View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

To the Andrew Brimmer Policy Forum: National Economic and Financial Policies for
Growth, Employment, and the Improvement of Equity, at the 2005 Annual Convention,
Allied Social Science Associations, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania
January 7, 2005

Interpreting Labor Market Statistics in the Context of Monetary Policy
In assessing the appropriate stance of monetary policy, policymakers must come to some
judgment about the likely future course of economic performance and, especially, of
inflation. To make this judgment, we find a useful concept to be the level of economic slack-defined as the difference between the current level of output and the level of output the
economy could produce if all available resources were fully utilized. In many standard
models of inflation, an economy operating above its potential is associated with upward
pressure on inflation, and an economy operating below its potential is associated with
downward pressure on inflation. Unfortunately, economic slack cannot be measured directly
but must instead be inferred from the variables we do observe.
Labor market measures have traditionally been a valuable source of information about
economic slack. In particular, statistics like the unemployment rate can tell us something
about the amount of available, but as yet unused, labor in the economy. But even this
relation--between the unemployment rate and the concept of economic slack--is not
necessarily constant, and thus a given unemployment rate may not indicate the same level of
slack at two separate times. For example, shifts in the composition of unemployed individuals
across different skill levels, industries, or occupations relative to the demand for workers with
these characteristics can complicate this relationship, as can changes in the behavior of the
individuals who are out of work.
Moreover, the possibility of a change in the relationship between the unemployment rate and
economic slack is likely to be greater--and thus the signals from the labor market may be
harder to read--when the labor market behaves atypically, as in many respects it has behaved
over the past three years. A particular question that is difficult to answer is whether the slow
recovery of employment has left significant underutilized resources in the economy that
could be readily re-employed, or whether the lag in hiring indicates that the supply of those
resources is relatively less forthcoming given the state of demand?
In this context, I would like to discuss two aspects of the recent labor market downturn that
have received considerable attention and that have the potential to alter the relation between
economic slack and the unemployment rate. The first is the possibility that the extended
weakness in the labor market reflects permanent shifts in the composition of jobs--which is
often referred to as industrial restructuring. The second development I will address is the
decline in labor force participation in recent years.1 I should note, my comments today reflect
only my views and should not be taken to represent the views of my colleagues on the Board
of Governors or in the Federal Reserve System.

Industrial Restructuring
I will begin by providing some background on the current labor market recovery. As shown in
chart 1, which plots the level of private payroll employment relative to its level at the end of
recessions, as dated by the NBER, and compares employment performances across
recoveries, the current recovery in employment has been unusually slow--well below the
average and even slower than during the “jobless recovery” of the early 1990s. This
relatively poor employment performance has been due primarily to weak job creation.
Though the rate of job destruction (chart 2, upper panel) rose at the beginning of the
recession, it soon dropped below that seen immediately before the recession. In contrast, the
pace of job creation (lower panel) continued to fall until the end of 2003, when employment
finally began to turn up. Finally, as chart 3 shows, the rise in the layoff rate since the end of
2000 has been due primarily to an increase in permanent layoffs.
To many observers, the coincidence of a large share of permanent job losses and sluggish job
creation indicates a pronounced shift in the optimal allocation of workers across firms or
industries--that is, an elevated pace of economic restructuring. The basic story is as follows:
Permanent reductions in employment in declining industries require workers to search for
new jobs, a process made difficult and more time consuming by the likelihood that the skills
these workers acquired on their previous jobs may be ill-suited to sectors of the economy in
which labor demand is rising. Although some workers may accept whatever job is available-whether or not it meets their longer-run expectations for wages, benefits, or stability--our
unemployment insurance system provides enough protection that many will search longer for
a good match and thus remain out of work longer. Moreover, creating new jobs in expanding
industries requires businesses to invest, and the most recent recovery was marked, for some
time, by a reluctance of businesses to do so. A slowing in the pace of job creation resulted in
limited new opportunities available to these displaced workers. Though these stories sound
plausible, restructuring is, in practice, difficult to measure, and alternative measurement
techniques have led to very different conclusions about the amount of restructuring that has
occurred in recent years.2
Taking a somewhat different approach than previous analyses, we attempted to identify those
industries that have performed especially poorly since the 2001 business cycle peak and
assess whether these underperforming industries have been characterized by restructuring.
We judged the performance of each industry according to two criteria: (1) an industry’s net
employment change from March 2001 to November 2004, and (2) the change in an industry’s
share of total employment between March 2001 and November 2004 compared with the
change in employment shares exhibited over a pre-peak period of similar length.3
Table 1 ranks the performance of two-digit NAICS industries since March 2001 according to
the first measure of underperformance. In an absolute sense, the poorest performing
industries include durable and nondurable manufacturing, the information sector, retail trade,
transportation and warehousing, and professional and technical services. Moreover, four of
those six industries--durable manufacturing, information, transportation and warehousing, and
professional and technical services--also ranked among the six poorest performers according
to the second criterion, which is based on relative performance.
Table 1
Underperforming Industries in Terms of the Change in Employment since the Latest
Cyclical Peak (March 2001)

