View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Labor Markets and Federal Reserve Policy :: June 1, 2011 :: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
home | news & media | careers | site map

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK 0] CLEVELAND
A bout U
Tours

For the Public

News & Media

Com munit y D e velopm ent

S tream ing Media

Forefront M agazine

Speakers Bureau

I Our IRegion

I Research

I Ban kin g

I Learning Centter

Savings Bonds

Home > For the Public > News and Media > Speeches > 2011 > Labor Markets and Federal Reserve
Policy

SH ARE

^

f ...

Labor Markets and Federal
Reserve Policy

Additional Information
Sandra Pianalto

Introduction
This afternoon as I talk about the economy, I will point out that the
economic dislocations we have experienced and continue to
experience are not without historic precedent, however scary and
unfamiliar they might feel.
For example, this is a beautiful room in an equally beautiful building.
But when it was constructed in 1915, the nation was recovering from
the recession of 1913. The world was at war, and the unemployment
rate was around 9 percent.

P resident and CEO,
Federal Reserve Bank o f Cleveland
Columbus Metropolitan Club
Columbus, Ohio

June 1, 2011

During that same period, the Federal Reserve was established in
response to a fragile banking system and a series of financial panics.
The Federal Reserve Act of 1913 instructed the Fed to prevent
financial panics and bank runs by providing loans to the banking
system, a narrower charge than the Fed has today.
Of course, none of us in this room remembers 1915, but many of us
remember the 1970s. In 1976, we celebrated the country's
bicentennial while the Cold War still raged. Here in Columbus that
year, a group of feisty women who wanted a voice and a platform for
public discourse formed the Columbus Metropolitan Club.
At that time, the unemployment rate was nearly 8 percent, following
the recession of 1973. And policymakers worried not only about
elevated unemployment, but about an inflation rate of close to 6
percent.
A year later, in 1977, Congress validated these twin concerns by
changing the Federal Reserve Act, giving the Fed the dual mandate
we still hold - to promote "the goals of maximum employment" and
"stable prices."i
In some ways, the events of today mirror those of the early 1900s
and the 1970s. Our own economy is only gradually recovering from a
deep recession. World events such as the Arab Spring uprisings
capture our attention. The current unemployment rate is 9 percent.
And some are concerned about rising inflation.
At the Federal Reserve, our mandate has not changed since 1977. We
remain focused on doing our part to promote maximum employment
while maintaining stable prices.
Toward that end and in my role as president of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland, I make sure that the perspectives and needs of
the people of my District - which includes all of Ohio, western
Pennsylvania, eastern Kentucky and the northern panhandle of West

http://www.clevelandfed.org/For_the_Public/News_and_Media/Speeches/2011/Pianalto_20110601.cfm[4/29/2014 1:44:11 PM]

Labor Markets and Federal Reserve Policy :: June 1, 2011 :: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Virginia - are part and parcel of the national monetary policy debate.
My fellow Federal Reserve Bank presidents and I stay close to the
communities we serve - talking to business and community leaders
like you - to better understand your economic concerns.
Regular discussions with businesspeople, as well as Federal Reserve
Bank and branch directors around the country, provide us with
timely, anecdotal accounts of the economic landscape.
This way, we see emerging trends far ahead of when they would be
reflected in the economic figures - which after all are backwardlooking, not forward-looking data. And we incorporate those trends
into FOMC deliberations and decisions.
The FOMC, or Federal Open Market Committee, is the policymaking
arm of the Federal Reserve. We meet eight times a year in
Washington. At each meeting, Committee members, me included,
review economic and financial conditions and determine the
appropriate monetary policy to meet our long-term goals of stable
prices and maximum employment.
Today, we clearly do not have maximum employment, and many
people are worried about jobs. Also, it seems that stories about
inflation are in the news almost every day. I'll address both of these
concerns in my remarks today.
First, I'll share what recent labor market developments say about the
recovery. Second, I'll look at why today's unemployment rate is still
so high. Third, I'll discuss what today's labor markets reveal about
inflation. Finally, I'll wrap up with a few thoughts on what all of this
means for the economy going forward.

What Labor Markets Tell Us about the
Recovery
I probably don't need to remind this audience that nine million jobs
were lost in the recession. Since we started seeing employment gains,
in February of last year, only 1.8 million jobs have been added back.
As recently as the 1980s, it was common in a recovery for the
economy to return to its previous employment level within 12
months. However, during the past two recoveries, employers hired at
a far slower pace. So far, this pattern of the slower pace of hiring
seems to be holding in the current recovery as well. We've got a long
way to go before labor markets can be described as healthy again.
Still, we've had some encouraging news over the past few months. In
April, private companies created 268,000 jobs, the fastest pace in
five years. April also marked 14 straight months of net job creation.
In addition, some sectors important to this region have seen
substantial employment growth. For example, manufacturing
employment is up both nationally and in Ohio by 1.7 percent. Here in
Ohio, employment in professional and business services is up 3.5
percent, and employment in educational and health services has
risen by 2.4 percent year-over-year.
Improvement is also evident in job openings, pointing to continued
gains. According to the Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey
conducted by the Bureau of Labor Statistics, job openings increased
in March and 70 percent of industries have increased job openings
over the last 12 months.
We're also seeing a growth in hours worked per week. The Bureau of
Labor Statistics reports a 34.3-hour workweek for all employees right

http://www.clevelandfed.org/For_the_Public/News_and_Media/Speeches/2011/Pianalto_20110601.cfm[4/29/2014 1:44:11 PM]

