View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

At the Conference on Trade and the Future of American Workers, Washington, D.C.
October 7, 2004
Free Trade: What Do Economists Really Know?
The role of trade in the U.S. economy has moved well into the spotlight in recent years, and I
am pleased to be here today to share my thoughts on this important topic with such
distinguished and knowledgeable colleagues. Over the course of this day, you will be hearing
from leading analysts, policymakers, and commentators about recent developments in the
U.S. economy, past and prospective trends in job creation, the role of sourcing (both outand in-), and the implications of trade for the coming elections. In my remarks this morning,
I would like to put these issues into the broader context of the debate over free trade and its
implications for the American economy.
Though my focus will be on free trade, we must remember that prospects for the average
American depend on many other factors as well, including technological progress, the
education required to exploit this progress, a dynamic market-oriented economy, a
framework of limited but effective regulation, healthy and well-governed financial
institutions, and a stable macroeconomic environment. And free trade is not necessarily the
most important item on this list. Even so, it has been a focus of interest and aspiration for
economists dating back to Adam Smith and David Ricardo. As you know, finding
overwhelming agreement on issues is difficult among economists, but free trade is an
exception.1
The supporters of free trade have not been ignored. In the past half-century, global trade has
become freer and has expanded rapidly. The ratio of trade (exports plus imports) to
worldwide gross domestic product rose from only 16 percent in 1960 to 40 percent by 2001.
In 1960, the United States, Germany, and Japan had average tariff rates of around 7 percent;
these rates were more than halved by 1993. The number of members of the World Trade
Organization (WTO), or its predecessor, the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, rose
from 18 in 1948 to 146 in 2003, and the number of regional trade agreements in the world
ballooned from only 1 in 1958 to 161 in 2003.
Although most economists welcome these trends, the public at large has been much more
ambivalent about international trade. Attitudes toward free trade in principle remain
generally positive, but a substantial--and, perhaps, growing--minority of Americans hold
more negative views. According to a poll completed around the beginning of this year, 41
percent of respondents viewed the process of increasing international trade through
reduction of barriers as proceeding too quickly; this number was up from 30 percent in 1999.
And 43 percent of respondents believed that the government should try to slow or reverse
the expansion of international trade, up from 39 percent in 1999.2
What accounts for the apparent deterioration in public support for free trade over the past
five years? The widening of the U.S. trade deficit may have exacerbated concerns about the

country's international competitiveness. More important, some have blamed overseas
competition for the job losses associated with the economic slowdown earlier in this decade.
Without solid public support for free trade, achieving continued progress in reducing
protectionist barriers, both at home and abroad, may become more difficult. In the
remainder of my remarks, I'd like to review the arguments for and against free trade, explore
why it has been difficult to muster more widespread public support for this goal, and address
some of the consequences of trade protection as it has been implemented in practice.
Arguments for Free Trade
International trade contributes to prosperity and growth through several channels. These
channels are not especially subtle or esoteric, and I would argue that the public at large
understands them reasonably well. At the same time, however, quantifying the contributions
of trade to national welfare is by no means straightforward.
First, and most obviously, trade increases the variety of goods available to consumers. Trade
provides some products that otherwise would be beyond the reach of most American
households, such as roses for Valentine's Day, or peaches and nectarines during the winter.
More generally, international trade allows us to choose from a wider array of goods than
would otherwise be available: Japanese and German cars in addition to American, Chilean
apples as well as Washington state, French and Australian wine as well as Californian. It is
difficult to put a dollar figure on the value of this increased variety to the consumer, but
estimates range as high as nearly 3 percent of GDP.3
A second benefit of international trade is its role in reducing the cost of goods and hence in
raising our standard of living. To anyone who has walked into a large discount store and
surveyed the range of low-priced items produced in any number of distant economies, this
benefit is abundantly clear. However, actually measuring the extent to which trade holds
down consumer costs is tricky. Between 1990 and 2003, for example, the overall consumer
price index rose 41 percent, whereas prices declined for many highly traded goods, including
toys (whose prices fell 26 percent), televisions (53 percent), and clocks and lamps (15
percent); in just the past five years, the price of telephones, calculators, and other such items
has fallen 42 percent. Yet, we do not know how much of the decline in these prices can be
attributed to trade, as most traded products are manufactures and are subject to greater
productivity growth (and hence steeper declines in costs) than nontraded products such as
services.