Industry
Durable manufacturing
Nondurable manufacturing
Information
Retail trade
Transportation and warehousing
Professional and technical services
Wholesale trade
Company management
Utilities
Natural resources and mining
Arts, entertainment, and recreation
Real estate and leasing
Construction
Administrative support and waste
Other
Finance and insurance
Education
Accommodations and food services
Health care and social assistance

Performance Ranking1
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19

Note: Underlined industries ranked poorly according to both measures of underperformance
1. A higher rank indicates worse performance. Return to table
Anecdotally, most of these industries can be associated with elements of restructuring. Within
the information industry, for example, telecommunications has suffered from
overcapacity--and significant downsizings or business failures--since the cyclical peak.
Similarly, transportation includes the airline industry in which many firms have been under
stress, and professional and technical services includes several industries that complement
business investment and likely suffered in the wake of the sharp slowing in spending on
equipment and software early this decade. Within durable goods manufacturing, computers
and electronics, primary and fabricated metals, and machinery rank particularly poorly
according to our criteria of underperformance, and these industries have also been identified
with restructuring in recent years.
Corroborating this anecdotal evidence, the durable manufacturing, information, and
professional and technical services industries are also among the top six contributors to the
post-peak increase in the aggregate permanent layoff rate. These underperformers are also at
the top of the list of industries that experienced significant rates of job destruction during the
labor market downturn of 2001 and 2002. In fact, the four industries that, according to our
two criteria, were the key underperformers in recent years more than accounted for the
overall increase in the average pace of job destruction between 1998-2000 and 2001-02.
Finally, the relationship between our measures of underperformance and industry
productivity growth is also informative about the importance of restructuring. Typically,