Labor Markets and Federal Reserve Policy :: June 1, 2011 :: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
now, up from a low of 33.7 hours per week during the recession. And
manufacturing hours are up to almost 40.4 from 38.5 at the height of
the recession. This is hopeful because businesses will first restore
hours or overtime before they begin to add new employees.
At the beginning of a recovery, companies can avoid hiring additional
workers because they can ask employees to do more work or work
longer hours. But after awhile, employees have been stretched so
thin for so long - forced to work longer and harder and to give
ground on raises and benefits - that firms literally run out of ways to
get more productivity out of them. When productivity growth is
dampened, firms begin to hire again.
Taken together, these recent gains in the labor market suggest that
the economy is on firmer footing and that the recovery is likely to
continue. However, growth may be frustratingly slow at times.

Why the Unemployment Rate Is Still So High
Which brings me to my second point: If the economy is recovering,
why is the unemployment rate still so high?
The national unemployment rate for April was 9 percent. The rate in
both Columbus and Ohio has declined in recent months. In April, the
unemployment rate in Columbus was 7.2 percent, well below Ohio's,
which was 8.6 percent. But these rates are still high, well above pre­
recession levels, when Columbus' rate was under 5 percent and Ohio's
unemployment rate was just under 5-1/2 percent.
These unemployment rates primarily reflect an unhappy but true fact
- employment typically picks up only well after the start of a
recovery.
Still, many people wonder if this long period of high unemployment
that we are experiencing marks a fundamental shift in the economy.
Is it something we'll have to live with over the long haul? Is it what
some are calling the "new normal"?
Some people are concerned that the large job losses we experienced
in construction and finance, for example, will be permanent because
there's simply no place for these workers to go in the new economy.
But research reveals that jobs are scarce in most sectors. In fact, it
shows that workers who have lost jobs in construction and finance
have been moving out of the ranks of the unemployed at almost the
same rate as those laid off in less-troubled industries.
The problem isn't about specific industries; it's that there were large
layoffs across almost all industries and we have seen a slow pace of
hiring as the economy recovers at only a moderate pace. This slow
pace of hiring has caused a debate about whether high- and long­
term unemployment is a structural or a cyclical problem.
Structural unemployment is caused by a persistent mismatch between
the skill sets needed to do available jobs and the types of workers
available.
Cyclical unemployment, on the other hand, is caused by a fall-off in
sales and consumer demand resulting in less reason to produce
products and services...or hire workers.
The research done by the economists at my Bank suggests that most
of today's unemployment is cyclical. They don't believe that structural
unemployment has risen very much at all. And I support their
conclusions.
Their work has been paying particular attention to the nature of the

http://www.clevelandfed.org/For_the_Public/News_and_Media/Speeches/2011/Pianalto_20110601.cfm[4/29/2014 1:44:11 PM]

Labor Markets and Federal Reserve Policy :: June 1, 2011 :: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
labor market by analyzing something called labor market “churn”
over the last few decades. Churn is how workers flow into and out of
the job market through job findings and job separations, including
layoffs, quits and fires, and the ending of seasonal or contract
employment.
Their research reveals that historically, the more dynamism or churn
in the job market, the faster the unemployment rate returns to its
"trend" rate or "natural" rate, which we believe is between 5-1/2 and
6 percent. That's the rate where unemployment would settle if there
were no "shocks" to the economic system such as those we've
experienced.
Today, unfortunately, the rate of churn is not returning as quickly as
it has after previous recessions. The high number of unemployed
persons, coupled with a growth outlook that's weaker than in past
recoveries, means the adjustment back to a natural rate of
unemployment will take quite some time...but I believe it will come
back.
So I don't view high unemployment as the "new normal," but I also
don't see it as a quickly resolvable problem either.

