View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Before the East Hanover (N.J.) Area Chamber of Commerce, East Hanover, New
Jersey
June 10, 1999

The Making of Monetary Policy
Thank you for inviting me to share lunch and a few thoughts with you today. I believe that it
is important for the actions of this country's central bank to be as transparent as possible,
and, therefore, I am happy to address this audience on the topic of the what the Federal
Reserve actually does and how it does it. I will also try to give an assessment of the national
and international issues affecting Federal Reserve policy.
I hope that you will conclude from this discussion that, though the process of setting
monetary policy is complex, it is nonetheless in many important ways accessible to the
average citizen. I also hope that you will agree that there are really very few secrets; we
attempt to be as open as is responsible, which is appropriate in a democracy.
History of the Federal Reserve System and the FOMC
The Federal Reserve was created by an act of Congress on December 23, 1913. The Federal
Reserve System consists of a seven-member Board of Governors (an independent agency of
the federal government with headquarters in Washington, D.C.), plus a nationwide network
of twelve Federal Reserve Banks and twenty-five branches. Congress established the
Federal Reserve Banks as the operating arms of the nation's central banking system, and
they have both public and private elements.
Neither the Board nor the Reserve Banks receive appropriations from Congress. Therefore,
they do not operate with tax revenues, but rather pay expenses out of earnings. Earnings of
the Federal Reserve Banks are derived primarily from interest received on their holdings of
U.S. government securities and the fees they charge to depository institutions for providing
services. All of the net earnings of the Banks, after expenses, contributions to surplus and
payment of other assessments, are aggregated and paid over to the U.S. Treasury. In 1998,
for example, the Federal Reserve paid approximately $26.5 billion to the U.S. Treasury.
The Federal Open Market Committee, or FOMC, is the most important monetary policymaking body of the Federal Reserve System. The FOMC makes the key decisions regarding
the conduct of open market operations -- (purchases and sales of U.S. government securities)
-- which affect the cost and availability of money and credit in the U.S. economy. The voting
members of the Committee are the members of the Board of Governors and five Reserve
Bank presidents. The president of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York serves on a
permanent basis; the presidents of the other Reserve Banks serve one-year terms on a
rotating basis, beginning January 1 of each year. All the Reserve Bank presidents participate
fully in the various discussions, regardless of whether they currently have a vote in the
policy decision. By law, the FOMC must meet at least four times each year in Washington,

D.C. Since 1980, eight regularly scheduled meetings have been held each year. If
circumstances require consultation or consideration of an action between regularly
scheduled meetings, members may be called upon to participate in a special meeting or a
telephone conference.
So what happens at these meetings? The order and structure of these meetings may change
over time, but they have been pretty much fixed during my term on the Board. Before each
regularly scheduled meeting of the FOMC, System staff members prepare written reports on
past and prospective economic and financial developments, which are sent to Committee
participants. At the meeting itself, staff members present oral reports on the current and
prospective business situation, conditions in financial markets and international economic
and financial developments. After these reports, each Committee participant, voting and
nonvoting, expresses his or her views on the current state of the economy and prospects for
the future. After a short coffee break, we have a staff presentation on the alternatives we
face in setting monetary policy. At that point, the Chairman gives his view of the economy
and makes a suggestion for the appropriate direction of policy. Each Committee member
then responds to the Chairman's suggestion, in the process setting out a preferred choice for
policy. After this second "go-around," we take a formal vote on the target federal funds rate
for the period until the next meeting. At this point, the focus is on the voting members, who,
as I noted, include all of the Governors and five of the twelve Presidents. Generally, an
announcement of a change in interest rates, if any, is made at about 2:15 in the afternoon. A
full set of meeting minutes is made available after the subsequent meeting.
Let me shift now from the mechanics of the process to the broader conceptual issues that
confront the conduct of monetary policy and some of the issues surrounding the outlook for
the U.S. economy. Of course, the views I shall be expressing are my own and are not
necessarily shared by the FOMC or the Board of Governors.
The Goals of Monetary Policy
Federal law establishes the goals of monetary policy. The Federal Reserve and the FOMC
are "to promote effectively the goals of maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate
long-term interest rates." Many analysts believe that achieving price stability should be the
primary goal of a central bank because a stable level of prices appears to be the condition
most conducive to maximum sustained output and employment, and to moderate long-term
interest rates. This presumably is because in times of price stability the prices of goods,
materials and services are undistorted by inflation and thus can serve as clearer signals and
guides for the efficient allocation of resources. Also, a background of stable prices is thought
to encourage capital formation because it reduces the distortion created by a tax system that
is only partly indexed for inflation. Some would argue that the remarkable period of growth
that we are experiencing is due in no small measure to the low rate of inflation that has
prevailed for some time.
The problem with the rather neat formulation that I have just given is that it does not include
an element of time. In the long run, I have no doubt that price stability underpins efforts to
achieve maximum output and employment. But, in the short run, some tensions can arise
between efforts to reduce inflation and efforts to maximize employment and output. For
example, the economy may at times be faced with adverse developments affecting supply,
such as a bad agricultural harvest or a disruption in the supply of oil, which put upward
pressure on prices and downward pressure on output and employment. In these
circumstances, makers of monetary policy must decide the extent to which we should focus
on defusing price pressures or on cushioning the loss of output and employment in the short

