View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

At the European Institute Roundtable on Financial and Monetary Affairs, Washingotn,
D.C.
April 23, 2004

Global Imbalances
I am pleased to participate in a discussion with such distinguished colleagues and to share
my thoughts about some key issues confronting economic policy makers. As you are all well
aware, the global economy is becoming ever more tightly knit, with national economies
increasingly drawn together through trade and financial market transactions--all facilitated
by continuing advances in telecommunications and related technologies. The economic
slowdown that the U.S. economy entered in 2001 was shared by Europe, East Asia, and
Latin America. Similarly, the revival in growth that our economy has enjoyed since the
middle of last year has also shown up, to greater and lesser degrees, in other parts of the
world.
Although growth rates in different regions of the global economy are somewhat
synchronous, such shared movements in output do not ensure that external deficits or
surpluses will remain small. With the United States now running a current account deficit
equal to about 5 percent of the gross domestic product, the rest of the world must run a
correspondingly large net current account surplus. And when the U.S. deficit starts to
decline, then trade flows abroad will adjust as well, reducing their overall surplus.
Because of its size and persistence, as well as recent declines in the value of the dollar, the
U.S. current account balance is receiving an extraordinary amount of attention at present.
Observers routinely ask the following questions: Is the deficit unusually, or even abnormally,
large? How long can it be sustained? How might a correction of the deficit affect the United
States and its trading partners, including Europe? One must always be mindful of the
possibility that the inevitable adjustment process related to global imbalances may be
disorderly, but the tone of these questions is often more pessimistic than I think is warranted.
Nevertheless, these questions are important, and I will devote the remainder of my remarks
to addressing them.
Is the U.S. current account deficit "abnormal"?
The economics profession has no consensus model to tell us, for a given economy, what the
appropriate level of the current account balance is. At best, economists can agree on some
general principles. I will emphasize only two. First, current account imbalances allow
countries to smooth consumption over time, for example, in response to the ups and downs
of the world price of a major export. Second, current account imbalances--which represent
the difference between domestic savings and domestic investment--allow savings to be
allocated to those parts of the world where they can be invested most productively.
On the basis of these considerations, some analysts have argued that industrial countries

should run current account surpluses and invest their abundant savings in developing
countries, which, being labor-rich and capital-poor, would offer higher rates of return.
However, examples of high or persistent current account deficits abound among
industrialized economies, including Canada (averaging 2.5 percent of GDP from 1975
through 1998), the United Kingdom (1.9 percent of GDP from 1984 through 2003), and
Australia (4.1 percent of GDP from 1974 through 2003). Global investors have confidence
that in countries such as these as well as in the United States they can safely seek the highest
possible return for their funds.
Some of the factors that lie behind such confidence are political stability, a legal system that
effectively protects property rights and enforces commercial contracts, economic policies
that promote and strengthen the role of markets, a financial system that efficiently channels
resources to their most productive uses, and an educational system that produces highly
skilled workers and supports rapid technological development. These elements are present in
many mature economies, including those of the United States and Europe.
Rates of return on investments in the United States have also been driven by the rapid
diffusion of technological innovation. Labor productivity in the United States accelerated to
a rate of about 3 percent in the period 1996-2003. Over the same period, smoothing through
the recent cycle, the value of U.S. equities rose about 80 percent compared with 60 percent
for European equities and a decline of 30 percent for Japanese. These developments attest to
the expansion of favorable investment opportunities in the United States. Thus, it is neither
surprising nor abnormal that, beginning in the mid-1990s, capital flows to the United States-primarily in the form of direct investment and equity inflows--began to pick up substantially,
including, importantly, investment flows from Europe. These capital inflows exerted upward
pressure on the dollar and provided the financing for our widening current account deficit.
How long can the current account deficit be sustained?
To say that a current account deficit is unsurprising or explainable is not to say that it is
sustainable in the long run. With the net external debt of the United States rising more
rapidly than GDP, some narrowing of the deficit is inevitable. However, such shrinkage does
not mean that the current account deficit will be eliminated. Moreover, to say that the
current account deficit cannot stay large on a permanent basis is not to say just when or how
adjustment will occur.
One can envision several developments that could trigger adjustment, many of which would
be very positive for the global economy. A pickup in perceived rates of return abroad could
divert capital flows from the United States to other countries and prompt adjustments in
external balances. In Europe, for example, a considerable expansion in the use of
information technologies in recent years has not, to date, appreciably boosted growth rates
of labor productivity. It is conceivable that such high-tech investments may finally lead to
higher productivity growth, further boosting investment spending, and weakening trade
performance, as occurred in the United States in the 1990s. In Japan, corporate and financial
sector restructuring appears to be making gains. In Latin America, improved policies and
more flexible exchange rates may set the stage for renewed capital inflows. And in Asia, a
revival of domestic demand could give the authorities confidence that, if they allow capital
inflows to strengthen their currencies and narrow their current account surpluses, high rates
of economic growth will be maintained.
Even if rival sources of demand for global capital do not emerge, another factor that would
induce adjustment of the current account, if it were to occur, would be a diminishing

