View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

To the Conference on Reflections on Monetary Policy 25 Years after October 1979,
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, St. Louis, Missouri
October 8, 2004
Panel discussion: Safeguarding Good Policy Practice through Maintaining Flexibility
I am pleased to address this conference commemorating the twenty-fifth anniversary of the
historic monetary policy changes implemented in October 1979. In my prepared remarks, I
would like to focus on two issues with respect to safeguarding good monetary policy
practice. First, I will discuss what constitutes good monetary policy practice and review the
Federal Reserve's record in satisfying its mandates in recent decades. Then, I will speculate
on how good policy outcomes come about. In particular, I will discuss the role of policy
transparency, central bank leadership, and alternative monetary policy regimes in preserving
effective monetary policy. Of course, the usual caveat to my remarks applies: I will express
my own views, and you should not interpret them as the position of the Federal Open
Market Committee or of the Board of Governors.
Assessing the Federal Reserve's Performance after 1979
When assessing what constitutes good monetary policy practice, I prefer to focus not on
theory but on the reality of the Federal Reserve's objectives. In contrast to many other
central banks, the Federal Reserve has been assigned a "dual mandate"--to pursue policies
that both maintain price stability and achieve maximum sustainable economic growth and
employment. Good policy practice can be judged by the outcomes achieved. Therefore, I
would like to briefly outline the Federal Reserve's performance with respect to the level and
the variability of inflation and growth. To be sure, the strong economic performance over the
past two decades has several possible explanations, but the practice of monetary policy has
likely contributed by helping to preserve macroeconomic stability.
With respect to price stability, inflation in the United States over the past decade or so has
clearly been lower and more stable than it was earlier in our history. In fact, annual inflation
in the price index of personal consumption expenditures excluding food and energy--core
PCE--averaged just over 2 percent from 1990 through the end of last year and consistently
remained within a range--roughly 1 to 4 percent--that is relatively narrow compared with
historical experience. This period contrasts sharply to the fourteen-year period from 1965
through the end of 1979, when annual core-PCE inflation averaged just over 5 percent and
fluctuated between 3 and 10 percent. The recent experience of the United States with
inflation has been similar in some respects and dissimilar in others to that of other countries.
For example, based on the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development's
measures of overall consumer price inflation, prices rose at an annual average rate of about
3 percent in the United States from 1990 through 2003, compared with about 3 percent in
the euro area and in the United Kingdom and roughly 1 percent in Japan.1 But, more
important, the volatility of inflation was lower in the United States than in these other
economies.

An equally important indicator of the success of the Federal Reserve's monetary policy is
private expectations for future inflation. Measures of inflation expectations obtained from
financial asset prices clearly indicate that market participants expect that the Federal
Reserve will maintain low and stable inflation. For example, although the difference
between the yields on nominal inflation-indexed and Treasury securities is an imperfect
measure that includes complicating factors such as inflation risk and liquidity premiums, the
five-year break-even inflation rate five years ahead has averaged about 2-1/2 percent over
the past five years and has fluctuated in a narrow range of about 1-1/2 to 3-1/2 percent.
Survey measures confirm that inflation expectations over this period have been subdued and
well anchored. The University of Michigan's survey of ten-year inflation expectations has
averaged less than 3 percent and has stayed within a very narrow range over the past five
years.
Assessing the outcomes with respect to the Federal Reserve's goal of maximum sustainable
output growth is inherently more difficult. Estimates of the relevant measures, such as the
nonaccelerating-inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU), which in recent years has been
decreasing according to some estimates, have very wide confidence intervals. But we can
point to some evidence suggesting that the United States has enjoyed, besides subdued and
stable inflation, some favorable developments with respect to output and employment.
Certainly, we can document substantial gains in productivity in recent decades in the United
States. According to the OECD, business sector labor productivity growth in the United
States averaged about 2 percent from 1990 through the end of 2003, compared with about
1-1/2 percent in the euro area and in Japan over the same period. And since the mid-1990s,
this gap has widened, with annual productivity growth averaging about 2-1/2 percent since
1995 in the United States, compared with about 1-1/2 percent in Japan and just less than 1
percent in the euro area over the same period.2
Another important measure of the success of monetary policy is how well the FOMC has
responded to threats to our nation's financial stability. This claim is surely hard to quantify.
But everyone would agree that, compared especially with the deleterious effects of the
Federal Reserve's policy response during the Great Depression, the Fed has responded
effectively to more-recent crises so as to help minimize the impact of such shocks on the
greater economy. These episodes include the stock market crash of October 1987, the Asian
financial crisis, and the collapse of Long-Term Capital Management in the late 1990s.
Thanks in no small part to the flexibility of our policy framework, which I will discuss in
greater detail in a few moments, the Federal Reserve appropriately discharged its
responsibility as lender of last resort by providing ample liquidity and ensuring confidence
during these and other troubling episodes, including the aftermath of the terrorist attacks of
September 11, 2001.
There is greater disagreement about how well the Federal Reserve responded to the bursting
in recent years of the so-called bubble in technology stocks. This topic is broad, but I would
like to note that, as many of my colleagues and I have previously argued, prospectively
addressing perceived asset-price bubbles is a matter of such great uncertainty that, even with
the benefit of hindsight, it is not clear that policy decisions in the late 1990s, for example,
should have been any different. In any case, the recession that followed the sharp decline in
stock prices was shallow by historical standards.
How Can We Safeguard Good Policy Outcomes?
I would now like to turn to issues related to preserving, as best we can, a continuation of

