View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Economic Forecasts and Monetary Policy :: February 13, 2006 :: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
home | news & media | careers | site map

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK o f CLEVELAND
A bout U
Tours

For the Public

News & Media

Com munit y D e velopm ent

S tream ing Media

Forefront M agazine

Speakers Bureau

I Our IRegion

I Research

I Ban kin g

I Learning Center

Savings Bonds

Home > For the Public > News and Media > Speeches > 2006 > Economic Forecasts and Monetary
Policy

D _shrre

Economic Forecasts and Monetary
Policy

Additional Information
Sandra Pinalto

Today I would like to share with you some of my thoughts about
economic forecasts and monetary policy. I will begin with some
comments about the economy's recent performance and the outlook
for 2006. Next, I will explain why making sound policy decisions
requires me to think about both the demand and supply sides of the
economy. Finally, I will describe how the stories behind the
forecasts directly relate to the way I think about the appropriate
course for monetary policy.

President and CEO,
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Cleveland Association for Business
Economics (CABE)
February 13, 2006

Please note that the views I express today are mine alone. I do not
presume to speak for any of my colleagues in the Federal Reserve
System.

Economic Performance and the 2006 Outlook
I will set the context for my remarks by first taking a brief
look at our recent economic performance and the outlook for 2006.
Although the national economy in 2005 was not as strong as it was in
2004, overall we saw solid growth for the year. As you know, the
economy endured a series of significant energy-price shocks that, in
earlier eras, might have triggered a recession. Instead, third-quarter
GDP growth remained strong.
Now, it is true that the advance estimate for fourth-quarter GDP
growth was only 1.1 percent. Some may interpret this weak
performance as a sign that the energy shocks may have finally taken
their toll. However, we should remind ourselves that these are
preliminary numbers. Third-quarter GDP growth was substantially
revised upward, so we may learn in a few weeks that fourth-quarter
growth was not quite as weak as the initial estimate indicates.
We should also remember that it is fairly common to miss on
forecasts of quarter-to-quarter economic performance. For instance,
it would not surprise me too much to look back and see that some of
the growth we thought would occur in the final three months of last
year was actually spread across the third quarter of 2005 - when GDP
growth was stronger than expected - and the first quarter or two of
this year.
Please understand that I am not suggesting we should be complacent
about the weak statistic for fourth-quarter growth. I will be
watching the incoming data very carefully over the next several
months. In fact, the early data for January have been reasonably
good.

http://www.clevelandfed.org/For_the_Public/News_and_Media/Speeches/2006/Pianalto_20060213.cfm[4/29/2014 2:09:23 PM]

Economic Forecasts and Monetary Policy :: February 13, 2006 :: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Assuming the preliminary fourth-quarter report holds up, though,
GDP still grew last year by 3.5 percent. For the year as a whole, it is
clear that employment growth accelerated, business fixed investment
was relatively strong, and core inflation remained subdued.
What about the outlook for 2006? Most forecasters are
expecting another solid performance. Forecasts published by Blue
Chip Economic Indicators, the Congressional Budget Office, and NABE
economists generally call for real GDP to expand by roughly 3-1/4 to
3-1/2 percent this year. Housing investment is generally expected to
slow, while business fixed investment is expected to increase. These
forecasts call for interest rates, the unemployment rate, and core
inflation to remain steady. I know that at your meeting last month,
your three forecasters presented views that were largely the same.
No one, of course, is expecting that every detail of these
forecasts will prove to be precisely accurate. We have to
acknowledge reality: Any forecast is only as good as our ability to
look into the future and foresee the unforeseeable.
In fact, the standard deviation of annual real GDP growth is about 2 ­
1/2 percentage points. This means that most of the time we would
expect real GDP growth to vary in a range that is quite large between 1 and 6 percent. Although very good economic forecasting
models can narrow that range of uncertainty, a fair amount of
uncertainty still remains. Forecasting is a tough business, leading
some people to question the value of forecasting altogether.
I find forecasts to be helpful. However, achieving better forecast
accuracy is less important to me as a member of the Federal Open
Market Committee than understanding the forces that drive the
economy. As a result, although I know that forecasts tend to be
inaccurate - sometimes very inaccurate - the process of thinking
through those forecasts is central to the way I do my job. Within the
numbers, I need to look not just at the "what" but also at the "why."
In other words, I need to think hard about the demand- and supplyside assumptions that underlie economic forecasts.
Thinking about the Demand and Supply Sides of the Economy
So let me explain why I believe that making sound policy decisions
requires me to think about both the demand and supply sides of the
economy.
Most often, it seems that forecasts are presented from the demand
side - as the sum of growth in different categories of spending. In
other words, we gauge how fast consumption spending is likely to
grow, add an estimate of how fast investment is likely to expand,
throw in a prediction of government spending growth, include some
assumptions about net exports and, voila, we have a GDP forecast.
But this is really just a description of what the forecast is, not a
description of why the forecast is what it is.
As a policymaker, I am less interested in a statement like "GDP will
grow by 3-1/4 percent," than I am in answering the question "Why
will GDP grow by 3-1/4 percent?" I find great value in the story
behind a forecast, even if I suspect that unforeseen events could
prove the forecast wrong. Both supply and demand conditions inform
the stories behind the forecasts.
Here is an example. Just recently, a major newspaper ran an
article that stated: "Largely because consumer spending slowed to a
near halt in the fourth quarter last year, overall economic growth
fell." On the surface, that statement seems pretty straightforward: If
spending is strong, the economy grows. If spending is weak, the
economy grows by less. Is that really the best way to think about

