large-scale
purchases of Treasury securities, I evaluated the potential costs as
well. The most important cost in my mind was a possible increase in
inflation and inflation expectations. The public might question the
Federal Reserve’s ability to head off destructive inflationary
pressures after expanding our balance sheet so dramatically. The
FOMC is firmly committed to maintaining price stability, and we have
developed tools that we expect to be very effective in eventually
shrinking our balance sheet. If we do begin to see a buildup of
undesirable inflationary pressures, I am confident that the FOMC has
the resolve and tools to counteract them.
In the weeks before the last FOMC meeting, markets were already
anticipating further policy accommodation. In other words, even well
in advance of the November 3 announcement, we saw evidence of the
likely effect of additional purchases as investors began to anticipate
easier financial conditions. Initially, stock prices rose and long-term
interest rates fell, and I believe that this easing in financial
conditions will, over time, promote more economic growth. Lower
mortgage rates will support home purchases and mortgage
refinancing. Lower corporate bond rates will support more
investment. Each of these developments will help to increase
confidence, which in turn encourages more spending, which leads to
somewhat more employment, and then to higher incomes and profits.
In this way, small gains can build into significant progress over time.
Putting it all together, my choice was clear. I voted to support
additional asset purchases. I think our policy action offers the right
kind of insurance that the Federal Reserve’s monetary policy will
support the economic expansion while stabilizing inflation and
inflation expectations consistent with our price stability mandate.

Conclusion
In conclusion, I’ve studied the financial and economic situation
carefully to determine the right policy actions to fulfill our dual
mandate of price stability and maximum employment. I will continue
to do so, constantly evaluating the costs, benefits, and results along
the way. The FOMC will regularly review incoming economic and
financial data, update our outlook, and make adjustments as needed.
We know that our economy faces a multitude of challenges, and a
full recovery will take some time. We also know that the Federal
Reserve cannot solve all of the economy’s problems on its own. A
sustainable recovery will also depend on prudent, sensible
approaches to fiscal policy, tax policy, trade policy, and many other
considerations far beyond the Federal Reserve’s scope. But
responding to inflationary and disinflationary pressures gets to the
heart of what a central bank can and must do. The main variable the
Federal Reserve can control over time is the price level. Ensuring
price stability is our job. My belief is that by promoting price
stability, the Federal Reserve is following the best course for
supporting the economic recovery.
1. For recessions since 1948, the average length of time it took
for real GDP to return to its pre-recession peak level was just
over 12 months. We are already 33 months into this business
cycle and in the third quarter of 2010, real GDP still remained
nearly a full percentage point below its 2007 peak.
2. Tasci, Murat, and Saeed Zaman. “Unemployment after the
Recession: A New Natural Rate?” Economic Commentary 2010­
11, September 2010. Available at:
http://www.clevelandfed.org/research/commentary/2010/201011.cfm >

http://www.clevelandfed.org/For_the_Public/News_and_Media/Speeches/2010/Pianalto_20101202.cfm[4/29/2014 1:51:29 PM]

The Recovery and Monetary Policy :: December 2, 2010 :: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
3. “Inflation: Noise, Risk, and Expectations,” by Timothy Bianco
and Joseph G. Haubrich. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland,
Economic Commentary, no. 2010-5 (June 28, 2010). Available
at:
http://www.clevelandfed.org/research/commentary/2010/20105.cfm v .
4. “Estimating Real and Nominal Term Structures using Treasury
Yields, Inflation, Inflation Forecasts, and Inflation Swap
Rates,” by Joseph G. Haubrich, George Pennacchi, and Peter
Ritchken. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, working paper,
no. 08-10 (November 2008). Available at:
http://www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/2008/wp0810

Careers | Diversity | Privacy | Terms of Use | Contact Us | Feedback | RSS Feeds

http://www.clevelandfed.org/For_the_Public/News_and_Media/Speeches/2010/Pianalto_20101202.cfm[4/29/2014 1:51:29 PM]