What Today’s Labor Markets Tell Us about
Inflation
Third, let's look at what today's labor markets tell us about inflation.
In fact, the connection between employment - or labor markets - and
inflation is a very old issue.
In 1958, Alban Phillips, studying unemployment and wage data in the
U.K., concluded that one stable curve represents the trade-off
between inflation and unemployment. If unemployment goes down,
inflation goes up, and vice versa.
This relationship seemed to hold for some time, but history revealed
that another factor - inflation expectations - played a large role as
well. In the United States in the 1970s, unemployment was high and,
nonetheless, wages and prices were spiraling out of control. Over
time, the public came to expect higher inflation. I believe this
expectation played a significant role in driving up both wages and
prices without the expected reduction in unemployment.
This came to be known as "stagflation," and its presence threw into
question the reliability of the Phillips curve. In the 1970s, we
underestimated the role that inflation expectations would have - that
is, that expectations were more or less a self-fulfilling prophecy.
Today, we pay a lot of attention to inflation expectations. Our
research shows that inflation expectations greatly influence the
actual path of inflation over time. If people come to expect a higher
inflation rate into the future, they tend to make decisions about
wage and price setting that actually push inflation in that direction.
To break the 1970s wage-price spiral, the FOMC, under the
leadership of Paul Volcker, decided that inflation was too high and
that the Federal Reserve would accept temporarily higher
unemployment rates to bring inflation back down.
To be sure, inflation expectations are still--in the longer run--most
influenced by the actual behavior of inflation. And today, Americans'
long-term inflation expectations remain subdued. However, some
Americans are clearly concerned that inflation will rise because of
higher prices at the gas pump or rising food prices at the grocery
store.
My view is that those price increases are, in fact, likely to be

http://www.clevelandfed.org/For_the_Public/News_and_Media/Speeches/2011/Pianalto_20110601.cfm[4/29/2014 1:44:11 PM]

Labor Markets and Federal Reserve Policy :: June 1, 2011 :: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
transitory. Because food and energy prices are already so high this
year, it's unlikely they would rise by as much in the coming year.
Just think, if you had to pay $5 for a gallon of gas, demand for gas
might fall because you might alter your habits - consolidating trips,
taking public transit, or riding your bike to work. This would lessen
the demand for gas, putting downward pressure on the price of gas.
Historically, food and energy prices have been volatile. They rise and
fall because of floods and droughts and wars and variability in global
demand.
It's also significant that most other prices, such as rent, recreation
and furniture, have seen relatively small increases or even price
declines over the past year. These movements in less-volatile
components of the consumer market basket turn out to be better
predictors of inflation. In fact, well over half of all non-energy
consumer goods and services had price increases of less than 2
percent over the past three months.
A critical factor behind slower growth in prices in most non-energy
consumer goods and services is today's subdued wage growth.
Research at my Bank notes that there is a clear connection between
periods of high unemployment (associated with recessions) and slower
wage growth.
Our most recent recession has already brought down wage growth
from just below 4 percent per year to less than 2 percent. After a
recession, wage increases typically remain low for quite some time.
This should keep the inflation rate lower because lower wage growth
directly implies little rise in the cost of producing goods and providing
services.
Consumers purchase more services than goods. And many services are
all about the costs of labor - whether those services are medical,
financial, a new haircut, or a lawn-mowing service.
So, overall in fact, today's circumstances are not like the 1970s.
Instead, today we have temporarily elevated inflation from energy
costs and food prices. But inflation expectations are stable and wage
growth is moderate.

Concluding Thoughts
Let me conclude with some comments about my economic outlook.
Today's labor market conditions are important to my outlook. I
expect the economy to continue on a gradual recovery pace over the
next few years, with annual growth just above 3 percent a year. And
I anticipate it could take about five years for unemployment to reach
its long-run sustainable rate of 5-1/2 to 6 percent.
I believe inflation will be temporarily elevated this year due to
developments in oil and food prices, but I expect inflation to fall
back below 2 percent in the next couple of years.
Given this outlook, I think that the current accommodative stance of
monetary policy, with short-term interest rates close to zero, is
appropriate and supports the FOMC's dual mandate of stable prices
and maximum employment.
Monetary policy refers to actions undertaken by the Federal Reserve
to influence the availability and cost of money and credit. Today's
accommodative monetary policy is keeping interest rates low for
borrowing so business owners can invest in new technologies, capital
improvements, and additional workers. Consumers also benefit from
lower rates on mortgages, student loans, auto loans, and so forth.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/For_the_Public/News_and_Media/Speeches/2011/Pianalto_20110601.cfm[4/29/2014 1:44:11 PM]

Labor Markets and Federal Reserve Policy :: June 1, 2011 :: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Nevertheless, monetary policy will eventually have to become less
accommodative. The FOMC has been developing tools that we'll use
to exit from our current policy stance, and we'll be ready to use
them when the time is right.
As a Federal Reserve policymaker, I study the financial and economic
situation carefully to determine the appropriate policy actions. I'll
continue to do so, constantly evaluating the costs, benefits, and
results along the way.
I began my remarks today by looking at how the economic
dislocations of the past help us to understand and deal more
effectively with those of our own day. I am committed to building on
those economic lessons and vow to bring them to bear, every day, in
my work at the Federal Reserve, to help improve all of our futures.
1. Originally, there were three parts to the Fed's goals: "promote
effectively the goals of maximum employment, stable prices,
and moderate long-term interest rates."

Careers | Diversity | Privacy | Terms of Use | Contact Us | Feedback | RSS Feeds

http://www.clevelandfed.org/For_the_Public/News_and_Media/Speeches/2011/Pianalto_20110601.cfm[4/29/2014 1:44:11 PM]