View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

At a symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Jackson Hole,
Wyoming
August 31, 2001

Technology, Information Production, and Market Efficiency
I am pleased to participate in this symposium on the information economy. My colleagues in
Kansas City deserve thanks for again having arranged a stimulating program. I will begin by
discussing some issues that relate directly to the paper by D'Avolio, Gildor, and Shleifer. I
will then offer some broader comments on the actual or potential effects of information
technology in markets for financial services.
This paper fits into the large literature on the economics of imperfect information. This line
of research has generated important insights concerning economic behavior and the
functioning of markets, showing in particular that imperfect information can lead to
outcomes that are distinctly less favorable than those under complete information. Andrei
Shleifer (with many co-authors) has been a leading contributor to this field.
The current paper argues that advances in information and communication technology have
improved the functioning of financial markets in many ways but that this technology also has
a dark side that may harm market efficiency. This concern centers on the stock market and
reflects the following argument. Improvements in information technology--most notably, the
rapid growth of the Internet--have made participating in the market much easier and cheaper
and, as a result, the market has drawn in many new and unsophisticated investors. These
"noise traders" cannot differentiate between accurate and distorted information about a
given company. Thus, company managers see greater opportunity to boost their firm's stock
price by fooling investors through the release of distorted information--and have a strong
incentive to do so because of the shift toward stock-based compensation and the widespread
use of equity financing in the "new economy." In the end, according to the paper, more
information is available, but its quality has deteriorated, which reduces the benefit from
information technology for market efficiency.
Because the incentive to produce distorted information is so strong, the authors doubt that
market mechanisms alone can correct the problem. They advocate a two-pronged strategy of
enhanced disclosure requirements and investor education to improve market efficiency.
These recommendations are very sensible. The emphasis on disclosure has long been a
cornerstone of the regulatory framework in the United States, and it lies behind recent
initiatives at the SEC to combat what the commission views as a variety of conflicts of
interest that threaten the integrity of our financial markets. The authors' other
recommendation--greater education of investors--is also important, especially given the
broadening participation in financial markets. The Federal Reserve, along with other
government agencies, is working to promote financial literacy in several ways--by issuing
regulations that make comparing financial products easier, by producing educational
materials for the public, and by supporting private-sector initiatives, such as programs that

design and disseminate course materials for use in schools.
Although I certainly concur with the policy recommendations in the paper, I have some
suggestions for tightening the analysis that lies behind those recommendations. For example,
the paper implies that financial disclosure is generally weaker than in the past, and uses the
media focus on pro forma accounting as one proof of the increasing weakness of financial
disclosure. Increases in pro forma disclosures do not necessarily imply that misleading
information is always being disclosed. While the authors demonstrate that, in a small number
of firms, earnings from pro forma numbers are high relative to GAAP earnings, it is not clear
from the paper how severe a problem exists with regard to these disclosures. Similarly, while
the paper attempts to show that earnings management can fool the market, virtually all the
evidence is based on data from the 1970s, 1980s, and early 1990s, and thus it may not be
relevant for the later years. Moreover, the analysis of more recent effects of earnings
distortions tends to be loose. For example, the paper argues that the high turnover of shares
in option-intensive companies may indicate that their shareholders are relatively
unsophisticated--on the thought that the omission of option-related costs from GAAP
earnings overstates the firm's true income and that uninformed investors trade heavily on
this noise-ridden news. Perhaps. But the paper ignores other plausible explanations for the
high turnover that may be unrelated to the sophistication of shareholders. One such
explanation is that option-intensive firms are concentrated in the high-tech sector, where the
flow of news and, hence, trading opportunities are greater than elsewhere in the economy.
My second suggestion is that the authors be more careful about asserting that information
technology has greatly expanded the presence of uninformed investors in the equity market.
Based on my reading of the available data, this occurrence seems far from clear, and I would
like to spend a couple minutes indicating why.
Let's begin by looking at the aggregate data on household equity holdings from the Federal
Reserve's flow of funds accounts.1 These data include direct holdings by households, along
with the various forms of indirect equity holding that involve professional management (such
as investing through mutual funds). If uninformed individuals have played a growing and
direct role in the equity market, as the paper argues, we might expect to see that direct
holdings by households have become a larger share of the total equities outstanding.
However, as chart 1 (3 KB PDF) shows, we see just the opposite. This result may reflect the
fact, as indicated in chart 2 (3 KB PDF), that over the past decade, households have been
reducing the portion of their equities that they hold directly and have increasingly invested
through mutual funds and variable annuities (which are essentially mutual funds combined
with life insurance). That is, households have been handing over more and more of their
equity portfolio to professional managers, who tend to be relatively well informed investors.
Household-level data on equity ownership paint a similar picture. It is true, as shown by
table 1 in the paper, that the number of U.S. households owning equity in some form has
increased substantially. However, this table also shows that relatively little of this increase
reflects broader direct ownership of equity. According to the Federal Reserve's Survey of
Consumer Finances--which is the original data source for this table--only 19 percent of U.S.
households owned individual stocks outside retirement accounts in 1998, barely above the
17 percent share in 1989. Like the aggregate data, these figures suggest that new investors
have largely been putting their money in managed accounts.
What do we actually know about the new investors who have chosen to buy individual
stocks in recent years? To my knowledge, the best source of such information is the "Equity