http://www.clevelandfed.org/For_the_Public/News_and_Media/Speeches/2006/Pianalto_20060213.cfm[4/29/2014 2:09:23 PM]

Economic Forecasts and Monetary Policy :: February 13, 2006 :: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
U.S. economic performance in 2005?
It is certainly true that GDP growth last year was off the pace of
2004. But, as we are all painfully aware, energy prices rose
dramatically over the course of the year. Consumers saw energy
prices rise about 30 percent by the time they peaked in September.
Clearly, energy-market disruptions - a supply condition - could go a
long way toward explaining why economic activity, including
consumer spending, was more restrained than in the recent past.
So, which interpretation is right? Did economic growth slow
in 2005 because spending slowed? Or did spending slow because
economic growth was restrained by a series of large energy-price
spikes? To put it another way, did growth slow because demand in
the economy was too weak, or did it slow because productive
capacity in the economy was reduced by adverse supply effects?
For me, from a policymaker's perspective, these are important
questions. My job is to help find the course of monetary policy that
is consistent with price stability and with the economy operating at
maximum sustainable growth or, in other words, growing at its
potential. This means that we have to have an idea of where
"potential" is, and we have to be able to identify factors that affect
potential, as opposed to factors that affect only aggregate demand.
In practice, there may be circumstances that affect both demand and
potential, but we still must try to disentangle demand effects from
supply effects. And the reason we must be able to make these
distinctions is that demand and supply effects can have different
implications for the appropriate course of monetary policy.

The Stories Behind Forecasts and Monetary
Policy
Now I will turn to how the stories behind the economic forecasts
directly relate to the way I think about the appropriate course for
monetary policy. I use the term "stories" as a shorthand way of
describing the various hypotheses that lurk behind the economic data
we receive. Each story that I might consider rests on some
hypothesis about potential GDP, full employment, and other concepts
such as the neutral real rate of interest. The challenging part of
using these concepts to inform policy decisions is that they are not
fixed numbers, or even fixed ranges of numbers. Their values
themselves are a complicated function of the supply and demand
conditions that I have been discussing.
Former Chairman Greenspan has expressed skepticism about the
ability of policymakers to translate these concepts into precise
numerical benchmarks. But the concepts themselves must be taken
into account when the FOMC assesses the appropriate path for
monetary policy. When you hear policymakers - or at least this
policymaker -- speak of concepts like "potential GDP" or "full
employment," you are really hearing an attempt to sort out the
supply and demand conditions that frame the economic environment.
Thinking through these concepts is not just an academic exercise. It
is a necessary part of creating a framework for monetary policy
decision-making. To fulfill its mandate, the Federal Reserve must
look not just at the economy's top-line performance. We must try to
determine the stories that may be hidden within the numbers. And,
as I said earlier, even though it can be frustrating to know that our
economic forecasts will likely be inaccurate, we know that the very
process of constructing the stories behind the forecasts is invaluable.
Let me suggest some concrete examples to help clarify what I mean.
From 1997 through 1999, real GDP growth averaged almost 4.4

http://www.clevelandfed.org/For_the_Public/News_and_Media/Speeches/2006/Pianalto_20060213.cfm[4/29/2014 2:09:23 PM]