A more fruitful approach may be to compare the prices of goods that are protected from
international competition with what they would be in the absence of such barriers. A recent
study by the U.S. International Trade Commission indicates that sectoral trade liberalization
would lower the price of sugar for U.S. consumers by 8 percent, of apparel by 5 percent, and
of footwear and leather products by 4 percent.4 Clearly, if international trade were curtailed
for a much broader range of goods, the cost of living for American workers would be higher
and the standard of living correspondingly lower.
A third key benefit of free trade is that it allows economies to specialize in the activities they
do best. This notion was at the core of the classical economists' defense of free trade. By
allowing England to specialize in cloth production and Portugal in wine, for example,
international commerce leads to a higher income for both countries than if each tried to
produce both goods for themselves. By the same token, no American today would object to
trade between Massachusetts and Montana, or between Alaska and Alabama--the various

U.S. states obviously have their own comparative advantages in producing a variety of
different products, and trade among them makes such specialization possible. Extending the
example of trade among states to trade among countries is not much of a stretch.
Can we measure the extent to which the specialization associated with free trade may boost
incomes and welfare? Such an estimate is obviously no simple thing to calculate. Economists
frequently use so-called computable general equilibrium models, often consisting of
hundreds of equations, to address this issue. A recent analysis of the effects of past trade
liberalizations on the U.S. economy puts the gains to U.S. welfare at about 1/2 percent of
GDP.5 A separate analysis of a hypothetical 33 percent reduction in trade barriers around
the world suggests it would raise welfare by 1-1/2 percent of global GDP.6
In addition to promoting specialization, trade boosts productivity through a fourth channel of
influence: opening the economy to heightened competition. This effect could occur either as
firms are spurred by foreign competitors to become more efficient, or as the least productive
firms are forced to close, thus raising the average level of productivity for the economy as a
whole. Again, most Americans likely recognize the importance of competition in boosting
performance--the ascendancy of Japanese automobiles, for example, has been cited as a
factor that has spurred Detroit to greater innovation and better quality. By heightening
competitive forces and thus incentives for productivity and innovation, international trade
has likely accelerated the process of "creative destruction" by which outdated and less
productive activities are replaced by new technologies and more dynamic enterprises.
Academic research supports the view that import competition has led U.S. manufacturing
firms to become more capital intensive;7 trade liberalization apparently has enhanced
productivity in some import-competing firms in foreign countries as well.8 Producing for
export markets may also yield dividends: Research suggests that exporters are more
productive than non-exporters in the same industry and that they grow more rapidly as
well.9 Finally, many studies suggest that countries that are more open to international trade
have enjoyed higher rates of economic growth.10 Our sad experience after adoption of the
Smoot-Hawley tariff of 1930, as well as the record of Latin America, India, and other
regions that experimented with "import-substituting industrialization," point to the
deterioration in economic performance that occurs when countries erect barriers to trade.11
Arguments against Free Trade
If the benefits conferred by international trade are reasonably straightforward, how can we
explain the apparent ambivalence toward trade picked up by recent surveys? Clearly, many
people view the benefits of free trade as being outweighed by its perceived costs.
One concern about free trade may be that it has given rise to large trade and current account
deficits, thereby adding to the nation's debt and putting future prosperity at risk. Now at
more than 5 percent of GDP, the current account deficit is in record territory, it is growing,
and it cannot be sustained indefinitely. We cannot foresee when the deficit will stop growing
and return to more-sustainable levels, through what mechanisms this adjustment will occur,
or whether this adjustment will be smooth or disruptive for financial markets and the
economy more generally. No matter how a correction of the external imbalance proceeds,
however, it will involve a range of adjustments to investment, saving, and asset prices, both
for the U.S. economy and for our trading partners. Research suggests that past corrections of
large external imbalances in industrial countries generally have occurred without crisis.12

Whether or not this will remain the case, I am confident that protectionism is not the
appropriate response to our growing current account deficit. The amount of current account
adjustment that would be gained from a given tightening of import controls is questionable.