good policy practice in the future.
Central Bank Transparency
Consider first the important role of central bank transparency. Transparency of central bank
decisionmaking is desirable, not only for economic reasons, but also because it is supportive
of central bank independence within a democratic society. Because of the lagged effects of
monetary policy on output and prices, the time horizon of central bankers is necessarily
more distant than that of other policymakers. Thus, the central bank needs substantial
insulation from political pressures to execute policy: An independent monetary authority is
less tempted to make policy for the short term, such as boosting output or refinancing
national budgets, at the expense of long-run objectives. Of course, the goals of monetary
policy should be determined within the democratic process, but the central bank should have
discretion to achieve those ends. In short, an appropriate arrangement within democratic
societies is for central banks to have independence with respect to the instruments, but not
the goals of monetary policy, and transparency is an appropriate condition for that
independence.
Besides its inherent virtues in a democratic society, transparency can enhance monetary
policy's economic effectiveness by more closely aligning financial market forces with central
bankers' intentions. Like other central banks, the Federal Reserve controls only a very
short-term interest rate, the overnight federal funds rate. However, theory and empirical
evidence suggest that longer-term interest rates and conditions in other financial markets,
which reflect expectations for short-term rates, matter most for monetary policy
transmission to the economy. If the monetary authority is transparent about the rationale and
the stance of policy as well as its perception of the economic outlook, then investors can
improve their expectations of future short rates.3
The path that monetary policy will follow in the future is uncertain even to policymakers
because that trajectory will depend on incoming news about the economy and the
implications of that news for the economic outlook. But announcing policy decisions in a
timely manner and explaining those decisions fully allows market participants to better
anticipate the response of policy to unexpected developments and to speed needed financial
adjustments.
Central Bank Leadership
Next, I consider the role of the individuals entrusted with the responsibility for making
policy decisions. Although monetary policy frameworks have a potentially great influence
on macroeconomic outcomes, we should not forget that the individuals who serve in central
banks themselves have a crucial role in preserving policy outcomes. Even with a monetary
policy regime that follows best practices and shapes the decisionmaking process, ultimately
individuals' beliefs and perceptions still matter for the actual policy taken.
An interesting recent study of the history of the Federal Reserve by Christina Romer and
David Romer finds a very strong link between the skill and knowledge of the FOMC,
particularly the Chairman, and macroeconomic outcomes.4 For example, with little
reference to transformations in the disclosure policy and the independence of the Federal
Reserve over the years, they ascribe the policy successes of two periods--the 1950s and the
1980s and 1990s--to a conviction of Federal Reserve Chairmen regarding the high costs of
inflation and their tempered views about the sustainable levels of output and employment. In
contrast, they attribute the deflationary and counterproductive policies of the 1930s to the
erroneous belief that monetary policy can do little to stimulate output and that the economy