productivity falls with employment in recessions, as firms--hesitant to sever ties to workers
who will be valuable to them when demand recovers--reduce employment less than output.
However, if firms perceive changes in demand to be permanent, the reluctance to reduce
employment in proportion to output should diminish. In fact, productivity growth from 2000
to 2002 in the four key underperforming industries was not lower, on average, than in
industries not experiencing large reductions in labor demand, supporting the notion that firms
in these industries believed demand changes to have been permanent. Moreover, labor
market underperformance, in general, was associated with slightly greater productivity
growth between 2000 and 2002; this association suggests that underperforming industries
reacted to changes in labor demand by destroying their least productive jobs--which is also
consistent with the restructuring hypothesis.
If our hypothesis that restructuring is associated with our four key underperforming industries
is correct, the influence of this restructuring on aggregate labor market outcomes would be
substantial. These industries, though together composing just 25 percent of private
employment, accounted for net job losses totaling nearly 2.6 million from the March 2001
business cycle peak through November 2004 (compared with a net decline of 1.2 million jobs
for the private sector as a whole) and for about half the deterioration in the average monthly
employment change over this period relative to the average pace before the peak.
Given this evidence that restructuring has been a notable feature of the labor market
landscape in recent years, it is also worth assessing the relevance of some possible
explanations for the high proportion of permanent job losses over this period. These
explanations include technological change, international competition, offshoring of less
productive jobs, and large industry-specific demand shocks, perhaps related to the 2001
terrorist attacks or the earlier overoptimism in the high-tech sector.
To gauge the importance of these various explanations, we first examined the relationship
between industry employment and industry output using data for sixty three-digit NAICS
industries. As can be seen in chart 4, which plots the change in employment shares from 2000
to 2002 against the change in value added shares over the same period, there is a strong
positive correlation between these changes, both for all industries and for the subset of
industries that make up the four restructuring sectors we identified previously. In the chart,
industries in this subset, designated with an R, are bunched in the lower left quadrant--an
indication that most experienced declines in both employment and output shares over this
period. These positive correlations suggest that restructuring has been caused mainly by
adverse industry demand shocks rather than by positive supply shocks, although as I will
highlight later, there are some exceptions.
One possible source of these adverse demand shocks is increased international trade. To
assess the potential relationship between international trade and restructuring, we examined
correlations between changes in import and export shares and changes in employment shares
for two-digit manufacturing industries for the period from the start of the recession to the
third quarter of 2004. We found it difficult to discern any clear relationship in the data; this
lack of clear relationship suggests that international trade has not been an important
determinant of the recent pattern of underperformance in the labor market. Martin Baily and
Robert Lawrence (2004) present a much more thorough analysis of this issue and come to a
similar conclusion.4
To investigate further the relationship between restructuring and labor productivity, we
compared the performance of industry employment to the performance of industry

productivity for the period from 2000 to 2002 (chart 5). The fact that some industries
experienced large declines in employment share and well-above-average gains in productivity
suggests that adverse demand shocks may not be the only source of restructuring. Indeed,
these industries include computer systems design, information and data-processing services,
and publishing (which includes software)--all high-tech categories that have been associated
either with positive technology shocks or with the outsourcing of low-productivity jobs.
Overall, the evidence points to several tentative conclusions. First, although a period of
permanent employment declines is admittedly difficult to distinguish from an extended period
of cyclical weakness, the data, on balance, seem to indicate that restructuring has been an
important characteristic of the post-2000 labor market downturn. Second, except for a few
high-tech industries, restructuring appears to have been caused primarily by adverse shifts in
the demand for the output of restructuring industries rather than by positive supply shocks.
Finally, any slowing of the current labor market recovery from restructuring, if indeed
restructuring has played such a part, has likely been due to a slow transition of workers from
restructuring industries to expanding industries rather than a slow pace of restructuring in
declining industries. The last conclusion is based on the absence of a positive relation
between employment share changes and industry productivity growth and on the high rates of
job destruction in underperforming industries, both of which suggest that restructuring
industries responded aggressively to adverse demand shocks.
Labor Force Participation
As I noted at the outset, a second anomaly that may have influenced the recent relationship
between the unemployment rate and economic slack is the behavior of the labor force
participation rate. Although the participation rate--adjusted for trend movements--tends to
decrease when job prospects are poor, recent declines have well exceeded the cyclical norm.
In addition, though the unemployment rate has fallen since the middle of 2003, the
participation rate currently remains near the low point reached in the first half of 2004.
Together, these facts raise the question of whether economic slack is being reflected
increasingly in the participation rate rather than in the unemployment rate. The answer to this
question hinges on whether the recent declines in participation have been due to cyclical or to
more-permanent factors.
Distinguishing very long-term or permanent changes in labor supply from cyclical movements
is difficult, but some information can be brought to bear on this issue. First, demographic
changes seem not to be an important explanation of the decline in the participation rate. In
general, one might expect the aging baby-boom generation to put downward pressure on the
participation rate, as this cohort moves into their retirement years during which participation
rates have traditionally been lower. Although this possibility is clearly a concern for the
future, changes in the age composition of the population have, thus far, not accounted for
much of the drop in the participation rate. Instead, the low participation rate reflects
pronounced declines in participation rates for a number of demographic groups, most notably
teenagers and young adults, as well as individuals between the ages of 25 and 44.
In addition, as can be seen in chart 6, the timing of the downturn in labor force participation
lines up closely with the weakening of economic activity that began in the second half of
2000. This concordance suggests that the recent weakness in participation is more likely to be
associated with this business cycle than with an emerging downward trend, although one
obviously cannot rule that out.
Finally, we can perhaps learn something from the reasons that individuals give for being out