Yet, it is certain that such actions would impose costs on the economy that would persist
long after concerns about the deficit dissipated.
A second concern about free trade that is frequently voiced, and probably a more important
one to many people, is that trade destroys American jobs and creates unemployment. The
same survey I mentioned earlier, showing a deterioration in general attitudes toward trade,
also indicated that 40 percent of respondents believed that trade barriers should be
maintained because of the threat to U.S. jobs, up from 31 percent in 1999.13
It is worth distinguishing among several variants of the concern about trade and jobs. The
first variant holds that the rise in imports lowers employment and raises the unemployment
rate by shifting jobs overseas. This claim is strongly contradicted both by theory and by
experience. Make no mistake: Import competition clearly has cost some American workers
their jobs and has caused them considerable hardship as a result. However, economywide
equilibrating forces, including monetary policy, ensure that over time such employment
losses are offset by gains elsewhere in the economy, so that the nationwide unemployment
rate averages around its equilibrium level. In fact, the inflow of foreign capital that finances
our trade deficit provides the funding for investment projects that employ U.S. workers just
as surely as does any other productive activity in the economy. Between 1960 and 2003, the
trade balance moved from a slight surplus to a deficit of 4-1/2 percent of GDP, and nominal
imports rose from about 4 percent of GDP to 14 percent--yet, the current unemployment
rate of about 5-1/2 percent is little changed from its 1960 level, while nonfarm private
employment has grown by more than 60 million jobs.14
It has also been suggested that import competition has caused a significant portion of the
decline in employment since the recession of 2001. Yet, the ratio of the nominal trade deficit
to GDP widened less than 1 percentage point between 2000 and 2003. Moreover, this
deterioration came entirely from a decline in the ratio of exports to GDP, from 11.2 percent
in 2000 to 9.5 percent in 2003; the ratio of imports to GDP actually declined about 1
percentage point over this period.
A second variant of the concern over trade and jobs is certainly valid: Import competition
can be highly disruptive and cause considerable pain for those who lose their jobs. One study
of worker displacement indicates that only about two-thirds of displaced workers found
another job within three years, and even when they were successful in finding full-time
work, the earnings of these workers on average declined 8 percent.15 Another study found
that job losers in industries facing heavy import competition were slightly less likely to be
reemployed, and suffered greater earnings losses, than workers who lost their jobs in
industries facing less import competition.16
We cannot and should not minimize the hardships of workers displaced by imports.
However, we must also keep in mind that their numbers are relatively small compared with
either the total labor force or even the total number of jobs lost in the United States.
Estimates of the gross number of jobs lost to imports vary, but one representative estimate
puts them at a bit more than 300,000 per year during the 1980s and 1990s.17 This number,
while hardly negligible, is dwarfed by the roughly 15 million job losses estimated to occur
each year in the United States. As our dynamic market economy evolves, it generates

substantial churning in labor markets as jobs are gained in some sectors and lost in others;
jobs gained and lost because of trade are only a small part of that process.
It is understandable that concerns about job losses from import competition may extend far
beyond their actual incidence in the labor market, given more general anxieties about
employment security among American workers. However, to echo a point that has been
made before, the proper response to the disruptions associated with trade is not to reduce
trade, but rather to ameliorate the pain associated with those disruptions through enhanced
assistance and retraining for displaced workers.