can actually overheat at low levels of capacity utilization.
But there is one aspect of the process that Romer and Romer do not emphasize enough--the
ability of central bankers in general, and indeed members of the FOMC in particular, to
withstand political pressures. In addition, central bankers should have a thorough and
practical, rather than a purely academic, understanding of the economy and, given the
Federal Reserve's objective to preserve financial stability, of financial markets and
institutions.
The committee's institutional memory may also matter in this context. Today, the FOMC is
well versed in the monetary history of the 1970s and 1980s, for example, and recognizes the
great efforts that previous members of the FOMC undertook to achieve price stability. I trust
that future generations of policymakers will continue to share that understanding and thus
help to preserve good policy outcomes.
Will Inflation Targets Preserve Good Policy Practice?
Finally, I would like to touch on a topic that is perhaps more controversial in the context of
safeguarding good policy practice. Several academic and professional economists, including
distinguished colleagues of mine at this conference, have eloquently advocated the adoption
of explicit numerical goals for central bank objectives, most notably inflation targets. The
adoption of numerical targets, it is argued, facilitates central bank accountability and better
anchors private expectations about inflation and monetary policy and thereby yields better
macroeconomic outcomes.
Quantifying central bank objectives has some positive aspects and, certainly, vigorous
advocates. Nonetheless, I harbor significant reservations about this approach regarding both
its practical implementation, in the specific context of the Federal Reserve System, and its
demonstrated effectiveness based on inferences from the recent experience of regimes that
have specific numerical targets, particularly with respect to inflation, around the world.
A basic, yet difficult, issue is the selection of a particular price index to guide policy, even in
the case of a single goal such as inflation. Experience tells us that economies and the
composition of productive enterprises change over time, and therefore the appropriate index
and inflation value for the monetary authority would also need to change to reflect
technological and other advances. In light of this inherent uncertainty associated with the
construction of a price index, one might be concerned that choosing and rigidly adhering to
an inappropriate index could have negative economic consequences that might outweigh
prospective benefits.
Also, we must consider the ramifications of quantified goals in the context of our
democracy. That is, the quantification of objectives becomes even more problematic for
central banks such as the Federal Reserve with multiple democratically based mandates,
some of which are notably less disposed to quantification than others. For example,
considering our dual mandate from the Congress, how do we measure maximum sustainable
employment? Indeed, as I mentioned previously, estimates of the NAIRU and other possible
related measures that address the full-employment objective such as the output gap have
uncomfortably wide confidence intervals and are far more controversial than selecting a
target for a specific price index.
Of course, the central bank could in principle quantify only the inflation objective. However,
I fear that quantifying one goal and not the other would present problems because the
monetary authority might inadvertently place more emphasis on the quantified goal at the

expense of the nonquantified objective. Doing so would seem inappropriate. The ease of
quantification should not influence how the Federal Reserve pursues its dual mandate.
In addition, I worry about the potential loss of flexibility from the implementation of an
inflation target, as explicit numerical goals might inhibit the central bank's focus on output
variation or financial stability. I would argue that, besides the episodes of financial turmoil in
the late 1990s mentioned earlier, supply shocks, such as large increases in oil prices that
simultaneously increase the price level and decrease aggregate output, can be problematic
for inflation-targeting regimes.
Of course, some variants of the approach--so-called flexible inflation targeting for
instance--can address the issues I just raised by stipulating wide target ranges, by
maintaining escape clauses that allow inflation to diverge from the target, or by aiming at
average inflation over the business cycle. But the credibility gains from inflation targeting
seem to me to be inversely related to its flexibility. Simply, credibility is less likely to be
gained and expectations are less likely to be anchored if the central bank frequently uses
escape clauses, widens the target bands, or pushes out its time horizon.
Ultimately, real credibility for achieving goals must come from performance, and
predetermined frameworks do not seem to be a necessary or a sufficient condition to
safeguard desirable policy outcomes. Observation of more-recent Federal Reserve actions
reveals the apparent preferences of policymakers. In recent years, the Federal Reserve has
apparently leaned against disinflation when core inflation threatens to fall much below 1
percent, and, similarly, against inflation when the core rate threatens to rise above 2 to 2-1/2
percent. The Federal Reserve has demonstrated this strategy without the formal adoption of
a specific inflation target or range for the FOMC.
Given the subdued and stable inflation witnessed over the past fourteen years, I have to ask:
What would be gained from a formal goal for inflation? Can we draw compelling general
inferences from the recent experience of inflation-targeting central banks? As a caveat
regarding this evidence, economists have very limited data to work with, as the first
recognizable inflation targeting regime appeared in New Zealand in 1990. But to date, I
would argue that the case for inflation targeting has yet to be proved.
Certainly, I would not deny that numerical inflation targets have proven useful for several
countries in particular circumstances. One example is the United Kingdom, where, in the
aftermath of "Black Wednesday" in October 1992, an inflation target helped provide a
nominal anchor after sterling was removed from the European exchange rate mechanism. I
should also add that the Bank of England has quite successfully helped to achieve low and
stable inflation ever since. In addition, inflation targeting can have demonstrable benefits in
lower-income countries that have experienced high and variable inflation rates in the recent
past.
In several cases, quantified inflation targeting has served as a means of achieving the central
bank independence necessary to focus more effectively on controlling inflation. That is, the
adoption of an inflation target is frequently part of a broader program to increase the
autonomy and transparency of central bank practice. But inflation targeting is not the only
means by which to achieve these ends. Again, the recent experience in the United States that
I have noted is an object lesson in this regard.
Unfortunately, the empirical evidence for industrial countries available to date generally
appears insufficient to assess the success of the inflation-targeting approach with