of the labor force. As shown in chart 7, the proportion of the population who say that they
are out of the labor force because they cannot find a job has increased only slightly. Instead,
the rise in nonparticipation since 2000 is associated with an increase in the proportions of
individuals attending school, reporting themselves as ill or disabled, or retired. Whether these
patterns are more indicative of cyclical or of structural changes in participation is difficult to
pin down, however. Although the absence of a sizable increase in discouraged workers might
be viewed as evidence against a cyclical interpretation, the rise in school enrollment may
reflect a decline in the opportunity cost of attending school associated with the lack of new
job opportunities in a weak labor market. Similarly, the increase in disability rates--or even, to
some extent, retirement rates--could have both cyclical and structural elements.
In sum, the available information is far from definitive. The absence of any clear
demographic shift suggests that at least some portion of the unusually large declines in labor
force participation has been associated with this business cycle. Nevertheless, individuals
who have recently exited the labor force likely have weaker ties to the labor market than
currently unemployed individuals. Thus, it is an open question how quickly, if at all, recent
increases in nonparticipation due to schooling, disability, or retirement will be reversed.
Restructuring and Participation
As the number of puzzles concerning the labor market increases, so does the complexity of
analysis necessary to relate observed variables to concepts relevant for monetary policy.
Thus, it seems worthwhile to ask whether restructuring and the decline in participation might
be part of the same phenomenon. Such a relation does not seem implausible. As I noted
previously, restructuring destroys human capital specific to firms and industries and thus can
significantly reduce the job opportunities available to some workers. As the benefit to
remaining in the labor market falls, these individuals may become discouraged or choose to
spend their time on activities outside the labor market, one of which may be schooling or
retraining to prepare for future reentry to the labor force.
To investigate this possibility further, we examined data from the most-recent displaced
worker survey. Table 2 shows the proportions of displaced workers from restructuring and
nonrestructuring industries (according to our classification scheme), as well as the shares of
employment for these two groups of industries.5 Qualitatively, the data are similar to those I
have already presented: Displaced workers come disproportionately from restructuring
industries. Of course, since more than half of displaced workers come from other industries,
restructuring at the industry level is, by no means, the only cause of worker displacement. It
is also true that displaced workers were more likely than other job losers to have been out of
the labor force in January 2004. Putting these facts together, it would not be unreasonable to
infer a linkage between restructuring and the decline in the participation rate.
Table 2
Distribution of Employment and of Displaced Workers by Industry Category
Industry
Employment
Displaced Workers
Restructuring
23.1
42.2
Nonrestructuring
76.9
57.8
Total
100
100
Source: Displaced Worker Supplement to the CPS.
The Labor Market and Monetary Policy

