View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Is Price Stability Attainable? :: June 11, 2007 :: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
home | news & media | careers | site map

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK o f CLEVELAND
A bout U
Tours

For the Public

News & Media

Com munit y D e velopm ent

S tream ing Media

Forefront M agazine

Speakers Bureau

I Our IRegion

I Research

I Ban kin g

I Learning Center

Savings Bonds

Home > For the Public > News and Media > Speeches > 2007 > Is Price Stability Attainable?

Is Price Stability Attainable?
Additional Information

Introduction
I have just arrived here from Frankfurt, where the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland sponsored a conference with the Deutsche
Bundesbank on some of the challenges facing central bankers. It is
clear to me that we all share many of the same concerns, and
importantly, we share the same priority - price stability.
For the European Central Bank, price stability is the sole objective.
For the Federal Reserve, price stability is one pillar of our dual
mandate, the other being maximum sustainable economic growth.
Producing price stability is the surest way to enable the economy to
grow at its maximum sustainable rate.

Sandra Pianalto
President and CEO,
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Global Interdependence Center
Conference: GIC Abroad in Ireland
Dublin, ireland
June 11, 2007

For the past two decades, central banks around the world have done
an impressive job of achieving price stability. Despite our past
successes, however, we must always stand ready to deal with
challenges that could eventually confront us.
Recently in the United States, the Federal Reserve's Federal Open
Market Committee has described our core rate of inflation as being
uncomfortably high and has stressed the importance of further
moderation in inflation. We have held our federal funds rate target at
5.25 percent for nearly a year, and we have stated that our
predominant concern is "the risk that inflation will fail to moderate
as expected."
In my remarks this morning, I will first explain why maintaining price
stability requires keeping inflation expectations low and secure.
Second, I will describe some inflationary risks that may become
significant down the road. Finally, I will discuss why, in the face of
these risks, central banks' ability to maintain price stability will
depend on the clarity and transparency of their communications.
Please note that my comments today are my own. I do not presume
to speak for any of my colleagues on the Federal Open Market
Committee.
I. Why Maintaining Price Stability Requires More than Just Keeping
Inflation Low
A few years ago, former Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan
stated that "price stability is best thought of as an environment in
which inflation is so low and stable over time that it does not
materially enter into the decisions of households and firms."1 This is a
fairly common definition of price stability, and it has two essential
characteristics. First, actual inflation must remain low and stable,
and second, people must have every confidence that inflation will
remain low and stable. This second characteristic may not get as
much emphasis as it deserves. Price stability is more than keeping

http://www.clevelandfed.org/For_the_Public/News_and_Media/Speeches/2007/Pianalto_20070611.cfm[4/29/2014 2:06:03 PM]

Is Price Stability Attainable? :: June 11, 2007 :: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
inflation in check - it also means keeping inflation expectations in
check.
Of course, actions speak louder than words, and ultimately, the
public will judge a central bank's resolve to keep inflation low and
stable by whether it actually delivers low and stable inflation.
Expectations can become unglued under some circumstances, even if
the current inflation measures appear contained. From time to time,
there are pressures on a central bank to "buy" relief from economic
troubles with artificially low short-term interest rates. The public
understands these pressures, of course, and if they believe that their
central bank will yield to the pressures, inflation expectations can
rise. Also problematic is that inflation uncertainty can rise. Both of
these outcomes impose costs on the economy by misdirecting how
resources are allocated. Most notably, long-term interest rates move
higher than they otherwise would, interfering with saving and
investment decisions.
Central bankers face an unpleasant dilemma when inflation
expectations become unanchored. Central banks could validate these
expectations of rising inflation by actually delivering higher inflation,
but that outcome would be contrary to our policy objective.
Alternatively, central banks could pursue policies that generate lower
inflation than the public expected. This, in my opinion, is the correct
course, but there can be costs in terms of lower short-term growth costs that would not be incurred if expectations had remained
aligned with the central bank's inflation goal in the first place.
The past quarter-century has brought
central banks. But the credibility test
currents are not so favorable. History
central bankers, so if we are prudent,
challenges to price stability that may

relatively good times for
comes when the economic
has not always been kind to
we must prepare for the
still lie ahead of us.

II. Potential Inflationary Risks Down the Road
Now let me describe some potential risks that I believe could
challenge central banks down the road. Although there are many such
risks, this morning I will focus on three familiar risks: relative price
shocks, extraordinary liquidity crises, and fiscal imbalances. Please
note that I do not regard these risks as imminent, but rather as
representative of the risks that central banks face from time to time.
The first inflationary risk can occur when large and persistent
relative price shocks temporarily ripple through the inflation data.
The obvious example is energy prices, although we see such changes
in commodity prices more generally. These price pressures are
temporary and so do not represent changes in the inflation trend.
Still, a central bank cannot ignore them if it hopes to maintain
credibility for delivering low and stable inflation.
Since 2005, the three- to five-year moving average of U.S. inflation
has hovered around 3 percent.2 This is above where I would like to
see the trend settle in the longer run. The reality of rising oil and
commodity prices is evident, and my Federal Reserve colleagues and I
have been clear that we believe the impact of these influences will
dissipate over time. But until our beliefs are validated by the data,
there is a risk that the public's trust could erode and inflation
expectations could move higher.
The second inflationary risk that central banks should be prepared for
could come about when responding to extraordinary liquidity crises.
This is an important lesson learned from experience. Just consider a

http://www.clevelandfed.org/ForJhe_Public/News_and_Media/Speeches/2007/Pianalto_20070611.cfmt4/29/2014 2:06:03 PM]