A final concern about trade that I would like to discuss is that import competition, whether
or not it affects the number of jobs, shifts the employment mix from high-quality jobs to
low-quality jobs. For example, critics have long held that international trade pushes workers
out of manufacturing jobs and into less desirable service-sector jobs. However, no
conclusive evidence has shown that, over the long haul, the service jobs being created pay
less or are otherwise less desirable than manufactured jobs being displaced. Moreover, the
declining share of manufacturing in U.S. employment most likely stems less from import
competition than it does from the rapid pace of productivity growth in manufacturing; this
growth outpaced the productivity growth of the overall economy by about 1-1/4 percentage
points annually from 1973 to 1994 and by 1-1/2 percentage points from 1994 to 2000. The
higher rate of productivity growth in manufacturing has restrained both price increases and
employment in the sector, thus leading the services area of the economy to expand its share
of spending and jobs. This phenomenon is hardly unique to the United States--the share of
manufacturing has declined in most of our major foreign trading partners as well.
More recently, the outsourcing of service jobs to developing countries has come under the
spotlight. The increasing use of computer programming talent in India and other low-wage
countries has, understandably, struck a chord of anxiety among American workers. For
years, the response of pro-trade advocates to the loss of low-wage jobs in manufacturing has
been that they are being made up by the creation of higher-paid, higher-skilled jobs in the
service sector. The loss of highly paid programming jobs to lower-paid workers abroad now
appears to suggest that there is no place where American workers can hold their own.
Yet, as in the case of import competition more generally, we must not exaggerate the
importance of outsourcing to the nation's overall employment picture. There are no
conclusive data, but a prominent study puts the number of jobs displaced through services
outsourcing over the next decade or so at fewer than 300,000 annually, or less than 2
percent of the 15 million in total gross job losses I noted earlier.18 Moreover, only a fraction
of those jobs represent high-skilled, high-wage jobs; these numbers are quite difficult to pin
down, but one study puts the number of software jobs lost to India since 2000 at fewer than
50,000 annually.19 Finally, we should remember that the United States gains jobs through
what is often referred to as "insourcing," that is, performing service jobs for other countries.
In fact, the United States has consistently run a surplus in those categories of the balanceof-payments associated with trade in business services.
Turning from the sectoral job mix to the impact of import competition on wages, the
evidence is particularly unclear. Some studies have suggested that import competition from
low-wage countries has depressed wages for low-skilled workers relative to those for higherskilled workers in recent decades. However, other studies have argued that the rise in skill
premiums is attributable to technological developments that have raised relative demands for
educated workers. Focusing on the past few years, we see no consensus on how the mix of

low- and high-wage jobs in the economy has evolved; estimates are extremely sensitive to
the definition of job classes, the source of data, the time period, and method of calculation.
In any event, it is doubtful that changes in the pattern of wages in the U.S. economy can be
explained by any single factor--trends in trade, in population and immigration, in
unionization and labor market competition, in minimum wage policy, in the skill mix of the
labor force, and in technology all play a role.
Drawbacks of Protectionism
To sum up the discussion so far, the public likely has a reasonably good grasp of the benefits
of free trade. It is the perceived drawbacks to international trade that probably account for
the ambivalence indicated in opinion surveys. Some of these fears may be overstated--for
example, the claim that imports lower aggregate employment. But other concerns cannot be
dismissed out of hand--especially the claim that trade leads to disruptions for some workers.
Balancing the pain for a few against the lasting gains for the economy as a whole,
economists generally view the latter as outweighing the former, but it is admittedly difficult
for many individuals in American society to share this assessment.
Rather than arguing the merits of international trade in the abstract, advocates of free trade
might gain more traction by arguing against concrete examples of protectionism. Each year
brings new actions by the U.S. government to protect individual sectors from imports.
Antidumping duties are imposed when domestic industry is believed to be injured by the sale
of imported goods at less than "fair value." Countervailing duties are intended to counteract
subsidies to foreign producers. Safeguard actions are intended to protect a domestic industry
that has been seriously injured by a surge in imports.20 As of August 2004, 359 antidumping
and countervailing duty orders were in place in the United States against imports from 51
countries.21
By discouraging unfair commercial practices, such actions, in principle, promote a more
stable and competitive environment for international trade. In practice, identifying
anticompetitive practices is a murky process. For example, in antidumping cases,
determining the "fair value" of a good may involve a degree of discretion, thereby
complicating the assessment of whether foreign goods are being sold below their appropriate
price.22 Domestic producers have a strong incentive to lobby for trade actions regardless of
whether such actions are merited.