run, while still keeping an eye on our long-term objectives. At other times, policymakers
may be concerned that expectations of inflation will get built into decisions about wages and
prices and, become a self-fulfilling prophecy. Countering this threat of inflation with a more
restrictive monetary policy could risk small losses of output and employment in the short run
but might make it possible to avoid larger losses later should expectations of higher inflation
become embedded in the economy.
The press tries to categorize FOMC members as "hawks" and "doves." These labels are an
effort to simplify, in fact oversimplify, the complex choices that each member of the FOMC
must make in deciding how to trade off the risk that action, or inaction, on our part will lead
to inflation heating up to unacceptable levels, against the risk of having inadequate creation
of jobs. But I believe that all members of the Committee recognize that, over the longer haul,
the major contribution the Federal Reserve can make to higher standards of living is to
promote price stability.
It is generally thought that monetary policy takes many months to have most of its effect on
the growth of output and employment, while, of course, it has an immediate impact on
financial markets. Because of the long time-frame in which the effects on the real economy
are realized, I believe that it is important for policy to look ahead as it aims at promoting
stable prices and a sustainable GDP growth path, along which the economy is at full
potential.
Given that we need to be forward-looking, or "preemptive," as it is often put, one potentially
important element in making monetary policy is the forecast or likely outlook for economic
growth, unemployment and the price level for the next year or two. Fortunately, as we make
monetary policy we have the advantage of several forecasts. The staff of the Board of
Governors, private-sector economists, and the staffs of the Federal Reserve Banks make
forecasts. Some individual Governors and Reserve Bank Presidents also have considerable
experience and expertise in forecasting.
To be useful for monetary policy, forecasts of the future health of the economy need to be
reasonably reliable. Good forecasts rest on the identification of empirical regularities that
can be confidently relied upon to provide guidance. Regrettably, some previously reliable
empirical relations have not proven so of late. As one example, the failure of price inflation
to pick up, as labor markets have become tighter is not consistent with the simple
correlations that were so apparent in earlier cycles. Moreover, factors outside of economists'
models have provided some surprises, such as the Asian economic and financial turmoil and
the gyration of oil prices.
If forecast relationships are less certain, it becomes more challenging to be "preemptive." In
these circumstances, I believe, it is appropriate to put greater weight on incoming data to
determine whether the stance of monetary policy should be changed. Some of the variables
relevant in this regard are: 1) the rate of change in wages or prices or early signs of emerging
inflation, 2) the level of the unemployment rate and the pace of job creation, 3) the rate and
composition of GDP growth (inventories, trade flows, consumption, investment, residential
and commercial construction, and so forth), and 4) international developments. Economists
refer to these variables as being from the "real" side of the economy. Another set of
variables to be considered in making monetary policy are financial variables, such as the
money supply, interest rates, exchange rates, credit flows, and conditions in bank lending
and in the debt and equity markets.