Economic Forecasts and Monetary Policy :: February 13, 2006 :: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
percent, which is well above most traditional estimates of how fast
the economy can grow without accelerating inflation. But several
members of the FOMC - among them, former Chairman Alan
Greenspan and Jerry Jordan, my predecessor as president of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland - argued that growth itself is not
inflationary if it is driven by productivity gains.
Although they were considering the same projections that others
were studying, Chairman Greenspan, Jerry Jordan and the others had
a much different picture of what it meant for inflation. They saw
favorable supply-side conditions as the cause of the rapid growth,
while others saw overheated demand conditions. In my view, history
has proven that the supply-side perspective was correct.
Consider a more recent example. Many people expected job growth
to bounce back more quickly over the past four years than it did. Job
creation was well below expectations as the economy emerged from
the 2001 recession. Just how far below was made clear by the dating
of the recession itself. As you know, a committee sponsored by the
National Bureau of Economic Research determines the precise timing
of the beginning and the end of recessions. Although the committee
concluded that the recession ended in November 2001, it was not
until July 2003 that it was confident enough to make that judgment.
The main reason for the delay was the unusually weak behavior of
job growth.
In fact, it took almost four years for the economy to reach
the point where there were as many people working in the United
States as there were at the beginning of the recession in 2001. It was
not until last year that we reached the milestone of having created 2
million new jobs in this expansion. A reasonable interpretation of this
period is that demand for goods and services was not strong enough
to create more robust demand for workers. That view implies that
the economy had generally been operating below its potential. If an
economy is operating below its potential because of weak demand,
then a relatively more accommodative monetary policy is the right
medicine - and it can be administered without fear of stoking
inflation. Indeed, the FOMC followed this course for a considerable
period of time.
It is true that even today, new jobs are still being created
more slowly than the roughly 3 million jobs created each year
between 1994 and 2000. How can we account for this performance?
Does a demand-side story make the most sense? In this case, I think
that trends on the supply side of the economy suggest that we might
need to interpret sluggish labor markets differently today.
Perhaps the most interesting trend is the pattern of labor-force
participation - that is, the fraction of people who either have a job
or are actively seeking a job. Since 2001, the labor-force
participation rate of all age groups, except those 55 and older, has
declined. The change has been especially noticeable among younger
workers - 16- to 24-year-olds. Those participation rates have
declined by about 5 percentage points. That amounts to 1.9 million
young people who, for now, are no longer potential workers.
Has this episode of slower employment growth resulted from
demand conditions, supply conditions, or some combination of both?
If it is defined as a demand condition, perhaps poor job prospects
have discouraged people from even attempting to find work. Will
another year like 2005 reverse the recent trend? And does that mean
that monetary policy should be accommodative until the economy is
once again generating substantially more than 2 million new jobs per
year?

http://www.clevelandfed.org/For_the_Public/News_and_Media/Speeches/2006/Pianalto_20060213.cfm[4/29/2014 2:09:23 PM]

Economic Forecasts and Monetary Policy :: February 13, 2006 :: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Alternatively, if the lower labor-force participation rate is defined as
a supply condition, then it may be driven by younger workers'
deferring entry into the labor force - perhaps to obtain more
schooling and skills. If that is the correct explanation, then potential
employment will be calculated much differently from the number we
saw in the 1990s. In that case, attempting to spur more rapid job
growth with an accommodative monetary policy is exactly the wrong
thing to do. It will not accomplish the goal of maximum sustainable
growth in the long run, and it may threaten our goal of price
stability.

Conclusion
As economists - whether we work in corporate life, the
academic world, or the policymaking realm - we are all in the
business of economic forecasting, but each of us may approach our
profession from a different perspective.
The mission of the Federal Reserve leads me to look at economic
data - and the very process of economic forecasting - with a different
purpose, and thus from a somewhat different perspective than simply
producing the most accurate GDP forecast. Our motivation for
forecasting economic conditions begins with our need to shape
monetary policy to the evolution of the economy as we work to fulfill
our dual mandate of price stability and maximum sustainable
growth. For that reason, we look to the supply side as well as the
demand side of the economy when evaluating conditions.
I hope this discussion has helped clarify how I approach my
responsibilities as a member - and this year a voting member - of the
Federal Open Market Committee. Armed with that knowledge, the
next time you hear news reports about the FOMC's decisions, I hope
that you will have an even deeper understanding of the process I use:
considering not just the "whats" that make it into the headlines, but
thinking about the "whys" that I carefully weigh, within policy
deliberations, in an effort to maintain price stability and maximum
sustainable growth.

Careers | Diversity | Privacy | Terms of Use | Contact Us | Feedback | RSS Feeds

http://www.clevelandfed.org/For_the_Public/News_and_Media/Speeches/2006/Pianalto_20060213.cfm[4/29/2014 2:09:23 PM]