Because they inhibit free trade, protectionist actions have an array of adverse consequences
that one would expect: They reduce variety and raise costs for consumers; they distort the
allocation of resources in the economy by encouraging excessive resources to flow into
protected sectors; and they foster inefficiency by reducing the extent of competition.
Perhaps more important in the eyes of the public, however, may be several related and
highly egregious consequences of protectionist actions.
First, by raising the cost of goods that are inputs for other producers, import barriers may
destroy more jobs in so-called "downstream" sectors than they save in protected sectors.
According to one study, the 2002 steel safeguard program contributed to higher steel prices
that eliminated about 200,000 jobs in steel-using industries, whereas only 187,500 workers
were employed by U.S. steel-producers in December 2002.23
Second, trade protection may lead to very large payouts to a small number of producers and
hence is often inequitable. Any time a product receives import protection, of course, a
relatively small number of domestic producers receive benefits--through higher prices--at the

cost of all domestic consumers in the economy. On top of this, a disproportionately small
number of sectors, and often a disproportionately small number of firms within a sector, tend
to enjoy the gains from protection. For example, more than one-half of the antidumping and
countervailing duty orders in place as of August were on iron and steel-related products
alone; by contrast, less than one-half of 1 percent of total private nonfarm employment is
accounted for by iron and steel producers.24 As another example, according to a 1993
General Accounting Office study, 42 percent of the benefits to growers from sugar
protection went to just 1 percent of growers.25 Although Americans favor policies designed
to help the small farmer, much larger enterprises are also benefiting from agricultural trade
protection.
This disturbingly inequitable distribution of the benefits of protectionism is exacerbated
under current law by provisions allowing antidumping and countervailing duties to be
disbursed to the companies that petitioned for the duties. These provisions, which have been
ruled illegal by the WTO, lead to protected producers being rewarded twice: Once through
the higher prices stemming from the trade protection and again through the disbursal of the
higher duties paid by importers. The distribution of these payouts has been extremely
skewed: For fiscal year 2003, a single firm received more than one-fourth of the $190
million in countervailing and antidumping duties that were distributed to U.S. firms.26
Import quotas (as opposed to tariffs) raise a third concern about trade protection. By
restricting the supply of certain types of imports within the United States, quotas may benefit
those foreign producers who retain the right to sell to U.S. markets by raising the prices of
their goods. For example, one study found that, of the $8.6 billion in net welfare costs
induced by the Multi-Fiber Agreement, which restricts textile and apparel imports, about $6
billion accrued to those foreign producers who were allotted shares of the import quotas.27
Surely, many Americans would cease to support certain types of import protections if they
knew that such actions were serving to prop up the profits of foreign producers.
Finally, we must not forget that trade actions, while sometimes protecting some American
workers in import-competing industries, often invite the threat of foreign retaliation that
would hurt American workers in export industries. For example, after the imposition of steel
safeguard duties in March 2002, eight of our trading partners initiated safeguard
investigations of their own on steel imports. Given the importance of export markets to the
most dynamic areas of U.S. manufacturing, we cannot afford to jeopardize them by inviting
foreign barriers to our products.
Conclusion
In conclusion, I think it unlikely that we will see a marked global reversal of trade
liberalization on the order of the restrictions enacted in the 1930s. Policymakers have
generally learned the lessons of that destructive episode. Nevertheless, it is not
inconceivable that progress in dismantling trade barriers could stall. Many of the easiest
negotiations--such as on lowering tariffs--have already taken place. More ambitious and
intrusive trade liberalizations, which often involve dismantling barriers to internal
competition or cherished systems of domestic subsidies, may not have the necessary public
support. It is also possible that a multiplicity of narrow, targeted trade actions--such as
antidumping or safeguard actions--could lead to a de facto rollback in the overall degree of
free trade even without a concerted shift in national policies.