The last two years, 1997 and 1998, gave an interesting case study of the interplay between
these different variables and the degree of forward-looking behavior in the making of
monetary policy. From March of 1997 through much of 1998, pleasant surprises in the
performance of inflation and the general absence of early signs of inflation, and uncertainty
about the relationship of changes in inflation to the level of resource utilization, kept the
FOMC from tightening. We did not tighten despite the economy being beyond most
estimates of its potential and despite many forecasts of rising inflation. Put another way, the
FOMC could have "preemptively" tightened monetary policy, based on forecasts, but
recognizing the uncertainties about empirical relationships chose not to do so.
Indeed, monetary policy was eased in the fall of 1998. You may recall, there was
considerable concern last autumn regarding the performance of the debt markets, especially
the markets for corporate bonds and commercial paper. These concerns were centered
around a seizing up in those markets that raised significantly the cost of funds to some
borrowers and prevented some others from entering the market at all. Given the situation,
we were reasonably confidant that constraints on the ability of corporations to borrow would
eventually have a negative effect on their willingness to invest in productive capacity and,
therefore, on their ability to provide goods and services and to create jobs. A related concern
was that weakened foreign economies, associated with the financial turmoil, might have
adverse consequences on future domestic activity. Under those circumstances, the FOMC
thought it appropriate to ease policy to offset a likely significant impact on future domestic
spending and growth.
Finally, no discussion of monetary policy and financial markets would be complete without
reference to the equity markets. I believe that the Fed cannot target specific levels in equity
markets. However, equity markets have spillover effects into the real economy, and hence,
send important signals to policymakers. As you know, economists often speak of the "wealth
effect," and econometric modeling indicates that consumers tend to raise the level of their
spending somewhere around 2 percent to 5 percent of incremental stock market wealth,
after two or three years. As a consequence, equity valuations can have a noticeable effect
on consumption and on macroeconomic performance. Additionally, equity markets are a
source of investment capital, and valuations in the stock market are one determinant of the
cost of capital for businesses. Therefore, equity prices have an influence on business fixed
investment, along with household consumption. Finally, equity markets are of interest to
policymakers because we have a responsibility for macro-stability. We have seen in other
economies that bubbles and busts in financial markets can create unsettled conditions that
impair real economic activity. Therefore, while it would be incorrect to say that
policymakers target the equity markets or that market concerns "tie the hands" of the Fed,
the markets are an important consideration in macroeconomic analysis.
These are just some of the factors that go into making monetary policy. The interesting part
of the job is that the relative importance of these factors--forecasts, current macroeconomic
conditions, financial market conditions and others--are often in flux. For those who seek to
monitor our actions, the good news is that, through a reading of FOMC announcements and
minutes, speeches by Governors and Presidents, and interviews, an observer can get a pretty
good handle on which variables are uppermost in each policymaker's mind at any given time.
Often, however, many factors are relevant, and we cannot indicate precisely the relative
weights that a group as diverse as the FOMC may be applying to them in making policy.
After all, the economy is influenced by all of the factors I have outlined, and the FOMC's
emphasis on specific factors varies over time as economic conditions change.