Let me conclude my talk as I began it, stressing the importance to monetary policy of
measuring economic slack. As I’ve discussed, how much slack is indicated by the
unemployment rate and other labor market data depends both on the extent of industrial
restructuring and on the causes of the recent sharp declines in labor force participation. I
believe that restructuring has been a visible part of the recent downturn and that much of the
recent unusual behavior of labor force participation reflects cyclical forces. However, how
we should adjust our interpretation of the unemployment rate as a measure of economic slack
depends on the magnitudes of these effects, about which much uncertainty remains.
In such a situation, I view the conduct of monetary policy as a balancing of risks. One risk is
that industrial restructuring has been quite extensive. Because restructuring decreases the
value of human capital that is specific to downsizing industries, it acts, in effect, as a negative
supply shock, temporarily depressing the level of employment as the workers displaced by
restructuring must either search longer to find a job appropriate for their skills or seek
retraining. An additional risk is that declines in labor force participation have been
predominantly structural, so that many of the individuals who have exited the labor force
over the past three years will be unlikely to return, at least in the near-term. Under such
conditions, the amount of economic slack could be very small, and thus expansive monetary
policy could lead to a pickup in inflationary pressures.
Alternatively, restructuring, though ongoing, may have resulted in relatively little mismatch
between the skills needed in restructuring industries and the skills demanded in expanding
industries and, thus, should not impede job creation. In addition, although the prolonged slow
recovery in hiring may have taken a greater toll on worker confidence than in earlier cycles,
those workers who have recently exited the labor force may not have significantly reduced
their availability for work. In this scenario, a substantial pool of unused labor may remain in
the labor market, and an overly restrictive monetary policy would prevent the economy from
moving as quickly as possible to the level of full employment.
As you can see, transforming the information available from published statistics into concepts
useful for assessing the consequences of monetary policy is, in fact, quite complex. And, the
evidence is more ambiguous than one would like, indicating that it would be unwise to
assume that labor market indicators are complete predictors of slack. Nevertheless, I believe
that our ability to interpret labor market statistics will continue to benefit greatly from
additional research on the topics I have discussed today and from the exchange of ideas that
this type of forum encourages.
Charts

Return to text

Return to text

Return to text

Return to text

Return to text

Return to text

Return to text
References
Aaronson, Daniel, Ellen R. Rissman, and Daniel G. Sullivan (2004). “Can Sectoral
Reallocation Explain the Jobless Recovery?” (997 KB PDF) Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago, Economic Perspectives, vol. 28 (Second Quarter), pp. 36-49.
Baily, Martin Neil, and Robert Z. Lawrence (2004). “What Happened to the Great U.S. Job
Machine? The Role of Trade and Electronic Offshoring,” paper presented at the Brookings
Panel on Economic Activity, Brookings Institution, Washington, September.
Groshen, Erica L., and Simon Potter (2003). “Has Structural Change Contributed to a Jobless
Recovery?” Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Current Issues in Economics and Finance,
vol. 9 (August), pp. 1-7.
Footnotes
1. My presentation today is based on work with Andrew Figura, Bruce Fallick, and William
Wascher. Return to text
2. For example, both Groshen and Potter (2003) and Aaronson, Rissman, and Sullivan (2004)

construct summary measures of the extent of restructuring. While the Groshen-Potter
measure shows an elevated level of restructuring in recent years, the Aaronson-RissmanSullivan measure indicates that the labor market has not experienced an unusual amount of
restructuring recently. These authors will present updates of their earlier research at these
meetings. Return to text
3. The latter measure helps to distinguish industries that are in long-term decline (for
example, textiles) from the industries that may have experienced a more recent episode of
restructuring. It also allows us to identify those industries that have had upward trends but
that have experienced a period of relatively weak job growth in recent years. Return to text
4. The criteria we use to identify restructuring industries are not designed to capture
long-standing restructuring associated with foreign competition, such as in the textile
industry. Also, both anecdotal evidence and the Bailey and Lawrence study suggest that
foreign competition in the past couple of years has been an important factor for some
industries. Return to text
5. Displaced workers are defined here as those individuals who, at some point between 2001
and 2003, permanently lost a job on which they had at least three years of tenure. Return to
text
Return to top
2005 Speeches
Home | News and events
Accessibility | Contact Us
Last update: January 7, 2005