appetite for additional U.S. assets and, therefore, a reduced willingness to finance the deficit.
One cannot know whether or at what point such concerns might become pressing. However,
by several measures, the imprint of U.S. financing needs on global capital markets has not
been so large as to be problematic. At roughly 25 percent of GDP, the net external debt of
the United States is still below that of several other industrial economies, including the
Netherlands (30 percent), Finland (40 percent), and Australia (60 percent). Moreover, even
though the United States has been a net debtor since 1986, the net income on the
international investment position has remained positive, as the rate of return on U.S.
investments abroad continues to exceed that on foreign investments in the United States.
From the standpoint of investor portfolios, notwithstanding years of large current account
deficits, the share of U.S. equities in global equities actually fell from 49 percent in 1997 to
47 percent in 2002; the U.S. share in the global bond market moved up only marginally
during the same period, from 42 percent to 44 percent.
Finally, current account adjustment may be prompted by increases in U.S. saving. Concerns
about the expanding budget deficit may prompt some reining in of fiscal policy, leading to a
reduction of public sector dissaving. In the private sector, personal saving rates remain
extremely low by historical standards and thus may revert to earlier norms at some point.
Either of these developments would boost total domestic savings and, all else being equal,
cut into the current account deficit.
Although we cannot know the time frame over which capital flows may begin to shift or U.S.
demand for imports to lessen, so far there appears to have been no loss of appetite for dollardenominated assets. The dollar has declined since early 2002, but net private capital inflows
have remained strong. In the first two months of this year, net private foreign purchases of
U.S. securities, which are admittedly volatile, averaged about $60 billion, well above the $33
billion monthly pace reached in 2001 and 2002, when the dollar was much higher. Moreover,
while I am not privy to their plans, I note that foreign authorities, who are increasingly large
holders of dollars, currently show few signs of substantially adjusting the composition of
their balance sheets.
How might a current account adjustment affect the U.S. and global economies?
If a substantial current account adjustment is required, how might it take place, and what
might be its effects? As to the first of these questions, three mechanisms might induce a
narrowing of the current account deficit.
First, a fall of U.S. prices below foreign prices could raise our competitiveness. Prices have
become relatively stable, by historical standards, in the United States and its trading partners,
however, and, it is not clear how much of a dent this could put in the trade deficit. A second
possibility is that an increase of foreign growth above U.S. growth could boost our exports.
Between 1970 and 1995, foreign GDP growth, weighted by U.S. trade, exceeded U.S.
growth by nearly 2/3 percentage point annually; since then, U.S. growth has exceeded
foreign growth by 1/4 percentage point. Thus, there is some potential for foreign growth to
rise relative to U.S. growth. Finally, price adjustments through exchange rate adjustment, by
encouraging exports and making imports more costly, could play a role in current account
adjustment.
I must emphasize that, no matter how the U.S. external imbalance is narrowed, the level and
composition of demand, both in the United States and abroad, would have to change. Such a
change, in turn, would require adjustments of relative prices. In the United States, to
accommodate increases in exports relative to imports, changes in relative prices would be