Outlook for 1999
With this general statement of the factors that go into setting monetary policy, let me turn to
the outlook for 1999. Economic data for the final quarter of 1998 and the first quarter of this
year were stronger than many had expected. Real GDP grew more than 4 percent in 1998,
on a fourth-quarter-to-fourth-quarter basis, and maintained that rapid growth into the first
quarter of this year. The consensus, as represented by the most recent Blue Chip Economic
Indicators, is that growth will be more moderate over the remainder of 1999, but that it will
still total nearly 3-1/4 percent or so for the year. This is a more upbeat view of the prospects
for activity than prevailed just a few months ago. One reason is that the international
economic landscape looks, if not perfect, at least a bit calmer than it did. The ability of
Brazil, with the financial assistance of the international community, to weather its exchange
rate crisis as well as it has to date, no doubt, has done much to allay some of the fears that
were present in late 1998 and early 1999. So, too, have the signs that a number of East Asian
economies have been able to commence the process of recovery, after their tremendous
difficulties. Finally, it is simply the case that many economists have come to the realization
that they underestimated the underlying strength of domestic demand here in the United
States-and the profitability of American businesses in that environment. The strength in
corporate profits in the first quarter not only impressed economists, but it also impressed
investors, who drove stock prices up earlier this year. That rise, through the effects I noted
earlier, should continue to support domestic demand in the months ahead.
The flip side of that coin is that the pressures on resources in the United States are greater
than it was anticipated they would be. This is especially true in the labor market, where
many firms continue to report that the short supply of labor is a major problem. But, again
underscoring an earlier point, this tightness of the labor market has not manifested itself in
ongoing escalation of wage inflation. Indeed, if anything, the trend of increase in wages and
overall compensation per hour has turned more favorable on average in recent quarters. A
number of factors seem to have been at work here, but I'll mention just two. First, we earlier
had seen a disproportionate contribution to the aggregate pay acceleration from the finance,
insurance, and real estate industry, and there has been some ebbing recently in those sectorsevidently reflecting a response to a peaking in some areas of activity, such as mortgage
refinancing. Second, and more fundamentally, it is quite possible that we are seeing a
pass-through of the more modest rates of price inflation we have enjoyed in the past couple
of years into decisions about nominal wage increases. Put simply, wages have not had to
increase as rapidly as in prior years just to cover a rising cost-of-living.
This is, of course, a very healthy development-one that we hope will be sustained going
forward, because it is central to the achievement of ongoing price stability. We must
recognize that there have been a number of factors behind the favorable price performance
we have been experiencing. In part, it is due to an increase in productivity, as businesses
have invested in high-tech equipment and adjusted the procedures of the workplace to get
the greatest benefit from those investments. This allows workers to become more productive
and receive higher pay, which businesses need not translate into higher prices in order to
remain profitable. However, the recent good news also reflects, in part, "special factors" that
we cannot assume will be repeated indefinitely. I might say that we would not even want
them to be repeated in some cases-the Asian economic crisis, for example. Moreover, we
have already seen some reversal of some of these factors, most notably the sharp rebound in
world oil prices and a surge in health insurance costs. Under the circumstances, we must be
concerned that, with the economy operating at such a high level of labor utilization and
growth robust, we might be in some jeopardy of setting the stage for a an upturn in inflation.

In our announcement after our May 18 meeting, the Federal Open Market Committee made
it clear that we are watching things very closely and stand prepared to act promptly if the
evidence begins to mount that inflationary pressures could be building.
Conclusion
The Federal Reserve has an important role to play in our economy. However, our role in the
economy should be kept in perspective. We control just a very few of the levers that drive
the economy. We observe developments in the economy and in financial markets and try to
adjust monetary policy to the signals that we receive so that our nation's economic welfare is
not threatened by inflation or by growth that persistently falls below the economy's
potential. However, it is the decisions and actions that you take as consumers and business
managers that ultimately determine the health of the U.S. economy. Despite difficult periods,
1998 turned out to be a very good year because of a mix of private action and economic
policy. I hope that 1999 will continue to be as good to us all.

Return to top
1999 Speeches
Home | News and events
Accessibility | Contact Us
Last update: June 10, 1999, 12:30 PM