Thus, it is crucial to maintain public pressure for free trade. First, it is important to continue

to educate the public and create a political environment supportive of free trade. In this
respect, targeted criticisms of protectionist actions may be more effective than general
paeans to free trade. In a recent speech, my colleague, William Poole, urged journalists
describing trade restrictions to ask who gains, who loses, and what is the net gain or loss for
the economy as a whole?28 I very much support that sentiment. Second, it is crucial to
implement policies that foster stability and economic growth. Reducing unemployment and
diminishing economic insecurity will likely be more effective against protectionism than a
thousand speeches like this one. Toward that end, the Federal Reserve will do its part by
working to promote stable financial conditions and sustainable, noninflationary growth.
Footnotes
1. Ninety-three percent of economists surveyed agreed, to a least a limited degree, with the
statement that "tariffs and import quotas usually reduce general economic welfare." Richard
M. Alston, J.R. Kearl, and Michael B. Vaughan (1992), "Is There a Consensus Among
Economists in the 1990s?" American Economic Review, vol. 82 (May, Papers and
Proceedings, 1991), pp. 203‑09. Return to text
2. Steven Kull and others (2004), "Americans on Globalization, Trade, and Farm Subsidies,"
The American Public on International Issues, the PIPA/Knowledge Networks Poll (Program
on International Policy Attitudes, University of Maryland, January 22),
www.pipa.org. Return to text
3. Christian Broda and David E. Weinstein (2004), "Globalization and the Gains from
Variety," NBER Working Paper Series 10314 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of
Economic Research, February). Return to text
4. U.S. International Trade Commission (2004), The Economic Effects of Significant U.S.
Import Restraints: Fourth Update, Investigation 332‑325, Publication 3701 (Washington:
ITC, June). Return to text
5. U.S. International Trade Commission (2003), The Impact of Trade Agreements: Effect of
the Tokyo Round, U.S.-Israel FTA, U.S.-Canada FTA, NAFTA, and the Uruguay Round on
the U.S. Economy, Investigation TA-2111-1, Publication 3621 (Washington: ITC,
August). Return to text
6. Drusilla K. Brown, Alan V. Deardorff, and Robert M. Stern (2002), "Computational
Analysis of Multilateral Trade Liberalization in the Uruguay Round and Doha Development
Round," Discussion Paper 489, Research Seminar in International Economics, Gerald R.
Ford School of Public Policy (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan). Return to text
7. Andrew B. Bernard, J. Bradford Jensen, and Peter K. Schott (2002), "Survival of the Best
Fit: Competition from Low Wage Countries and the (Uneven) Growth of U.S. Manufacturing
Plants," NBER Working Paper Series 9170 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of
Economic Research, September). Return to text
8. Petia Topalova (2004), "Trade Liberalization and Firm Productivity: The Case of India,"
IMF Working Paper WP/04/28 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, February); Nina
Pavcnik (2002), "Trade Liberalization, Exit, and Productivity Improvements: Evidence from
Chilean Plants," Review of Economic Studies, vol. 69 (January), pp. 245-76. Return to text

9. Andrew B. Bernard and J. Bradford Jensen (1995), "Exporters, Jobs, and Wages in U.S.
Manufacturing, 1976-1987," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics,
1995, pp. 69-119. Return to text
10. David Dollar and Aart Kraay (2001), "Trade, Growth, and Poverty," unpublished paper,
World Bank, June; Sebastian Edwards (1998), "Openness, Productivity and Growth: What
Do We Really Know?" Economic Journal, vol. 108 (March), pp. 383-98. Return to text
11. Alan M. Taylor (1994), "Three Phases of Argentine Economic Growth," NBER
Historical Paper 60 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research,
September); Jagdish Bhagwati (1993), India in Transition: Freeing the Economy (New
York: Oxford University Press); Douglas A. Irwin (2002), Free Trade Under Fire
(Princeton: Princeton University Press); Mario J. Crucini and James Kahn (1996), "Tariffs
and Aggregate Economic Activity: Lessons from the Great Depression," Journal of
Monetary Economics, vol. 38 (December), pp. 427-67. Return to text
12. Caroline Freund (2000), "Current Account Adjustment in Industrialized Countries,"
International Finance Discussion Paper 2000-692 (Washington: Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, December). Return to text