Ownership in America" survey conducted in 1999 by the Investment Company Institute and
the Securities Industry Association. The following table uses these data to compare the
households that first purchased individual stocks after 1995 with the households whose first
purchase was between 1990 and 1995.2 I've split the sample at 1995 to assess whether the
increased access to information and sharply lower trading costs since then have lured a
cohort of clearly uninformed investors to the market.

Selected Characteristics of Households that First Purchased Individual Stocks in the
1990s (Median 1998 values, except for variables calculated as percentages)

Household Characteristics

First Purchase of Individual Stocks
Outside Retirement Plans

1990-1995

After 1995

Age as of survey

42

41

College or postgraduate degree (percent)

63

52

Income

$62,500

$62,100

Financial assets as of survey

$120,000

$70,600

Number of individual stocks owned as of survey

3

2

Number of individual stock transactions in 1998

0

2

Willing to take more than average risk (percent)

44

55

Already had owned a stock mutual fund (percent)

33

41

Source: Unpublished tabulations provided by the Investment Company Institute, based on data from the "Equity Ownership in America" survey, jointly
sponsored by the Investment Company Institute and the Securities Industry Association in 1999.

As the table shows, the two groups of investors appear to be similar in important respects.
There is almost no difference in median age (early 40s) or income (about $62,000) between
the two groups, and investors in both groups tend to be well educated, although the
proportion with a college or postgraduate degree is a little lower for the new-investor group.

With regard to their portfolios, the median investor in each group held only a few stocks and
did little or no trading in 1998.3 The new-investor group tended to have a higher
self-assessed tolerance for risk, which might suggest that these investors gravitated more to
technology stocks, which have had such a wild ride in recent years. However, it's also
noteworthy that this group had more exposure to the equity market through prior ownership
of stock mutual funds than did investors who first purchased individual equities between
1990 and 1995.
These observable characteristics are, of course, only crude proxies for what we really want
to measure--the degree of market knowledge and sophistication. Still, this survey provides
little reason to believe that the new purchasers of individual stocks are especially likely to be
duped by misleading information. The survey results, combined with the data indicating a
shift toward institutional holdings of equity, cast doubt on the authors' assertion that
information technology has "brought unsophisticated investors in droves to the stock
market."
I would feel more comfortable with an alternative story, which goes as follows. The late
1990s were a period of optimism about the prospects for the U.S. economy, reflecting the
pickup in productivity growth that was generated, in large part, by information technology.
The resultant optimism about the economy's growth prospects was accompanied by a
complacent attitude toward risk, fed by the long bull market dating back to the early 1980s.
In this environment, many investors--not merely newcomers--purchased stock on the belief
that business plans would become reality. The problem was not, for the most part, that new
investors came to dominate the market but that many investors' attitude toward and
perception of risk changed markedly. This explanation of recent events, which avoids the
less-compelling aspects of the paper, appears to provide a stronger foundation for the
authors' observations.
Given the panel topic of finance in the information age, I would now like to broaden the
discussion by considering the actual or likely effects of technology on product attributes,
pricing, and welfare in markets for other financial products. Since I read the paper to be
focused mainly on the retail market, I shall continue in that vein.
For a number of retail financial products, new technologies have surely led to a general
increase in welfare. New delivery technologies, such as the Internet, when combined with
automated underwriting and credit scoring, have given borrowers the opportunity to select
from a broader set of providers of credit cards, mortgages, and even some types of small
business loans--one of the most informationally opaque financial products. Competition has
been enhanced as new technology makes it easier for non-banking institutions to offer these
products and for out-of-market financial firms to compete with local financial institutions. In
addition, securitization--which is also dependent on advances in information technology--has
broadened the pool of lenders by allowing loan originators to package risk and then shift the
risk to the parties best able to bear it.
At the same time, automated underwriting and credit scoring are improving the ability of
lenders to evaluate and price credit risk, which has allowed credit to be extended to a wider
range of borrowers. The rapid growth in the market for subprime mortgages is but one
example of the broader access to credit. In effect, advances in information technology are
helping to ameliorate a key imperfection in loan markets--namely, the outright denial of
credit to relatively risky borrowers in the face of limited information. Recent events indicate
that this product market is still evolving.