needed to shift production toward internationally traded goods and services and to shift
consumption toward nontraded goods and services. By the same token, adjustment by our
trading partners to a reduction in the U.S. current account deficit would require both an
increased domestic demand to maintain the overall level of economic activity and an
adjustment of relative prices to raise the share of nontraded goods in production and of
traded goods in consumption.
The prospect of a correction in the current account is often portrayed in ominous tones, a
dark storm cloud looming on the economic horizon. Yet, the economic adjustments I have
just described are both feasible and, properly managed, need not lead to undue distress,
either in the United States or abroad. After the dollar correction of the mid-1980s, for
example, economic activity in the United States continued to expand as the growth of
domestic demand eased but was replaced by strong contributions from net exports. During
that period, analogous adjustments helped to maintain economic performance among our
trading partners. The pace of GDP growth in the foreign G7 economies, weighted by U.S.
exports, increased from about 2-1/2 percent during 1982-84 to nearly 4 percent in 1985-87
as greater domestic demand growth compensated for weaker performance in net exports.
U.S. current account adjustment could, in fact, be associated with quite favorable scenarios
for the global economy. For example, the rise in foreign productivity growth that I touched
on earlier could work through several channels to narrow the U.S. trade deficit as funds were
attracted abroad. Strong domestic demand among our trading partners would likely outweigh
any drag resulting from appreciation of their currencies, while U.S. exports would benefit
from both a change in relative prices and stronger foreign growth.
Of course, the financial press frequently points to less-favorable scenarios, including the
so-called disorderly correction, that is, a rapid fall in the dollar that engenders a steep falloff
in U.S. bond and equity prices and that perhaps disrupts other national markets as well. I
have seen little evidence to suggest that this scenario is likely, notwithstanding its popularity.
The fall in the dollar since early 2002 has not disrupted financial markets, nor did the dollar's
previous correction in the 1980s. Moreover, most U.S. external debt is in dollars, so currency
depreciation is unlikely to lead to the balance-sheet problems that arise during financial
crises in developing countries, although obviously some parties that have not taken
precautions would take losses.
That said, central bankers are paid to be prudent and watchful, and we will obviously
continue to monitor closely international financial markets and their effects on the U.S.
economy. Looking ahead, I see no obvious indications that the external sector poses
significant concerns for growth or stability. Not only has the decline in the dollar to date
failed to disrupt U.S. financial markets, but most would judge that, on balance, it has had
only modest effects on inflation. Consumer spending is continuing to rise strongly and,
although activity in housing markets has eased a bit, on balance, from the brisk pace of late
last year, both sales and construction remain at high levels. In the business sector, spending
on equipment and software appears to be increasing quite strongly, although outlays for
nonresidential structures have remained weak. As has been the case over the past half-year,
because of sizable increases in productivity, businesses seem to be able to boost production
without adding much to their payrolls. Going forward, policy makers will have to determine
whether the improvements signaled in some recent labor market measures indicate that the
economy is on a sustainable path to closing the pool of underutilized resources. Although it
has depressed job creation in the short run, increasing productivity is positive for the
economy's long-run outlook and the creation of wealth. Due, in part, to these same increases

in productivity, inflationary pressures have generally been muted. Now the process of
disinflation appears to have ceased, and inflation has apparently stabilized. However, we
cannot be complacent regarding inflation and inflation expectations. Should the Federal
Reserve conclude that the maintenance of price stability is in jeopardy, I am confident that it
will act appropriately.
Conclusion
To conclude, a change in the tone of international financial markets that required a
substantial adjustment of the U.S. current account would obviously have important
implications for spending and economic activity, both here and abroad. However, such
adjustment, properly handled, need not derail the global economy nor cloud the bright
prospects that the United States and Europe--linked by myriad ties of commerce,
communications, culture, and political tradition--share.
Return to top
2004 Speeches
Home | News and events
Accessibility | Contact Us
Last update: April 23, 2004