13. Kull and others (2004), "Americans on Globalization, Trade, and Farm Subsidies."
Return to text
14. My colleague, Ben Bernanke, has discussed many of the issues linking trade and jobs in
a speech earlier this year ("Trade and Jobs," at the Fuqua School of Business, Duke
University, March 30, 2004). Return to text
15. Henry Farber (2003), "Job Loss in the United States, 1981-2001," Industrial Relations
Section Working Paper 471, (Princeton: Princeton University, January). This study covers
workers displaced for any reason, including import competition. Return to text
16. Lori G. Kletzer (2001), Job Loss from Imports: Measuring the Costs (Washington:
Institute for International Economics). Return to text
17. Kletzer, Job Loss from Imports, estimates that 6.4 million workers were displaced from
import-competing industries from 1979 to 1999. Return to text
18. This is based on widely cited results from the technology research firm Forrester, which
predicts that 3.4 million U.S. service jobs will have been moved offshore by 2015. Return to
text
19. Martin Neil Baily and Robert Z, Lawrence (2004), "What Happened to the Great U.S.
Job Machine? The Role of Trade and Offshoring," paper prepared for the Brookings Panel
on Economic Activity, September 9-10. Their rough estimate of nearly 45,000 software jobs
relocated annually to India is consistent with an estimate by Charles L. Shultze that "the
number of workers employed in producing computer and related services relocated from the
United States to India could have increased by roughly 185,000 over the past four years"
(Charles L. Schultze, "Offshoring, Import Competition, and the Jobless Recovery," Policy
Brief 136, Washington: The Brookings Institution, August). Return to text
20. See World Trade Organization, "Anti-dumping, Subsidies, Safeguards: Contingencies,

etc.,"; U.S. International Trade Commission (1998), Summary of Statutory Provisions
Related to Import Relief, Publication 3125 (Washington: ITC, August). Return to text
21. U.S. International Trade Commission (2004), "Antidumping and Countervailing Duty
Orders in Place as of August 9, 2004, by Product Group (111 KB PDF)," Five-Year (Sunset)
Reviews, General Information, item 7: AD and CVD orders in place. Return to text
22. Bruce A. Blonigen (2003), "Evolving Discretionary Practices of U.S. Antidumping
Activity," NBER Working Paper Series 9625 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of
Economic Research, April). Return to text
23. Joseph Francois and Laura M. Baughman (2003), "The Unintended Consequences of
U.S. Steel Import Tariffs: A Quantification of the Impact During 2002," CITAC Job Studies
(Washington: Consuming Industries Trade Action Coalition). Return to text
24. "U.S. International Trade Commission, Antidumping and Countervailing Duty Orders in
Place as of August 9, 2004, by Product Group." Return to text
25. U.S. General Accounting Office (1993), "Sugar Program: Changing Domestic and
International Conditions Require Program Changes," GAO/RCED-93-84 (Washington:
GAO, April). Return to text
26. As of March 2004. U.S. Customs and Border Protection (2004), Continued Dumping
and Subsidy Offset Act FY 2003 Annual Report (Washington: CBP). Return to text
27. Gary Clyde Hufbauer and Kimberly Ann Elliot (1994), Measuring the Costs of
Protection in the United States (Washington: Institute for International Economics). Return
to text
28. William Poole (2004), Free Trade: Why Are Economists and Noneconomists So Far
Apart? Speech prepared for the Trade, Globalization, and Outsourcing Conference, Reuters
America, Inc., New York, June 15. Return to text
Return to top
2004 Speeches
Home | News and events
Accessibility | Contact Us
Last update: October 7, 2004