confidence. For example, it is unclear whether the announcement of quantitative inflation
targets lessens the short-run tradeoff between employment and inflation, and whether it
helps anchor inflation expectations. In addition, some research, controlling for other factors,
fails to isolate the benefits of an inflation target with respect to the level of inflation or its
volatility over time, and output does not seem to fluctuate more stably around its potential
for countries that have adopted numerical targets.5 Future data may or may not produce
compelling evidence, but I maintain that the case today for inflation targets in countries that
already enjoy low and stable inflation rates has certainly not been proved.
With respect to both its practical implementation, particularly in the United States, and the
empirical evidence to date, I submit that the adoption of a numerical inflation target does not
promise any obvious incremental benefits, at least in countries that have already achieved
reasonable price stability. That said, a continuing commitment to price stability is certainly
important, and the Federal Reserve has established a solid record of such commitment.
Conclusion
Based on this brief review, I conclude that, at least since the policy reform of October 1979,
most observers would agree that the Federal Reserve has achieved generally good policy
practice and outcomes. In my assessment, good policy practice cannot be safeguarded with
certainty using a single rule or framework, such as inflation targeting. Good outcomes
ultimately depend on flexible execution of an evolving strategy and policymakers with an
unwavering commitment to low and stable inflation as the foundation for maximum
sustainable growth.
Footnotes
1. Data are from the most recent OECD Economic Outlook (No. 75) (Excel
spreadsheet). Return to text
2. These data on productivity growth are also from the most recent OECD Economic
Outlook (No. 75) (Excel spreadsheet). Return to text
3. See Joe Lange, Brian Sack, and William Whitesell (2003), "Anticipations of Monetary
Policy in Financial Markets," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, vol. 35 (December),
pp. 889-909; William Poole, Robert H. Rasche, and Daniel L. Thornton (2002), "Market
Anticipations of Monetary Policy Actions," (253 KB PDF) Federal Reserve Bank of St
Louis, Review, vol. 84 (July/August), pp. 65-93; and Ben S. Bernanke, Vincent R. Reinhart,
and Brian P. Sack (2004), "Monetary Policy Alternatives at the Zero Bound: An Empirical
Assessment," Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2004-48 (Washington: Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System, September), for evidence relating to the increased
transparency of the FOMC over the past several years to the predictability of short-term
interest rates. Return to text
4. See Christina D. Romer and David H. Romer (2004), "Choosing the Federal Reserve
Chair: Lessons from History," Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 18 (Winter), pp.
129-62. Return to text
5. See for example, Laurence Ball and Niamh Sheridan (2003), "Does Inflation Targeting
Matter?" NBER Working Papers Series, no. 9577 (March), and E. Castelnuovo, S. NicolettiAltimari, and D. Rodriguez-Palenzuela (2003), "Definition of Price Stability, Range and
Point Inflation Targets: The Anchoring of Long-term Inflation Expectations," (413 KB PDF)

ECB Working Paper No. 273 (September). Return to text
Return to top
2004 Speeches
Home | News and events
Accessibility | Contact Us
Last update: October 8, 2004