Automated underwriting and credit scoring are also substantially reducing the time and cost
involved in making credit decisions. These savings contribute to the overall welfare
improvement brought about by information technology. In the area of mortgage lending, for
example, credit decisions today are routinely made in minutes rather than days and at much
lower cost than a decade ago. Freddie Mac reports that the cost of originating mortgage
loans processed through their system has fallen hundreds of dollars, helping to overcome one
of the main barriers to homeownership--a lack of available savings to meet closing costs and
downpayment requirements. Another benefit of automated underwriting is that credit
decisions have become more transparent, to both lenders and potential borrowers.
Individuals can easily obtain their credit report and credit score, check whether any
information in the report is incorrect, and learn how they can improve their credit standing.
In short, while the paper raises important concerns about equity markets, other areas of
finance provide evidence that the information age has brought significant benefits in the
form of increased transparency and competition, lower costs, more appropriate pricing, and
broader access to credit.
Technology has also expanded the ways in which customers can conduct business with
financial institutions, which has the potential to increase welfare. For example, the need for
"in-person visits" has diminished as financial service providers have established centralized
call centers to facilitate telephone banking, developed web sites to allow Internet banking
and software to permit PC banking, and promoted the use of direct deposits and
pre-authorized debits. According to recent statistics, nearly 40 percent of all U.S. banks now
provide some form of web site through which they can communicate with customers, and
almost 15 percent provide web sites that can be used to conduct banking transactions. These
numbers are growing rapidly. Of the banks with more than $500 million in assets, nearly 50
percent now provide web sites that can be used to conduct transactions. As the need for
in-person visits declines, we might expect customers to broaden the geographic area within
which they search for providers of financial services, leading to increased competition.
Clearly, mortgages and credit cards already fall into this category of financial product.
Nonetheless, the implications of these newer delivery channels for banking products other
than mortgages and credit cards seem more potential than real for the vast majority of bank
retail customers. For example, despite the expanded options made available to customers as
a result of technological advances, data collected in the Federal Reserve's 1998 Survey of
Consumer Finances and 1998 Survey of Small Business Finances indicate that households
and small businesses still rely very heavily on in-person visits to carry out their financial
transactions. Eighty-one percent of households surveyed in 1998 indicated that they used
in-person visits as a means for conducting business with a financial institution, and 86
percent of small businesses indicated that during 1998 they relied upon such visits as their
most common method for dealing with their primary financial institution. Only 6 percent of
households reported having used a computer to conduct business with a financial institution
in 1998. Electronic access to financial institutions, no doubt, will continue to grow, and the
next Federal Reserve Survey of Consumer Finances will provide valuable data about the
changes through 2001. In the meantime, the facts I have highlighted and other data already
available demonstrate that the use of electronic technologies for dealing with a financial
institution deserves monitoring and continuing analysis and evaluation.
It is also worth noting that some technology-driven financial services have been commercial
failures. In the world of payments, stored value cards are clearly technically viable but have

yet to be widely used. The "cashless society" appears little closer today than when that
phrase began to be used forty years ago. One likely explanation is that network effects are
important in determining which innovations succeed or fail. In many retail payment
experiments, too few consumers or merchants use a payment network or a new instrument
for these technology-driven services to become economically viable.
In concluding, the paper has added a note of caution to the discussions of the potential
welfare-improving elements of finance in the information age. Though I have taken
exception to some of the detailed analysis in the paper and noted that other financial
products likely have been enhanced by the emergence of new technologies, it is clear that
technology has not changed all elements of the delivery of financial services or cured all
market imperfections. Likewise, not all technology-derived financial products have achieved
commercial success. The authors are to be commended for reinforcing these common-sense
lessons. By doing so they give further impetus to both financial literacy and regulations that
foster market experimentation and development while appropriately protecting those that
need to be protected and responding to market imperfections when they appear.

Footnotes
1. Technically, these data combine nonprofit organizations with the household sector;
however, the nonprofits are a small part of this aggregate, so we can safely regard the data
as pertaining to households. Return to text
2. This comparison is based on unpublished tabulations of the survey data that were kindly
provided by the Investment Company Institute. Return to text
3. However, there are some very active traders in both groups. The average number of stock
trades for each group in 1998 was seven, far above the median. Return to text
Return to top
2001 Speeches

Home | News and events
Accessibility
To comment on this site, please fill out our feedback form.
Last update: August 31, 2001 1:00 PM