Is Price Stability Attainable? :: June 11, 2007 :: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
few examples of what the world's major central banks have dealt
with in the past few decades: the U.S. stock-market crash of 1987,
the Asian currency crisis in 1997, and the collapse of the Brazilian
real in 1999.
Central banks have often provided liquidity in times of large-scale
financial stress, and I think this is the appropriate response. But in
any given case, there are still questions of how much to intervene,
and for how long. How those questions are answered can have longerterm consequences for inflation expectations.
If central banks remove liquidity too quickly following a crisis,
financial markets might not fully stabilize. However, if central banks
maintain an accommodative policy too long after a crisis has passed and the demand for liquidity has diminished - then inflation
expectations can come unglued and future inflation can take root.
We live in an era of financial innovation and increasingly integrated
financial markets. Clearly, these changes have fostered a more
secure economic environment and have improved the wealthgenerating capacity of the global economy. But great change rarely
proceeds without challenges. We need to explore how best to meet
those challenges in ways that will preserve the public's confidence in
our commitment to price stability.
The final inflationary risk I want to emphasize is fiscal imbalances - in
both the United States and Europe.
In the 1970s, economists Tom Sargent and Neil Wallace gave us a
lesson in "unpleasant monetarist arithmetic." They noted that fiscal
imbalances provide a temptation to inflate away the value of the
government's debt, and this possibility may become embedded in
inflation expectations. Those lessons are even more relevant when an
important share of a nation's debt is held abroad. The political cost of
inflating away debt is lower when that debt is held by predominantly
by foreigners.
Unless the fiscal problem is addressed through explicit fiscal policies
or changes in national saving rates, creditors might reasonably
conclude that debtor governments will resort to inflationary policies.
Ultimately, however, central banks cannot control either fiscal policy
adjustments or private consumption decisions. If fiscal dynamics don't
improve, central bankers could once again face the difficult challenge
of maintaining price stability in a world where expectations are
moving in the wrong direction.

III. The Importance of Clear Communications
So what assurances can central banks provide to secure inflation
expectations in the face of these risks? Here, I believe, we are still
learning. We actually know very little about how the public forms its
expectations and the specifics about how best to secure them. In
fact, just last month, the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland held a
joint conference with the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas to better
understand inflation expectations. Central banks from 22 countries
were represented, underscoring the universal interest in this topic.
What seems clear enough is that without guidance from the central
bank, the public is left to guess about future inflation based only on
the central bank's history. Clearly, history alone could be insufficient
to hold expectations stable in times of crisis.3 And so central banks
are developing strategies to provide that guidance.
Suppose I asked you to describe the most important ways central
banks have changed in the past quarter-century. What would you say?
First, I think you would say we have shown a much greater vigilance

http://www.clevelandfed.org/ForJhe_Public/News_and_Media/Speeches/2007/Pianalto_20070611.cfmt4/29/2014 2:06:03 PM]

Is Price Stability Attainable? :: June 11, 2007 :: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
against inflation. But second on that list, I think, would be that
central banks today spend a lot of time communicating - about the
economy, about their policy objectives, and about the risks to
achieving those objectives.
In the United States, the Federal Open Market Committee issues a
press release immediately following our meetings, with minutes of
each meeting released only a few weeks afterward. I can assure you
that every word and every nuance in our communications are
carefully considered. It is essential that the public understand our
interpretation of the economic situation and that they support our
policies. In a very real sense, our communications have become a
part of the policy process, because we understand that influencing
inflation expectations is an important dimension of monetary policy.
Some central banks hold regular press conferences. And, of course,
some have established explicit numerical objectives - or inflation
targets - and publish economic projections that clearly show what
they are aiming at and how they expect to get there. Our different
approaches are, in part, a result of our different histories and
governance structures. But also, I think, central banks are still
developing "best practices" for securing inflation expectations in the
face of unknown future risks.
However, differences in tactics should not be confused with
differences in intent. I believe that my colleagues - and indeed, most
central bankers today - are working to achieve the same end. We are
all trying to create an environment in which inflation is so low and
stable that it does not influence the decisions that households and
businesses would otherwise make.

Conclusion
At the present time, inflation expectations appear to be wellanchored. But we cannot afford to be complacent. However, I
continue to be optimistic that central bankers will successfully meet
the challenges that lie ahead.

[1] Alan Greenspan, "Transparency in Monetary Policy," Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, July/August 2002, p. 6.
[2] These figures are measured by the Consumer Price Index.
[3] This issue is discussed at length by Ben Bernanke in "Central Bank
Talk and Monetary Policy," address to the Japan Society, October 7,
2004.

Careers | Diversity | Privacy | Terms of Use | Contact Us | Feedback | RSS Feeds

http://www.clevelandfed.org/For_the_Public/News_and_Media/Speeches/2007/Pianalto_20070611.cfm[4/29/2014 2:06:03 PM]